Econ 201 Chpt. 10 Coase Theorem: Establishing Property Rights & Tradable Permits.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Getting More for Four Principles for Comprehensive Emissions Trading Jan Mazurek, Director Center for Innovation and the Environment 2002 Environmental.
Advertisements

4 THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR. Copyright©2004 South-Western 10 Externalities.
Incentive-Based Strategies: Transferable Discharge Permits Chapter 13.
U.S. Market for SO2 Allowances
EXTERNALITIES Chapter 5.
In chapter 10, we look for the answers to these questions:
10 Externalities.
1 Chapter 3 Externalities and Public Policy. 2 Externalities Externalities are costs or benefits of market transactions not reflected in prices. Negative.
Externalities and Property Rights
Public Goods and Common Property Resources Chapter 11.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
 Homework #1 Due Thursday  Group Quiz Next Thursday  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 28th.
Externalities Chapter 10 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
Chapter 17 Externalities and the Environment © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
When the market works as it should…
The Economics of Environmental Regulation Public Regulation or the Market.
Chapter 9 Externalities: When Prices Send the Wrong Signals
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Environmental Economics.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Externalities Chapter 10 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved.
Principles of Micro Chapter 10: Externalities by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
Chapter 10 notes Externalities.
Externalities ECO 230 J.F. O’Connor. Topics Nature of externalities Why do externalities cause market failure Private solutions to an externality problem.
Econ 201 Chpt. 10 Coase Theorem: Establishing Property Rights & Tradable Permits.
A lesson from chapter 7: Competitive markets are “efficient” -- they lead to maximum total surplus. The price rationing mechanism allocates output to.....
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Review for Exam 1 Chapters 1 Through 5. Production Possibilities Frontiers and Opportunity Costs Learning Objective 2.1 Production possibilities frontier.
Externalities.
Modeling Market Failure Chapter 3 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc. Chapter 3 Externalities and Public Policy Copyright © 2002 Thomson Learning, Inc. Thomson Learning™ is a trademark.
Dr. Laura Dawson Ullrich March 25, Q per year $ MB MD MPC MSC = MPC + MD Q1Q1 Q* Actual output Socially efficient output b a c.
Externalities and Public Policy
Market Failure Market failure refers to reasons why even a perfectly
The music is the symphonic suite, “Sheherazade” by Nikolai Rimsky-Korsakov (1888) Please enjoy Externalities Welcome to Unit 9.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 Stationary-Source Local Air Pollution.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview.
Air Quality Management Comparison of Cap-and-Trade, Command-and Control and Rate-Based Programs Dr. Ruben Deza Senior Environmental Engineer Clean Air.
Econ 100 Lecture 8.3 Pollution and Initiatives in the NW Summer 2009.
Externalities >> chapter: 17 Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers 1 of 32.
14-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported.
1 Econ 201 Lecture 8.2 Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits Summer 2009.
Public Goods and Common Property Resources Chapter 11.
Externalities ECO 230 J.F. O’Connor. Topics Nature of externalities Why do externalities cause market failure Private solutions to an externality problem.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview.
ExternalitiesExternalities. Overview Externalities –Negative: Action by one party imposes a cost on another party –Positive: Action by one party benefits.
ECON 201 Lec 10.1 b Environmental Economics Negative Externalities & Optimal Regulation.
Market Failures Chapter 7 Sections 2 and 3 Economic Solutions to Global Warming.
Policy Tools: Correcting Market Failures. What are the most serious problems we face? Climate change Agricultural production Peak oil Water supply Biodiversity.
Coase Theorem: Establishing Property Rights & Tradable Permits
Topics Externalities. The Inefficiency of Competition with Externalities. Regulating Externalities. Market Structure and Externalities. Allocating Property.
Summary: Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview
10 Externalities.
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
10 Externalities.
Carbon Pricing Telling Canada’s story in numbers
10 Externalities.
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Economics of Pollution Control: An Overview
Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
Summary: Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
10 Externalities.
Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
EXTERNALITIES ETP Economics 101.
Incentive Based Strategies: Transferable Discharge Permits
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
Presentation transcript:

Econ 201 Chpt. 10 Coase Theorem: Establishing Property Rights & Tradable Permits

Tradable Permits A Property Rights Approach “Common” Property Problem No one “owns” the air/water; therefore no one benefits from managing (pricing) its usage Solution is to assign the property right to one party and allow them to trade its use in the marketplace Coase Theorem

Coase’s Theorem If property rights exist and transaction (bargaining) and information costs are low Then parties will be able to bargain among themselves (without government intervention) to obtain an efficient outcome

An Example of the Coase Theorem Marketplace Firm upstream from a farmer Firm produces a good valued by consumer but dumps pollutants into the river as a byproduct Cost of using the river to the firm is $0 Farmer Downstream from the firm Uses water to irrigate his agricultural products Pollution affects/degrades his product

An Example Emissions from a local factory damages strawberry crops in the area. The damage to the strawberry crop is $5 million per year, and the cost of abating the emissions would be $3 million per year. Under which of the following conditions could an efficient bargaining solution be reached? A) Property rights are assigned to the firm B) Property rights are assigned to the farmer

Assigning the Property Rights If assigned to the firm Farmer is willing to “bribe” the firm to reduce pollution Willing to pay firm to reduce gallons discharged up to marginal value of crop damage due to pollution Firm: willing to accept payments that are >= marg costs of treatment/reduction

Assigning Property Rights Assigned to the Farmer Firm is willing to pay farmer up to the marginal value of “avoided” treatment costs Farmer is willing to accept payments >= marginal cost of crop damage Either way: socially efficient (marginal value = marginal cost) solution However, there are different income effects Concluding which is best => normative statement

Criticism of Coase’s Theorem If more than 1 farmer Transaction costs of getting all affected parties together may be too great to get to optimal solution if rights assigned to firm Demsetz (1964): “when transaction costs are too high; status quo may be optimal” Leffler: “if it exists, it’s optimal. But, why?” Use of the government to lower transaction costs Strategic behavior Last individual may “hold” out (lower bribe/higher payment) as key to agreement Fire protection example

Criticism of Coase’s Theorem A single factory spreads pollution that harms millions of people, but the damage to each individual is small. If we assume that the people have the property right to clean air, and that the total cost of the damage is greater than the cost of abatement, is it likely that a bargaining solution could be reached in this case? Bargaining/transaction costs may be too high Government agency could reduce transaction costs by “representing” the community Purpose of class action suits – reduce transaction costs

Comparison of Approaches Standards Can also produce optimal level of pollution But set same standard for all firms (and are not productively efficient, e.g. min cost) To set individual quotas: requires knowledge of each firm’s costs But have higher administrative costs Not only have to monitor emissions Enforcement costs: legal proceedings (time delays and expense) Not very flexible: regulatory process for changing standards Provide no incentive for firms to reduce pollution below current “authorized” levels

Comparison of Approaches Standards Are most useful when: Problem is short-lived (“burn” bans for high pollution days) Optimal level is zero Or pollutant is highly toxic even in small concentrations Arsenic, Mercury

Comparison of Approaches Taxes Can produce “optimal” amount of pollution at minimum costs and lower administrative costs Kneese (1977): comparing taxes versus standards found that desired quality costs half as much using taxes Automatically allocates pollution levels among firms based on their costs Provides incentive for firms to reduce pollution levels through technological innovation Easy to adjust/”tune” Tax revenues can be used finance admin costs

And They Are Endorsed by the Sierra Club! Sierra Club Conservation Policies Pollution Taxes The Sierra Club advocates the establishment of pollution taxes which would make it less expensive for a polluter to adopt alternative processes or invest in additional equipment to curtail releases to the environment than it would be for him to continue as before. Such taxes would supplement, and not replace, standards on maximum permissible emissions. These taxes should be imposed when the following conditions are found to prevail generally: for competitive or other reasons, cost-minimizing behavior tends to exist in the company or industry; the cost of abatement is expected to be significant, both in relation to revenue from sales and in absolute terms; and the quantity of the pollutant released to the environment can be determined with reasonable accuracy, either by direct monitoring of every source, statistical sampling of a small fraction of many similar sources produced by a few manufactures, or by indirect means. The cost of monitoring should be small in relation to the tax revenue expected in the absence of abatement. As a first step, a tax equal to 15 cents per pound should be imposed on sulfur contained in fuels intended for combustion (with a rebate given to those who demonstrate that the sulfur was not released to the environment), and on sulfur emitted from smelters, refineries, and sulfuric acid plants. The tax on lead contained in gasoline... should be promptly enacted. The feasibility of taxes on the emission of nitrogen oxides, particulate matter, carbon monoxide, and hydrocarbons should be investigated... for possible action on these air pollutants; studies should also be conducted on the practicality of similar taxes for various of the water pollutants. Adopted by the Board of Directors, February 13-14, 1997

Comparison of Approaches Tradable Permits Cost efficient Firms will purchase permits from more efficient firms if permit cost < abatement (technology) costs Technological incentive to reduce pollution Marginal cost of abatement = permit cost Similar to taxes Administratively simpler Require less information about the firms’ cost Better able to handle “spatial” variation in pollution Fewer permits auctioned in bad areas Adjust “automatically” for changes in inflation and growth If auctioned -> revenues for admin costs