Strategic Behavior in Elections and Markets Can game theory have anything to say about behavior by participants in elections or markets? We often imagine.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
Advertisements

Chapter 10: The Manipulability of Voting Systems Lesson Plan
Nash Equilibrium: Illustrations
3. Basic Topics in Game Theory. Strategic Behavior in Business and Econ Outline 3.1 What is a Game ? The elements of a Game The Rules of the.
Presented by: Katherine Goulde
Voting and social choice Vincent Conitzer
The Voting Problem: A Lesson in Multiagent System Based on Jose Vidal’s book Fundamentals of Multiagent Systems Henry Hexmoor SIUC.
NOTE: To change the image on this slide, select the picture and delete it. Then click the Pictures icon in the placeholder to insert your own image. CHOOSING.
CS 886: Electronic Market Design Social Choice (Preference Aggregation) September 20.
Auctions. Strategic Situation You are bidding for an object in an auction. The object has a value to you of $20. How much should you bid? Depends on auction.
Introduction to Game theory Presented by: George Fortetsanakis.
ECO290E: Game Theory Lecture 4 Applications in Industrial Organization.
What is your favorite food?. Preference Schedule A Preference Schedule is a way to represent the order in which people like (prefer) certain items. The.
Social Choice Topics to be covered:
GAME THEORY.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Alex Tabarrok Arrow’s Theorem.
Social choice theory = preference aggregation = voting assuming agents tell the truth about their preferences Tuomas Sandholm Professor Computer Science.
The Politics of Lineland Last time: She blinded me with Science Why and how should we study legislatures and legislators? Today Introduction to spatial.
Social Choice Theory By Shiyan Li. History The theory of social choice and voting has had a long history in the social sciences, dating back to early.
Social choice theory = preference aggregation = truthful voting Tuomas Sandholm Professor Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University.
Microeconomics 2 Lecture 2 Gains from exchange. Who will win the Nobel Prize in economics in 2013? In below Al Roth Lloyd Shapley See the Guardian.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
More Competitive Balance. Invariance Principle Owners in baseball have made the claim that free agency has changed the competitive balance in baseball.
How the Stock Market Works. Stock A share in ownership of a company. A share in ownership of a company. Someone who owns stock in a company owns a part.
Group Decision Making Y. İlker TOPCU, Ph.D twitter.com/yitopcu.
Social choice (voting) Vincent Conitzer > > > >
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Overview Aggregating preferences The Social Welfare function The Pareto Criterion The Compensation Principle.
Supply and Demand Chapter 3 Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Introduction to Economics Chapter 17
Bell Work. Have you ever watched someone win a game again and again? Do you think that person just has good luck? In many cases, winners have strategies.
CPS Voting and social choice Vincent Conitzer
Nash equilibrium Nash equilibrium is defined in terms of strategies, not payoffs Every player is best responding simultaneously (everyone optimizes) This.
TOOL #3 THE SUPPLY AND DEMAND MODEL. Our purpose is to illustrate how the supply and demand model can describe a macroeconomic system. One of the impressive.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Examinations Go to Read.
Lecture 4 Strategic Interaction Game Theory Pricing in Imperfectly Competitive markets.
Introduction to Matching Theory E. Maskin Jerusalem Summer School in Economic Theory June 2014.
Asymmetric Information
Lecture 7 Course Summary The tools of strategy provide guiding principles that that should help determine the extent and nature of your professional interactions.
Chapter 10: The Manipulability of Voting Systems Lesson Plan An Introduction to Manipulability Majority Rule and Condorcet’s Method The Manipulability.
Lecture 8 Product differentiation. Standard models thus far assume that every firm is producing a homogenous good; that is, the product sold by In the.
Assoc. Prof. Yeşim Kuştepeli1 VOTING GAMES. Assoc. Prof. Yeşim Kuştepeli2 Outline Choosing Among Voting Mechanisms Majority Rule with Two Choices Plurality.
AQA E CON 1: M ARKETS AND MARKET FAILURE Scarcity, choice and the allocation of resources Use economic terminology to explain the concept of scarcity.
Great Theoretical Ideas in Computer Science.
Price & The Market Equilibrium.   Demand and Supply interact and determine the price of a product, and the quantity bought or sold.  With competition,
Copyright 2013, 2010, 2007, Pearson, Education, Inc. Section 15.1 Voting Methods.
PUBLIC CHOICE AND GOVERNMENT FAILURES Miloš Fišar BPV_APEC PUBLIC ECONOMICS.
© 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R Oligopoly.
Social choice theory = preference aggregation = voting assuming agents tell the truth about their preferences Tuomas Sandholm Professor Computer Science.
Section 9.1 Great Expectations Deciding How to Weigh the Unknown Future Chance favors only the prepared mind. Louis Pasteur.
Bell Work Please write the fraction, decimal AND percent. 1)Convert 4/5 to a decimal and a percent. 1)Convert.675 to a fraction and a Percent. 1)Convert.
We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets?
How Should Presidents Be Elected? E. Maskin Institute for Advanced Study.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 6-1 CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Examinations Go to Read.
EFFICIENCY by Caterina Ficiarà. We know that a society has to face different problems. To sum up, the main difficulties we can find in every nation are:
Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 1 The Mathematics of Voting 1.1Preference Ballots and Preference.
Chapter 9: Social Choice: The Impossible Dream Lesson Plan Voting and Social Choice Majority Rule and Condorcet’s Method Other Voting Systems for Three.
Lecture 4 on Auctions Multiunit Auctions We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling.
Condorcet Method Another group-ranking method. Development of Condorcet Method  As we have seen, different methods of determining a group ranking often.
Voting: Does the Majority Always Rule?
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 13 Oligopoly.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of markets
Chapter 10: The Manipulability of Voting Systems Lesson Plan
Social choice theory = preference aggregation = voting assuming agents tell the truth about their preferences Tuomas Sandholm Professor Computer Science.
Alex Tabarrok Arrow’s Theorem.
Social Choice Theory [Election Theory]
Voting systems Chi-Kwong Li.
Section 14.1 Voting Methods.
Presentation transcript:

Strategic Behavior in Elections and Markets Can game theory have anything to say about behavior by participants in elections or markets? We often imagine that, in such environments, individual actors cannot have any impact on outcomes, i.e. that they are “ atomistic. ” Consequently, it seems that strategic behavior doesn ’ t matter. For example: –Polls show that my candidate is losing. If I vote, he will lose anyway, so there is no reason to vote. –The price of tickets to a Pirates game is too high, but by refusing to buy tickets, I, by myself, am unlikely to affect the price. As we shall see, strategy can matter in elections and markets if the number of players is small enough.

Voting Games Voting games involve groups of N people who decide some issue or choose some candidate by holding an election and counting votes. There are two sides to voting games: –Possible strategic behavior among the voters themselves, if N is small. –If the voters are choosing candidates as in political elections, and the number of candidates is small, then the candidates have good reason to behave strategically. The rules matter. The rules prescribe how the winning issue or winning candidate is determined. –Majority rule: issue/candidate with more than half of votes wins. –Plurality rule: issue/candidate with the highest frequency of votes wins: “ first past the post. ” With 3 or more issues/alternatives/candidates, strategic voting behavior becomes an issue.

An Issue Voting Game Pitt ’ s Board of Trustees is comprised of 13 members who have different positions on how much Pitt should increase tuition next year. Suppose there are three position types: Type X, 4 out of 13, thinks Pitt should seek a high tuition increase in light of the state government ’ s decreasing appropriation in recent years. If a high increase cannot be achieved, X types prefer a medium increase to no increase at all. Type Y, 5 out of 13, thinks Pitt should seek a medium tuition increase, since too high an increase might reduce student applicants and the state ’ s appropriation. If a medium increase is not possible, Y types prefer no increase at all to a high increase. Type Z, 4 out of 13, thinks Pitt should seek no increase in tuition, and ask the state government to increase its appropriation as a reward. However, if it appears that the other members will vote for some tutition increase (high or medium), type Zs reason that the state appropriation will not be increased and so in that case Zs prefer a high increase to a medium increase.

The Voting Outcome Depends on the Rules Let H=high, M=medium, N=no increase. Preferences are: If plurality rules, and members vote their first choice, then a medium increase in tuition wins, as 5/13 > 4/13, but it does not comprise a majority of the trustees ’ positions on tuition increases. If majority rules are in place, so that tuition policy is not implemented unless more than half vote for it, and voters are rational, they may behave strategically: –Suppose voting takes place in a single stage. If types X and Y vote for their first preference, and type Z strategically votes for its second preference, H, then H wins a strict majority of votes, 8/13, and type Z trustees are strictly better off than they would have been if M was the majority winner (imagine assigning payoffs based on preferences). –Of course, the other types, X and Y could also vote strategically, so that all 3 options, H, M, N could earn majority votes!

The Condorcet Rule This rule, proposed by the Marquis de Condorcet, a French Enlightenment philosopher, circa 1775, involves a complete round-robin pairing of all issues/candidates. The issue/candidate that wins majority votes in all pairwise matches is the Condorcet winner, a seemingly good approach to eliminating the problems with plurality voting. Alas, this rule can lead to a paradox: one can devise situations where there is no Condorcet winner, leading to the so-called Condorcet paradox.

The Condorcet Paradox Illustrated Consider again the tuition increase issue as described earlier. Preferences are given by: H vs. M. H wins; it gets a majority of 8/13 (X, Z prefer H). M vs. N. M wins; it gets a majority of 9/13 (X,Y prefer M). N vs. H. N wins; it gets a majority of 9/13 (Y, Z prefer N). Conclude: No clear Condorcet winner. The paradox is that while all types have transitive preferences (A  B, B  C  A  C) the social preference ordering that follows from application of the Condorcet procedure is not transitive (or intransitive): H  M, M  N, but N  H!

Other, Less Problematic Voting Rules Preference voting via a Borda rule (named after another French philosopher!) Each voter ranks all n issues/alternatives/candidates assigning n points to the best alternative, n-1 points to second best…and 1 point to the worst of the n alternatives. The alternative with the greatest number of points wins. Preference voting via instant run-off. Each voter ranks all n issues/alternatives/candidates. If the first preferences produce a majority, it is adopted. If not, the alternative with the least first preference votes is eliminated, and its supporter ’ s second preference votes become their new first preference votes. Procedure continues until a majority is obtained. Approval voting. No ranking – voters just say yes or no to each alternative. The one alternative with the most yes votes wins.

A Two-Candidate Election Suppose there are just two candidates, say D and R, for president. Suppose the voters ’ preferences can be described by four main types: Left, Center-Left, Center-Right and Right. Suppose the distribution of types over voters is as follows What positions will the two candidates take if they are rational, strategic players?

The Median Voter Theorem Candidates get the votes of those whose preferences are closest to their chosen positions. Assume the two candidates equally split the votes of any types that lie between their chosen positions. If they choose the same position, each gets half of all 100 million votes. The payoff table can be written as follows: Cell-by-cell inspection reveals that (CR, CR) is the unique NE. But CR also corresponds to the position of the median voter – the voter for whom 50% of voters have positions to the left of that voter, and 50% have positions to the right of that voter. The median voter in our example is a CR type – why? The median voter theorem says that both candidates choose the same position on the political spectrum where the median voter resides. The theorem breaks down if there are more than two candidates.

Market Games A market is any arrangement in which goods or services are exchanged. –For example, auctions, supermarkets, job markets, “ meet ” markets. Those supplying goods are suppliers or sellers. Those demanding goods are demanders or buyers. Do individual buyers or sellers act strategically? –If just one (or a few) buyers and just one (or a few) sellers, then strategic behavior is very likely as in a bargaining game. –Oligopolistic markets - just a few firms compete. –If there are many buyers and sellers, individuals still act strategically, in the sense that they seek prices that maximize their individual surplus (they play individual best responses).

Buyers and Sellers ’ Objectives in the Market for a Certain Good/Service Each buyer i=1,2,... has a value v ij that they attach to unit number j of some good. The buyer ’ s surplus is the value of unit j, v ij less the price s/he paid to the seller for that unit: p: Buyer ’ s surplus = v ij -p Each seller, i=1,2,... has a cost of bringing unit number j of the good to market, c ij The seller ’ s surplus is the price received for unit j of the good, p less the per unit cost, c ij. Seller ’ s surplus = p-c ij

Example: 1 Buyer and 1 Seller Suppose a buyer wants to buy one unit of a good, say a used car. The buyer values it at v, and the seller ’ s cost (or reserve value) c, is such that c < v. Suppose that v and c are common knowledge (a big assumption, we will relax later). Then any price, p, such that v > p > c will provide a positive surplus to both the buyer and the seller. p could be determined via bargaining, but the important point is that there are gains from trade: the buyer gets v-p > 0 and the seller gets p-c > 0.

The Example Graphically price, p quantity, q 1 0 Buyer ’ s Demand Curve price, p quantity, q 1 0 c Seller ’ s Supply Curve price, p quantity, q 1 0 c Combined Supply and Demand v v } price range

Example 2: 2000 Mazda Miata MX-5 Convertible, 20,000 miles

Example 2: 4 Buyers, 4 Sellers 4 buyers B1, B2, B3, B4, and 4 sellers, S1, S2, S3, S4. Each buyer wants to buy one MX-5, and each seller has one MX-5 available for sale. Assume all 4 Miatas are essentially identical, same mileage, transmission type, red color, etc. Suppose the 4 buyer ’ s values can be ranked: v 1 =$19,500 > v 2 =$17,500 > v 3 =$15,500 > v 4 =$13,000 Suppose the four sellers ’ costs (reserve prices) can be ranked: c 1 =$14,500 < c 2 =$16,500 < c 3 =$18,500 < c 4 =$21,000 What will be the equilibrium (market) price? How many cars will be sold? Assuming that no buyer is willing to pay more than their value, and no seller is willing to sell for less than cost, we can find the answer graphically.

Graphical Illustration of Example 2 Equilibrium price, p, is such that $17,500 > p > $16,500. Equilibrium quantity, q=2 Mazda Miatas bought and sold Number of Miatas 13,000 14,500 15,500 16,500 17,500 18,500 19,500 $21,000 Price Per Unit B1 B2 B3 B4 S1 S2 S3 S4 } price range