Common Value Auctions 1. Coin auction What’s for sale: the coins in this jar. Second price sealed bid auction. Write down your bid. 2.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Yossi Sheffi Mass Inst of Tech Cambridge, MA ESD.260J/1.260J/15.
Advertisements

Auctions An auction is a mechanism for trading items by means of bidding. Dates back to 500 BC where Babylonians auctioned off women as wives. (Herodotus)
(Single-item) auctions Vincent Conitzer v() = $5 v() = $3.
CPS Bayesian games and their use in auctions Vincent Conitzer
Economics 100B u Instructor: Ted Bergstrom u T.A. Oddgeir Ottesen u Syllabus online at (Class pages) Or at
1 Auctioning Many Similar Items Lawrence Ausubel and Peter Cramton Department of Economics University of Maryland.
Auctions. Strategic Situation You are bidding for an object in an auction. The object has a value to you of $20. How much should you bid? Depends on auction.
Chapter 25: Auctions and Auction Markets 1 Auctions and Auction Markets.
Bidding Strategy and Auction Design Josh Ruffin, Dennis Langer, Kevin Hyland and Emmet Ferriter.
Auctions Auction types: –First price, sealed bid auction –Second price, sealed bid auction –English auction (ascending bid auction) –Dutch auction (descending.
1 Project 2 Bidding on an Oil lease. 2 Project 2- Description Bidding on an Oil lease Business Background Class Project.
Econ 805 Advanced Micro Theory 1 Dan Quint Fall 2007 Lecture 2 – Sept
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Game Theory “A cynic knows the price of everything and the value of nothing” - Oscar Wilde, Lady Windemere’s Fan Mike Shor Lecture 11.
Welcome Auctions Jonathan D. Wareham
1 Chapter 6: Auctions SCIT1003 Chapter 6: Auctions Prof. Tsang.
Auction. Types of Auction  Open outcry English (ascending) auction Dutch (descending) auction  Sealed bid First-price Second-price (Vickrey)  Equivalence.
Auctions Ruth Tarrant. Classifying auctions What is the nature of the good being auctioned? What are the rules of bidding? Private value auction Common.
Auction Theory.
The Economics of Information
Liz DiMascio Paige Warren- Shriner Mitch Justus DUTCH AND ENGLISH AUCTIONS IN RELATION TO THE TULIP MARKET.
Common Value Auctions 1. Coin auction What’s for sale: the coins in this jar. We’ll run an ascending auction 2.
Multi-Unit Auctions 1. Many auctions involve the sale of multiple similar or identical units. Cases of wine at an auction house, carbon permits, shares.
1 of 22 Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall · Economics · R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 3e. Chapter 17: The.
Project: – Several options for bid: Bid our signal Develop several strategies Develop stable bidding strategy Simulating Normal Random Variables.
Sponsored Search Auctions 1. 2 Traffic estimator.
1 Teck-Hua Ho April 18, 2006 Auction Design I. Economic and Behavioral Foundations of Pricing II. Innovative Pricing Concepts and Tools III. Internet Pricing.
Chapter Seventeen Auctions. Who Uses Auctions? u Owners of art, cars, stamps, machines, mineral rights etc. u Q: Why auction? u A: Because many markets.
Project 2 Introduction. Auctions Common way to sell Different types: - First-price sealed-bid - Second-price sealed-bid - English (open outcry) - Dutch.
1 Teck-Hua Ho April 22, 2006 Auction Design I. Economic and Behavioral Foundations of Pricing II. Innovative Pricing Concepts and Tools III. Internet Pricing.
Common Value Auctions Professor Susan Athey Market Design Spring 2010.
Auction Design for Atypical Situations. Overview General review of common auctions General review of common auctions Auction design for agents with hard.
Auctions Hal R. Varian. Auctions Auctions are very useful mean of price discovery eBay: everyone’s favorite example DoveBid: high value asset sales at.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Week 11 1 COS 444 Internet Auctions: Theory and Practice Spring 2008 Ken Steiglitz
and Lecture Notes in Game Theory1 Game Theory Applications: Lecture Notes Course Website u Galina.
This Week’s Topics  Review Class Concepts -Auctions, continued -Repeated Games -Bertrand Trap & Anti-Trust -Auctions.
Introduction to Game Theory
Chapter 17: The Economics of Information © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. 1 of 21 Asymmetric.
Games People Play. 12: Auctions Games People Play. Auctions In this section we shall learn How different types of auctions allocate goods How to buy.
Auctions and Bidding. 2 Auction Theory Auction theory is important for practical reason empirical reason –testing-ground for economic theory, especially.
© 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 17 The.
Auctions Shyam Sunder, Yale University Kozminski Academy Warsaw, June 22, 2013.
Steffen Staab 1WeST Web Science & Technologies University of Koblenz ▪ Landau, Germany Network Theory and Dynamic Systems Auctions.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Auction Services Alkera, Inc. Proprietary & Confidential June 25, 2003 Energy Auction Alternatives Sam Dinkin Chief Economist.
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics Hubbard/O’Brien UPDATE EDITION. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 17 The Economics of Information.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Auctions Great Lakes Institute of Management, Chennai March 4, 2012.
Incomplete Information and Bayes-Nash Equilibrium.
Advanced Subjects in GT Prepared by Rina Talisman Introduction Revenue Equivalence The Optimal Auction (Myerson 1981) Auctions.
Lecture 4 on Auctions Multiunit Auctions We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling.
1 Types of Auctions English auction –ascending-price, open-outcry Dutch auction –descending-price, open-outcry 1 st price sealed bid auction –known as.
Shyam Sunder, Yale University Kozminski Academy Warsaw, June 23, 2012
Auctions and Competitive Bidding
Economics 100C April 6, 2010.
Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie Mellon University
Bidding on an Antique.
Internet Economics כלכלת האינטרנט
Auction Theory.
Auctions: Basic Theory & Applications
Economics 100C.
Auctions An auction is a mechanism for trading items by means of bidding. Dates back to 500 BC where Babylonians auctioned of women as wives. Position.
Auctions and Bargaining
International Trade and Tariff
Economics 100C: April 8, 2010 April 8, 2010.
Class 2 – Revenue equivalence
Presentation transcript:

Common Value Auctions 1

Coin auction What’s for sale: the coins in this jar. Second price sealed bid auction. Write down your bid. 2

Coin auction What’s for sale: the coins in this jar. Second price sealed bid auction. What if one person gets to count the coins. Does this change your bid? Why? 3

The winner’s curse Winning the jar means that everyone else in the class was more pessimistic about its contents. Winning is “bad news” If you had an initial estimate of $10, seeing everyone else drop out first (especially the person with good information!) should cause you to revise your estimate downward. Equilibrium bidding should account for this. 4

Common Value Auctions Today we will look at “common value” auction settings, where bidders have differential information about the value of the item being sold. Three main issues Strategic bidding and the winner’s curse Information aggregation and “price discovery” Selling strategies and information disclosure 5

Imperfect Estimate Model Two bidders with common value v. v is drawn at random from a known distribution. Bidder 1 receives a “signal” s 1 (correlated with v) Bidder 2 receives a signal s 2 Signals provide information about v, but not perfect. Second price sealed bid, or ascending auction How should bidders account for the winner’s curse? 6

Equilibrium bidding Let p(s) = E[v|s i =s and s j =s] = E[v|s,s] (increasing in s) Claim: In the equilibrium of the ascending auction, bidder i should drop out at the price p(s i )=E[v|s i,s i ]. Explanation: If both bidders follow strategy, then if j drops out first, i is happy. Why? This means that s j < s i, and auction price is p(s j )=E[v|s j,s j ]. So i expects a profit because E[v|s i,s j ] > E[v|s j,s j ] = p(s j ). But if i was to stay in too long and win at p>p(s i ), she’d be unhappy. Why? This means that s j > s i, and auction price is p(s j )=E[v|s j,s j ]. So i expects a loss because E[v|s i,s j ] < E[v|s j,s j ] = p(s j ). 7

Second price / Ascending Auction 01 p(s i ) Strategy: bid p(s i ) =E[v|s i,s i ] 8 If opponent drops out here, win and pay p(s j ). p(s j )=E[v|s j,s j ] for s j <s i. As E[v|s i,s j ]>E[v|s j,s j ], expected value is greater than payment, so make a profit from winning. If opponent drops out here, win and pay p(s j ). p(s j )=E[v|s j,s j ] for s j >s i. As E[v|s i,s j ]<E[v|s j,s j ], expected value is less than payment, so would make a loss from winning.

Derivation of equilibrium Consider candidate equilibrium in which a bidder with signal s i plans to drop out at b(s i ), where b is increasing in s i. So bidders stay in longer with higher estimates. If i wins at price p, then j had a signal s j such that p=b(s j ), or s j =b -1 (p). So i’s expected profit is E[v|s i,s j =b -1 (p)]-p. If it is optimal for i to drop out at b(s i ), then i must want to win at any lower price and not win at any higher price, so at p= b(s i ), we must have E[v|s i,s j =b -1 (p)]=p. Substituting for p, we get b(s i )=E[v|s i,s j =s i ]. 9

Winner’s or Loser’s Curse? How does accounting for the information of other’s affect your estimate of the item value? Case 1: 10 bidders, 1 item. Winning means other signals were all lower. Case 2: 10 bidders, 9 items. Losing means other signals were all higher. 10

Not just uncertainty The logic of common values comes from the fact that other bidders may have information that is relevant for your value, not just from the value being uncertain. Suppose we’re bidding for the jar of coins… I know there are exactly 650 pennies. But I think there’s a fifty percent chance I’ll lose the jar. My value of winning is less than 650 ($3.25 if risk-neutral). But I don’t care about the other bidders’ estimates (except insofar as bidders with high estimates drive up the auction price). 11

Revenue equivalence? If bidders have “correlated” estimates of a common value item, an open auction leads to higher revenue than sealed bid auction. (Paul Milgrom and Robert Weber) Idea In either case, the high estimate bidder will win. In a first price sealed bid auction, the payment will be a function of the winner’s estimate, but given the winner’s estimate, it won’t depend on the estimate of the second highest bidder. In an ascending auction, the payment will depend on the second highest estimate, which is correlated with the winner’s estimate. This “linkage” reduces the winner’s profit and increases revenue! 12

Providing Information to Bidders Deciding how much information to provide to bidders – e.g. what information to disclose if you are selling a house, or a company – can be a tricky issue. Milgrom-Weber “linkage principle” – under certain conditions seller should provide information to alleviate the winner’s curse and connect the price more closely to the true value. In other cases, giving bidders the opportunity to become informed can create informational asymmetries – seller does better to keep bidders in the dark. 13

De Beers Diamond Example De Beers sells a large fraction of the world’s uncut diamonds: at one point, 85%. It sells these diamonds at regularly scheduled “sights”. Each buyer is given a box of diamonds and a price. He or she must decide whether to buy the whole box at that price. What is the rationale for having so little inspection and pricing of individual items? 14 De Beers “sight” boxes

Information aggregation How many miles is it to drive from New York to Chicago? Answer 15

Information aggregation Suppose we have many bidders, and each has an independent estimate s i = v+e i. Median of the bidder’s estimates s i is likely to be a very good estimate of v. Why? Median(s i ) = Median(v+e i ) = v+Median(e i ) ≈ v. “The wisdom of crowds”; Galton example. 16

Information aggregation Suppose we have many bidders, and each has an independent estimate s i = v+e i. If many bidders compete in an auction, is the resulting price a good estimate of v? Potentially YES!, auction price can aggregate information. First shown by Stanford profs. Wilson, Milgrom. Let’s go through a somewhat loose sketch of the argument. 17

Why Information Aggregation? Assume N bidders, K=N/2 items, top K bids win and pay K+1 st bid. Equilibrium bidding: bid so that if you “just” win, you’ll “just” want to win (else should raise/lower bid). b(s i ) = E[v|s i is tied for Kth highest of N]  E[v | s i is median signal] (assume N large) = E[v | v+median(e)= s i ] = s i Price will be b(s K+1 )=s K+1, where s K+1 is K+1 st highest signal. So the auction price will be approximately the median signal! 18

Information Aggregation If value if v, signals will be distributed around v – and if there are enough bidders, the true value will be close to the median signal. vL 19 vH

Common values in practice Many auctions have some “common value” aspect Treasury bill auctions – everyone may have a guess about the trading price after the auction, but no one knows for sure. Same for IPOs and new debt issuance. Timber auctions: what kind of timber is actually out there on the tract that’s being sold. Oil lease auctions: oil is under the Gulf of Mexico, bidders do independent seismic studies – each has valuable information. 20

OCS Auctions The US government auctions the right to drill for oil on the outer continental shelf. Value of oil is similar to the different bidders, but no one knows how much oil there is, or if there’s none. Prior to the auction, the bidders do seismic studies. Two kinds of sale “Wildcat sale” - new territory being sold “Drainage sale” - territory adjacent to existing tract. These are like the “wallet auctions” we ran in class! 21

Wildcat vs Drainage 22

Drainage sales 23

Explaining the Results Comparing wildcat and drainage sales Wildcat sales yield low profits => competition. Drainage sales are profitable, but only for “insiders” => insiders have an advantage. 24

Internet Advertising Internet advertisers often can identify people or profile their behavior and then bid to show them ads. Concern in some advertising auctions Sophisticated advertisers potentially can “cherry-pick” the best opportunities by bidding high only for those impressions. Less sophisticated advertisers who submit the same bid for good and bad opportunities might be left with only the bad ones. Example: the Yahoo! - “Happy Meal” contract. 25

Akerlof Lemons Model Note the parallel with the Akerlof lemons model... Seller has a car that is either a “peach” or a “lemon” Seller values a peach at 80 and a lemon at 20. Buyer values a peach at 100 and a lemon at 50. Ideally, car would trade either way, at a price either between 80 and 100, or between 20 and 50. But what if seller knows the value and buyer doesn’t? For concreteness, assume that peach/lemon equally likely. 26

Lemons model, cont. Recall buyer values are 100/50, sellers are 80/20. At a price p>80, seller will sell even if the car is a peach. But buyer won’t pay 80 for a 50/50 chance at a peach. At a price p<80, seller will only sell if the car is a lemon. Knowing this, buyer will only be willing to pay 50. So market price will be between 20 and 50 and only lemons will trade. How does this story connect with common value model? 27

Summary Many auctions have a “common value” flavor. In common value settings: The event of winning reveals information about opponent estimates, and bidders must account for this. Auctions that aggregate participant information into the price can yield more revenue. If there are many bidders, the resulting price can be a useful indicator of the item’s value. The distribution of information is very important. 28