Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 10.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Supplier hold-up problem If one company is supplying another company a good used in production (such as a supplier of coal to an electric company), then.
Advertisements

Economics of Contract Law. Agency Game I Give me $100 and Ill turn it into $200 and share the gain with you Do you trust me? No! Player 2 has DS to breach.
Contract Designing contracts –A common interest in efficient contracts –How to make a contract efficient Enforcing and interpreting contracts –What contracts.
ECON 1450 – Professor Berkowitz Lecture Notes -Chapter 5 Remedies for Breach of Contract Efficient Breach Model Previous lectures – what promises should.
Ind – Develop a foundational knowledge of pricing to understand its role in marketing. (Part II) Entrepreneurship I.
Supplier hold-up problem If one company is supplying another company a good used in production (such as a supplier of coal to an electric company), then.
Business Law: Ch 8 Consideration.
E- CONTRACTING MIDTERM(2). Definition E- Contract- a contract that is entered into in cyberspace and is evidenced only by electronic impulses (such as.
Section 13.2.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 10.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 12.
SUNK COSTS & THE EXTERNALITIES 1. Index 1. Sunk costs Sunk costs 2. Shubik’s Theory Shubik’s Theory 3. Ernest Dupuis III Ernest Dupuis III 4. Sunk costs.
The U. S. Economy: Private and Public Sectors
Hazards Liability and Tort Lecture 8. Outline Another economic role for the government is regulating hazards and risks Factory producing explosives (location.
1 Externality Here we study the situation where production leads to not only private costs, but also social costs.
Externalities 1. An externality is a situation where actions of one have impacts on others. Here we focus on negative externalities, where the impact.
Incomplete Contracts Renegotiation, Communications and Theory December 10, 2007.
Limits on Restoring Plaintiff to Rightful Position – Bargaining out of Rightful Position Default rules – rules a court applies to determine how to restore.
1 REMEDIES FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT. 2 When one of the parties to the contract makes a breach of the contract the following remedies are available to the.
Ch. 8: COMPENSATING WAGE DIFFERENTIALS AND LABOR MARKETS
Principles of Micro Chapter 10: Externalities by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 11.
Law and economics: game theory N.J. Philipsen Associate Professor of Law and Economics Faculty of Law, Research Institute METRO Shandong University, Jinan,
1 Ch. 2: Economic Activities: Producing and Trading James R. Russell, Ph.D., Professor of Economics & Management, Oral Roberts University ©2005 Thomson.
1 George Mason School of Law Contracts I K. PreliminaryNegotiations © F.H. Buckley
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 16.
What’s It Worth? - The Movies - CSX Business Explorer Post 333 December, 2010.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 10.
The Concept of “Present Value” o Trinity Church majority rejected argument that P’s damages should be reduced to their present value – What is that? Present.
What I’m going to say to your parents "Your son/daughter is failing. They cannot graduate unless they pass all their classes” - Reasons why failing: Participation?
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2011 Lecture 14.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 14.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 14.
Chapter 9 Mutual Consideration. Consideration Main purpose of consideration is to distinguish between social promises and more serious transactions where.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 10.
Ownership and Risk of Loss in Sales or Goods Ownership and Risk of Loss in Sales or Goods Section 13.1.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 4.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 14.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 10.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 16.
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 The Ethics of Manufacturing and Marketing.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2012 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2015 Lecture 14.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 15.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 9.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2013 Lecture 16.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 13.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 6.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 9.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 13.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2012 Lecture 10.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 12.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 12.
International Contracts Slide Set 9 Economic Optimization of Contract Law and Economics Bounded Rationality Matti Rudanko.
LEB Slide Set 7b Economic Optimization of Contract Law and Economics Bounded Rationality Matti Rudanko.
Ch. 7 Consumer Law and Contracts 7-1 Sales Contracts.
Reminder: midterm exam Wednesday
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2012 Lecture 12.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2017 Lecture 11.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2013 Lecture 12.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2016 Lecture 12.
Contract Law An Economic Theory of Contracts Transaction costs, complete contracts, default terms and perfect contracts 11/5/09 Contract_D.
Contract Law An Economic Theory of Contracts Reliance and optimal reliance 11/2/09 Contract_C.
Presentation transcript:

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 10

1  Office hours between now and midterm:  Me: Monday 1:30-3:30  Chao: today 1:00-3:00, Monday 10:00-1:30  Midterm #1 Tuesday, in class  No contract law Logistics

2  Why do we need contracts?  What promises should be enforced?  Bargain Theory of Contracts  Efficiency  First purpose of contract law: enable cooperation  Second purpose of contract law: encourage efficient disclosure of information  Third purpose of contract law: secure optimal commitment to performance (efficient breach)  Fourth purpose of contract law: secure optimal reliance Tuesday…

3 Efficient Breach

4 Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit  Efficient to Breach  Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit  Efficient to Perform  Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability  Promisor will Breach  Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability  Promisor will Perform  Self-Interest (incentives of promisor): Efficiency:

5  I build airplanes  You value one of my planes at $500,000  You agree to buy one for $350,000, and pay up front  After you pay, price of materials goes up Example of efficient breach Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000

6  Promisee’s benefit = $500,000  If it costs me less than $500,000 to build plane, efficient to build it  If it costs me more than $500,000, efficient to breach Example of efficient breach Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Promisor’s Cost Promisee’s Benefit  Efficient to Breach 

7  Liability is just to return your money  If my costs rise to $400,000, performance is still efficient, but I’ll choose to breach  Liability is $1,000,000  If costs rise to $700,000, performance is inefficient, but I’d rather perform than breach  Liability = promisee’s benefit ($500,000)  I’ll perform when performance is efficient, breach when breach is efficient Example of efficient breach Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000 Promisor’s Cost Promisor’s Liability  Promisor will Breach 

8  Liability is $350,000, my costs rise to $400,000  I’ll breach original contract, but we can renegotiate to higher price  But I might try to do that even if my costs don’t go up…  Liability is $1,000,000, my costs rise to $700,000  Rather than performing, I can offer you money to let me cancel contract  But my threat point is very low – you can demand a lot of money  If I realize that might happen, maybe I’m afraid to sign original contract  Expectation damages avoid these problems But so what? Can’t we just “Coase” back to efficiency? Value to you = $500,000 Price = $350,000

9  If I breach contract, I impose externality on you  You’re $500,000 worse off  If I have to pay you $500,000, then I internalize the externality  Now my action no longer affects your well-being  So I choose efficiently when deciding whether to perform or breach Another way to think about expectation damages: eliminating an externality

10 Reliance

11  Reliance: investments you make to increase your benefit from performance  Increases my liability if I breach  If expectation damages include added benefit due to reliance, leads to more than efficient level of reliance  There’s some chance I’ll need to breach the contract  Your reliance investments increase my liability from breach, so they impose a negative externality  Activities which impose negative externality happen too much  Overreliance Next: Reliance

12  Reliance increases your benefit from my promise  Airplane gives you benefit of $500,000  Costs $75,000 to build a hangar  Airplane with hangar gives you benefit of $600,000  Suppose price is $350,000, to be paid on delivery  Expectation damages restore you to well-being you expected to have from performance  Without a hangar, if I breach, I owe you $150,000  If you build a hangar and I breach, do I owe you $250,000? Reliance and Damages: example

13  Cost of building plane: maybe $250,000, maybe $700,000  Clearly, you’ll choose to build the hangar  But, is that efficient? Reliance and damages: example Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600, = 175 Costs rise = = = = 175 Costs stay low I getYou getI getYou get You don’tYou build hangar

14  Let p be probability my costs go up  Combined expected payoffs if you rely: (1 – p) ( ) + p (175 – 250) = 275 (1 – p) – 75 p = 275 – 350 p  Combined expected payoffs if you don’t rely: (1 – p) ( ) + p (150 – 150) = 250 (1 – p) = 250 – 250 p  Which is bigger? 275 – 350 p > 250 – 250 p  25 > 100 p  p < ¼  So if p ¼, it’s not  But you’re going to rely either way! Reliance and damages: example Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000

15  When probability of breach is low, more reliance tends to be efficient  When probability of breach is high, less reliance tends to be efficient  If expectation damages include increased benefit from reliance, we sometimes get overreliance  (OTOH, if expectation damages exclude increased benefit from reliance, liability < benefit, so inefficient breach) What do we learn?

16  Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance  Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well- being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount  So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance So what do we do?

17  Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance  Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of well- being he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount  So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance  Actual courts: include only foreseeable reliance  That is, if promisor could reasonably expect promisee to rely that much So what do we do?

18  1850s England  Hadley owned gristmill, mill shaft broke  Baxendale’s firm hired to transport shaft for repair  Baxendale shipped by boat instead of train, making it a week late  Hadley sued for the week’s lost profits  “The shipper assumed that Hadley, like most millers, kept a spare shaft. …Hadley did not inform him of the special urgency in getting the shaft repaired.”  Court listed several circumstances where broken shaft would not force mill to shut down  Ruled lost profits not foreseeable  Baxendale didn’t have to pay Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale

19 Default Rules

20  Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract  Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps Default rules

21  Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract  Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps  Writing something into a contract vs leaving a gap  Allocating a loss (ex post)  Versus allocating a risk (ex ante), before it becomes a loss Default rules

22  Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue  This will be whatever rule is efficient What should default rules be?

23  Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue  This will be whatever rule is efficient  Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules  Do this by imputing the terms the parties would have chosen if they had addressed this contingency What should default rules be?

24  Don’t want ambiguity in the law  So default rule can’t vary with every case  Majoritarian default rule: the terms that most parties would have agreed to  In cases where this rule is not efficient, parties can still override it in the contract  Court: figure out efficient allocation of risks, then (possibly) adjust prices to compensate Default rules

25  Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000  Construction company can hedge this risk for $400  Family can’t do anything about it  Price goes up – who pays for it? Default rules

26  Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000  Construction company can hedge this risk for $400  Family can’t do anything about it  Price goes up – who pays for it?  Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk  So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company  Should prices be adjusted to compensate? Default rules

27 Default rules  Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000  Construction company can hedge this risk for $400  Family can’t do anything about it  Price goes up – who pays for it?  Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk  So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company  Should prices be adjusted to compensate?

28  So, Cooter and Ulen say: set the default rule that’s efficient in the majority of cases  Most contracts can leave this gap, save on transaction costs  In cases where this rule is inefficient, parties can contract around it Default rules

29  Ian Ayres and Robert Gertner, “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules”  Sometimes better to make default rule something the parties would not have wanted  To give incentive to address an issue rather than leave a gap  Or to give one party incentive to disclose information  “Penalty default” Default rules: a different view

30  Baxendale (shipper) is only one who can influence when crankshaft is delivered; so he’s efficient bearer of risk  If default rule held Baxendale liable, Hadley has no need to tell him the shipment is urgent  So Hadley might hide this information, which is inefficient  Ayres and Gertner: Ruling in Hadley was a good one, not because it was efficient, but because it was inefficient…  …but in a way that created incentive for disclosing information Penalty defaults: Hadley v Baxendale

31  Real estate brokers and “earnest money”  Broker knows more about real estate law  Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this Penalty defaults: other examples

32  Real estate brokers and “earnest money”  Broker knows more about real estate law  Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this  Courts will impute missing price of a good, but not quantity  Forces parties to explicitly contract on quantity, rather than leave it for court to decide Penalty defaults: other examples

33  Look at why the parties left a gap in contract  Because of transaction costs  use efficient rule  For strategic reasons  penalty default may be more efficient  Similar logic in a Supreme Court dissent by Justice Scalia  Congress passed a RICO law without statute of limitations  Majority decided on 4 years – what they thought legislature would have chosen  Scalia proposed no statute of limitations; “unmoved by the fear that this… might prove repugnant to the genius of our law…”  “Indeed, it might even prompt Congress to enact a limitations period that it believes appropriate, a judgment far more within its competence than ours.” When to use penalty defaults?

34  Default rules can be contracted around  Some rules cannot – immutable rules, or mandatory rules, or regulations  Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules and regulations.  Coase: if individuals are rational and there are no transaction costs, private negotiations lead to efficiency  So additional regulations would just get in the way  So regulations only make sense when people are not rational, or when there are transaction costs/market failures Default rules versus regulations