Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Managing Health Insurance Risk
Advertisements

RESOURCE ALLOCATION & THE MARKET Demand, supply and the market Sources of failure in the market for health care The insurance system of funding health.
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other. Consider a market.
Fall 2008 Version Professor Dan C. Jones FINA 4355 Class Problem.
1 PROVISIONS FOR PROFIT AND CONTINGENCIES (MIS-35) Seminar on Ratemaking Nashville, TNRuss Bingham March 11-12, 1999Hartford Financial Services.
Chapter 9: Health Care Market
Chapter 12 Social Insurance: The New Function of Government
Health Insurance – Part 1 Eric Jacobson. Employer Health Benefits 2004 Annual Survey Kaiser Family Foundation
Adverse Selection The good risks drop out. A common story.  Insurer offers a new type of policy.  Hoping to make money.  It loses money.  Reason.
Choices Involving Risk
Social Insurance Arises, In Part, Because of Asymmetric Information Assume there are 2 groups, each with 100 people. The first group has 5% chance of getting.
The Economics of Information. Risk a situation in which there is a probability that an event will occur. People tend to prefer greater certainty and less.
Health Insurance October 19, 2006 Insurance is defined as a means of protecting against risk. Risk is a state in which multiple outcomes are possible and.
Frederik Weber Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität München Institute for Risk and Insurance Management ARIA Annual Meeting · Quebec City 2007.
317_L17, Feb 13, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of the case for public health insurance basic reason => market failure.
Asymmetric Information ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert.
317_L15, Feb 8, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of why there is a demand for health insurance basic reason => people.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
Game theory v. price theory. Game theory Focus: strategic interactions between individuals. Tools: Game trees, payoff matrices, etc. Outcomes: In many.
Chapter 8 Demand and Supply of Health Insurance 1.What is Insurance 2.Risk and Insurance 3.The demand for Insurance 4.The supply for Insurance 5.The case.
Information and Advertising Lemons and Insurance Insurers have incomplete information on the quality of those seeking insurance. Some may be creampuffs.
Health Insurance – Part 2 Eric Jacobson. Key Definitions Adverse selection – Enrollees may seek to join a health plan at a premium that reflects a lower.
Fair Premiums, Insurability of Risk and Contractual Provisions
1 Chapter 9 Knowledge and Information In this chapter we want to see what happens in a market when the amount of information participants have is different.
The role of insurance in health care, part 1
Lectures Section Seven: Market Failure Introduction to Microeconomics (L11100)
Health Insurance: The Basics. 10 things you should know about Health Insurance 1.Insurance costs a lot but having none costs more 2.If your employer offers.
Chapter 6: Health Insurance Chapter 6 Health Insurance Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
The Private Health Insurance Market. Insurance Design Insurance is designed to spread risk Individuals can self-insure and face chance of paying for costs.
HEALTH AND PRODUCTIVITY MANAGEMENT H P M THINK GLOBALLY! BY: BRIAN D. HARRISON, MD DATE:9/28/04.
THE HEALTH CARE MARKET Chapter 9.
Health Insurance: The Basics Independent Living. 5 Things You Should Know About Health Insurance… Insurance costs a lot but having none costs more If.
Industrial Economics Fall INFORMATION Basic economic theories: Full (perfect) information In reality, information is limited. Consumers do not know.
Asymmetric Information and Agency. Overview and Background Traditional models of demand side assume that individuals have complete information about prices.
ENTREPRENEURS IN A MARKET ECONOMY
Unit 8: Insurance Section 14.1 – Insurance Basics.
Analyzing and Reducing Costs. Plan for Today Review and reflect on Roulette Excel Exercise Relate exercise to major cost-reduction strategies of health.
Health Annual statements: A way to assess insurers’ financial health May 20, 2015 Cheryl Fish-Parcham.
Asymmetric Information
Enhanced Annuities, Individual Underwriting, and Adverse Selection August 6, Enhanced Annuities, Individual Underwriting, and Adverse Selection.
Chapter 8 Insurance Pricing.
(More) Information Lemons and Insurance Insurers have incomplete information on the quality of those seeking insurance. Some may be creampuffs Others.
Potential State Applications of Section 125 Plans Rick Curtis, President Institute for Health Policy Solutions SCI/NASHP/NGA Section 125 Plans Meeting.
Asymmetric Information
Health Insurance The Basics. Health Insurance: The Basics It is important that you understand health insurance in order to protect yourself and your familyIt.
Chapter 3 Risk Attitudes: Expected Utility Theory and Demand for Hedging.
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples Agenda: 1.The Used Car Game 2.Insurance & The Death Spiral 3.The Market for Information 4.The Price.
317_L16, Feb 12, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture Finished our discussion of why there is a demand for health insurance today begin our.
Managed Care. In the broadest terms, Kongstvedt (1997) describes managed care as a system of healthcare delivery that tries to manage the cost of healthcare,
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Decision theory under uncertainty
The Economics of Information and Choice Under Uncertainty.
What is ‘Managed Care’? A ‘type’ of health insurance –combines both the financing of care (insurance) with the provision of care –variations in MC plans.
C. Bordoy UWC Maastricht Market Failure HL material HL material (Tragakes, 2012, pp )
Savings and Investment. Why do we invest? Spend It Save It Put It In The Bank Invest It If we have money we can... What are the Advantages/R isks of each.
Using Credit Scores to Fix Auto Insurance Rates Cassandra Kubes PPPA 6085, Evening Session December 1, 2015.
Market Failure. Occurs when free market forces, using the price mechanism, fail to produce the products that people want, in the quantities they desire.
Private Health Insurance
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization Presented by: Kuan Chen.
Chapter 15 Debt and Taxes. Copyright ©2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved The Interest Tax Deduction Corporations pay taxes on.
Signaling Game Problems. Signaling game. Two players– a sender and receiver. Sender knows his type. Receiver does not. It is not necessarily in the sender’s.
Introduction to Health Insurance. What Is Risk? Life has many uncertainties that result in financial loss and unhappiness- for example, loss of a job,
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples
Health Insurance Pricing
Presentation transcript:

Adverse Selection

What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services than does the insurer. As a result, you have an incentive to use this information to your best advantage. In particular, if you have some health problem you might try to find an insurance plan that is designed for healthier people. If you were successful, you would pay a premium that was less than your expected claims experience. The insurer, on the other hand, would probably lose money on you.

Adverse selection People with a higher than average risk of needing health care are more likely than healthier people to seek health insurance. Adverse selection results when these less healthy people disproportionately enroll into an risk pool.

Death spiral If a risk pool attracts a disproportionate share of people in poor health, the average cost of people in the pool will rise, and people in better health will be less willing to join the pool (or will leave and seek out a pool that has a lower average cost). A pool that is subject to significant adverse selection will continue to lose its healthier risks, causing its average costs to continually rise. This is referred to as a “death spiral.”

Asymmetric Information Assume there are 2 groups, each with 100 people. The first group has 5% chance of getting diseased, and the second group has a 0.5% chance. The payout is $30,000 when diseased.

Insurance pricing with separate groups of consumers Premium per: InformationPricing approach High Risk (100 people) Low Risk (100 people) Total premiums paid Total benefits paid out Net profits to insurers FullSeparate$1,500$150$165,000 (100 x $1, x $150) $165,0000 The insurance company collects $1500 x 100 from the high risks, and $150 x 100 from the low risks. Total premiums of $165,000 equal expected costs. The premium to the high risks is therefore 5% x $30,000. For the low risks, it is 0.5% x $30,000. It therefore charges separate prices to each group; competition forces it to charge an actuarially fair price. With full information, the insurance company can tell the high risks from the low risks. Failure of Different Insurance Strategies

Insurance pricing with separate groups of consumers Premium per: InformationPricing approach High Risk (100 people) Low Risk (100 people) Total premiums paid Total benefits paid out Net profits to insurers FullSeparate$1,500$150$165,000 (100 x $1, x $150) $165,0000 AsymmetricSeparate$1,500$150$30,000 (0 x $1, x $150) $165,000-$135,000 The insurance insurer collects $150 x 100 from the high risks, and $150 x 100 from the low risks. Total premiums of $30,000 are $135,000 less than expected costs. In this case, the insurer loses money, so it will not offer insurance. Thus, the market fails; individuals will not be able to obtain the optimal amount of insurance. The high risks have no incentive to tell the insurer about their disease, however; they pay 10 times as much if they reveal truthfully about their status. It could continue to charge separate premiums to the different groups, taking the person’s word that they are either healthy or ill. Now imagine the insurance company cannot tell people apart. This is a case with asymmetric information. Failure of Different Insurance Strategies

Insurance pricing with separate groups of consumers Premium per: InformationPricing approach High Risk (100 people) Low Risk (100 people) Total premiums paid Total benefits paid out Net profits to insurers FullSeparate$1,500$150$165,000 (100 x $1, x $150) $165,0000 AsymmetricSeparate$1,500$150$30,000 (0 x $1, x $150) $165,000-$135,000 AsymmetricAverage$825 $82,500 (100 x $ x $825) $150,000-$67,500 With this price structure, none of the low risk people buy the policy. The insure collects $825 x 100 people, but pays $1,500 x 100 people in benefits. Again, the insurer loses money, so it will not offer insurance. Thus, the market fails again with a pooling equilibrium. The average cost for the population as a whole would be $165,000 in claims divided by 200 people, or $825 per person. Another potential alternative is that the insurance company understands it cannot tell consumers apart. Thus, it charges a uniform premium for all customers. Failure of Different Insurance Strategies

Asymmetric Information This example illustrates how the problem of adverse selection plagues the insurance market. People have the option of buying insurance, and will only do so if it is a fair deal for them. Only the high risks take-up the policy so it loses money.

Does Asymmetric Information Necessarily Lead to Market Failure? Will adverse selection always lead to market failure? Not if: –Most individuals are fairly risk averse, such that they will buy an actuarially unfair policy. The policy entails a risk premium, the amount that risk-averse individuals will pay for insurance above and beyond the actuarially fair price. This leads to a pooling equilibrium, which is a market equilibrium in which all types buy full insurance even though it is not fairly priced to all individuals.

Does Asymmetric Information Necessarily Lead to Market Failure? Will adverse selection always lead to market failure? –In addition, the insurance company can offer separate products at separate prices, causing consumers to reveal their true types (careless or careful). This leads to a separating equilibrium, which is a market equilibrium in which different types buy different kinds of insurance products.

Does Asymmetric Information Necessarily Lead to Market Failure? The separating equilibrium still represents a market failure. Insurers can force the low risks to make a choice between full insurance at a high price, or partial insurance at a lower price. Although insurance is offered to both groups in this case, the low risks do not get full insurance, which is suboptimal.

Methods of limiting or adjusting financial risk A."Carve-Outs" Based on: Type of service (eg, preventive care) Diagnoses or conditions (eg, AIDS) Referral specialty (eg, ophthalmology) B.Caps on Expenditures C.Risk-adjustment of capitation payments

Underwriting And Rate Making Insurers deal with adverse selection through the underwriting and rate-making process. They seek to identify the determinants of claims experience and use this knowledge to put individuals and groups into risk pools that reflect their expected utilization. The nature and extent of this underwriting process depends in large part on the rating techniques employed. Community rating, in which everyone is in the same risk pool, requires little formal underwriting. Similarly, retrospective experience rating requires little underwriting; each employer group constitutes its own risk class.

Thank You ! Any Question ?