Lecture 7 Price competition. Bertrand’s Model of Oligopoly Strategic variable price rather than output. Single good produced by n firms Cost to firm i.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Nash Equilibrium: Illustrations
Advertisements

Oligopoly A monopoly is when there is only one firm.
Strategic Pricing: Theory, Practice and Policy Professor John W. Mayo
The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry
Monopoly Standard Profit Maximization is max r(y)-c(y). With Monopoly this is Max p(y)y-c(y) (the difference to competition is price now depends upon output).
ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 9 office: LUMS C85.
© 2009 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Game theory The study of multiperson decisions Four types of games Static games.
Stackelberg -leader/follower game 2 firms choose quantities sequentially (1) chooses its output; then (2) chooses it output; then the market clears This.
Part 8 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
MICROECONOMICS EV Prof. Davide Vannoni. Exercise session 4 monopoly and deadweight loss 1.Exercise on monopoly and deadweight loss 2.Exercise on natural.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
OT Anticompetitive consequence of the nationalization of a public enterprise in a mixed duopoly.
Game Theory: An Introduction Text: An Introduction to Game Theory by Martin J. Osborne.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Models for Interactions of Small Numbers of Firms.
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Bertrand Model Matilde Machado. Matilde Machado - Industrial Economics3.4. Bertrand Model2 In Cournot, firms decide how much to produce and the.
Simultaneous games with continuous strategies Suppose two players have to choose a number between 0 and 100. They can choose any real number (i.e. any.
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Strategic Pricing Techniques.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
Lectures in Microeconomics-Charles W. Upton Duopoly.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27 Oligopoly.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Chapter 10: Price Competition
Bertrand Duopoly.
OLIGOPOLY Managerial Economics Lecturer: Jack Wu.
Competition And Market Structure
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Nash equilibrium Nash equilibrium is defined in terms of strategies, not payoffs Every player is best responding simultaneously (everyone optimizes) This.
Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Static Games and Cournot Competition.
Lecture 4 Strategic Interaction Game Theory Pricing in Imperfectly Competitive markets.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
Today n Oligopoly Theory n Economic Experiment in Class.
Lecture 6 Cournot oligopoly. Cournot’s Model of Oligopoly Single good produced by n firms Cost to firm i of producing q i units: C i (q i ), where C i.
Lecture 8 Product differentiation. Standard models thus far assume that every firm is producing a homogenous good; that is, the product sold by In the.
1 Chapter 10 Price Competition 2 In a wide variety of markets firms compete in prices –Internet access –Restaurants –Consultants –Financial services.
Chapter 11 The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry.
Dynamic games, Stackelburg Cournot and Bertrand
Chapter 26 Oligopoly, mainly Duopoly. Quantity or price competitions. Sequential games. Backward solution. Identical products: p = p (Y ), Y = y 1 + y.
CHAPTER 27 OLIGOPOLY.
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the oligopoly model(II): competition in prices ………….1price competition: introduction.
Today n Oligopoly Theory n Economic Experiment in Class.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Lecture 6 Oligopoly 1. 2 Introduction A monopoly does not have to worry about how rivals will react to its action simply because there are no rivals.
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 13 Oligopoly.
ECON 330 Lecture 13 Tuesday, November 6.
Chapter 10: Price Competition
Static Games and Cournot Competition
27 Oligopoly.
Chapter 28 Oligopoly.
Games Of Strategy Chapter 4 Dixit, Skeath, and Reiley
Today Oligopoly Theory Economic Experiment in Class.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
BUS 525: Managerial Economics Basic Oligopoly Models
Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
Lecture 10 The Bertrand Model
Tutorial 3: Market Failures
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly.
Profit Maximization What is the goal of the firm?
N-player Cournot Econ 414.
Presentation transcript:

Lecture 7 Price competition

Bertrand’s Model of Oligopoly Strategic variable price rather than output. Single good produced by n firms Cost to firm i of producing q i units: C i (q i ), where C i is nonnegative and increasing If price is p, demand is D(p) Consumers buy from firm with lowest price Firms produce what is demanded

Bertrand’s Model of Oligopoly Strategic game: players: firms each firm’s set of actions: set of all possible prices each firm’s preferences are represented by its profit

Example: Duopoly 2 firms C i (q i ) = cq i for i = 1, 2 D(p) =  − p Profit function is discontinuous, so we cannot use calculus to solve. A best response function does not exist. Solution method: “see” the solution by logic, prove that it is a solution, prove that no other solution exists.

Example: Duopoly Nash Equilibrium (p 1, p 2 ) = (c, c) If each firm charges a price of c then the other firm can do no better than charge a price of c also (if it raises its price it sells no output, while if it lowers its price it makes a loss), so (c, c) is a Nash equilibrium.

Example: Duopoly No other pair (p 1, p 2 ) is a Nash equilibrium since If p i < c then the firm whose price is lowest (or either firm, if the prices are the same) can increase its profit (to zero) by raising its price to c If p i = c and p j > c then firm i is better off increasing its price slightly if p i ≥ p j > c then firm i can increase its profit by lowering p i to some price between c and p j (e.g. to slightly below p j if D(p j ) > 0 or to p m if D(p j ) = 0).

Duopoly with different MCs Now take the same example, but suppose that the two firms have different marginal costs. As before, D(P) = α – P But now: C 1 (q 1 ) = c 1 q 1, but C 2 (q 2 ) = c 2 q 2. Assume c 1 > c 2. Now, no Nash equilibrium exists. Clearly, any outcome where p 1 < c 1 or where p 2 < c 2 is not an equilibrium (at least one firm will earn negative profits and can profitably deviate). Any outcome where min[p 1,p 2 ] > c 1 is not an equilibrium; at least one firm could increase their profit by lowering their price. p 1 = p 2 = c 1 is not an equilibrium; firm 2 could profitably lower their price. p 1 ≥ c 1, p 2 < c 1 is not an equilibrium; firm 2 could increase their price and increase its profit. Thus, no equilibrium exists.

Differentiated product Bertrand Cost functions as before (C(q) = cq), but now demand function is q i = α – p i + bp j, where α > c, 0 < b < 2. Firm 1 and 2 choose prices simultaneously. So, now we have a well-behaved problem with continuous profit functions, and well-defined best response functions. Firm 1 solves: max p1 (α – p 1 + bp 2 )(p 1 – c) This gives FOC: α – 2p 1 + bp 2 + c = 0 So BR 1 : p 1 = (α + bp 2 + c)/2 By symmetry, BR 2 : p 2 = (α + bp 1 + c)/2 Solve these simultaneously to find NE. p 1 = [α + b((α + bp 1 + c)/2 + c]/2 By some algebra, this gives the NE: p 1 * = (α + c)/(2-b) = p 2 * (by symmetry).

Differentiated product Bertrand Notice that, given our assumptions on α and b, this price is very clearly > c. So, moving to a differentiated product environment, we have got away from the result that we can get competitive prices with only 2 firms from a Bertrand competition model. In the real world, virtually all products are differentiated to some extent.

Strategic complements vs substitutes Depending on the particular structure of a game, variables can be strategic substitutes or complements, based on the slope of the best response function. Strategies are strategic substitutes if in response to another player increasing their strategy, I wish to reduce mine. Strategies are strategic complements if in response to another player increasing their strategy, I wish to increase mine. Cournot: BR i : q i = (α - c – q j )/2. The BR of firm i is decreasing in the choice variable of firm j, so quantity is a strategic substitute. (Differentiated) Bertrand: BR i p i = (α + bp j + c)/2. The BR of firm i is increasing in the choice variable of firm j, so price is a strategic complement.