ECON 330 Lecture 13 Wednesday, November 6.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Games with continuous payoffs. The Cournot game In all the games discussed so far, firms had a discrete set of choices (high – medium – low, enter – not.
Advertisements

Strategic Pricing: Theory, Practice and Policy Professor John W. Mayo
office hours: 8:00AM – 8:50AM tuesdays LUMS C85
Cournot Oligopoly and Welfare by Kevin Hinde. Aims F In this session we will explore the interdependence between firms using the Cournot oligopoly models.
Chapter 12 Oligopoly. Chapter 122 Oligopoly – Characteristics Small number of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist Barriers to entry.
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Ten.
Price-Output Determination in Oligopolistic Market Structures We have good models of price- output determination for the structural cases of pure competition.
Week 13 Managerial Economics. Order of Business Homework Assigned Lectures Other Material Lectures for Next Week.
Yale lectures 5 and 6 Nash Equilibrium – no individual can do strictly better by deviating – self enforcing in agreements Investment game – all invest.
18. Oligopoly Varian, Chapter 27.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models.
Antoine Augustin Cournot
Chapter 9 – Profit maximization
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Lectures in Microeconomics-Charles W. Upton Duopoly.
1 Oligopoly. 2 By the end of this Section, you should be able to: Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly.
Bertrand Duopoly.
Lecture 10: The Theory of Competitive Supply
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Welcome! Professoressa Maria Covadonga de la Iglesia Villasol, Departamento de Fundamentos del Análisis Económico I,
Market structure and competition By A.V. Vedpuriswar.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Static Games and Cournot Competition.
CHAPTER 12 Imperfect Competition. The profit-maximizing output for the monopoly 2 If there are no other market entrants, the entrepreneur can earn monopoly.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
Roadmap: So far, we’ve looked at two polar cases in market structure spectrum: Competition Monopoly Many firms, each one “small” relative to industry;
Oligopoly: Interdependence and Collusion Industrial Economics.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey.
© 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R Oligopoly.
Chapter 11 The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry.
Pashigian, Chapter 10, Exercise 3. Since marginal cost is zero, I assume each firm can produce the entire market demand. This sounds to me like a "winner.
Chapter 6 Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
1 GAME THEORY AND INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS (ORGANIZATION) FIRMS’ STRATEGIC BEHAVIOUR Strategic interaction among economic agents (a sort of externality: the.
University of Papua New Guinea Principles of Microeconomics Lecture 13: Oligopoly.
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the oligopoly model(II): competition in prices ………….1price competition: introduction.
Today n Oligopoly Theory n Economic Experiment in Class.
Oligopoly Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers, when.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University The Mechanics of Profit Maximization 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Lecture 6 Oligopoly 1. 2 Introduction A monopoly does not have to worry about how rivals will react to its action simply because there are no rivals.
ECON 330 Lecture 11 Wednesday, October 30.
ECON 330 Lecture 17 Monday, November 25.
ECON 100 Lecture 11 Wednesday, October 22.
ECON 330 Lecture 11 Tuesday, October 30.
ECON 330 Lecture 21 Monday, December 9.
ECON 330 Lecture 26 Thursday, December 27.
Econ 330 Lecture 16 Wednesday, November 20.
Competition.
ECON 330 Lecture 8 Thursday, October 11.
ECON 330 Lecture 13 Tuesday, November 6.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
ECON 330 Lecture 10.5 Tuesday, October 23.
ECON 330 Lecture 23 Monday, December 16.
ECON 330 Lecture 14 Monday, November 9.
ECON 100 Lecture 16 Wednesday, November 12.
Oligopolistic Conduct and Welfare
Perfect Competition: Short Run and Long Run
27 Oligopoly.
Chapter 16: Oligopoly.
Chapter 28 Oligopoly.
Today Oligopoly Theory Economic Experiment in Class.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
CHAPTER 12 OUTLINE Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Price Competition Competition versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma 12.5.
Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Dynamic games and First and Second Movers (The Stackelberg Model)
Profit maximization.
Lecture 10 The Bertrand Model
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly.
Presentation transcript:

ECON 330 Lecture 13 Wednesday, November 6

The midterm exam is next week! Time: Wednesday November 13, 9:00 to 10:45. Place: Engineering Auditorium ENG Z50 This will be an easy, straightforward exam.

The midterm exam is next week! You may use a simple calculator. Bring your own! No sharing! No smart-phones please.

This one is not allowed

This one is OK

Office hours for the exam THIS WEEK Today 1 30 PM to 3 30 PM Thursday 1 30 PM to 3 30 PM NEXT WEEK Monday 1 30 PM to 3 30 PM Tuesday 11 00 to 12 15, and 1 30 PM to 3 30 PM

also … NEXT WEEK Pınar Önen (our TA) will hold a problem solving session for the exam. Time: Tuesday Nov 12, 3 30 to 4 45 PM Place: Room CASE B 38 (or 39?)

A few words on Monday lecture Price competition with 2 firms Demand for Firm 1: q1 = 10–p1+0.5p2 Demand for Firm 2: q2 = 10–p2+0.5p1 Cost functions: Firm 1: c(q) = 3q Firm 2: c(q) = q

We computed the Nash equilibrium prices pNE1 and pNE2

Definition of the Nash equilibrium prices π1(pNE1, pNE2) ≥ π1(p1, pNE2) for any p1 π2(pNE1, pNE2) ≥ π2(pNE1, p2) for any p2

A nice interpretation of Nash equilibrium: we can imagine that… a Nash equilibrium is a “law” no one wants to break (unilaterally, by themselves) even in the absence of an effective police force. So, if the “law” says that firm 1 must set p1 = pNE1 and firm 2 must set p2= pNE2 then no firm will want to break this law as long as the other firm follows the law.

But this is not how the analysis of oligopoly competition got started in the first part of the 19th century

Now, back to the beginnings.. Augustine Cournot, and the “Cournot equilibrium” “L'équilibre de Cournot”

In his HEA (his 1000+ pages long, unfinished book) Joseph Schumpeter wrote this: “[Cournot’s result is] the backbone of all further work in oligopoly.” In its many variations Cournot’s model has been used to address an astonishing range of questions in industrial economics.

Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801-1877) The first scholar to apply mathematics to economics in a serious way. His book ''Researches Into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth'' was published in 1838.

Andrew Carnegie (1835 - 1919), “the richest man in the world”, once said: ‘It does not pay to pioneer’ Cournot’s life and work is possibly the best illustration of this. Cournot was a true pioneer, and as such, was neglected in his time. The impact of his work on modern economics cannot be overstated.

So, here is the Cournot model of oligopoly competition

The “original” Cournot model Cournot considers the case of two profit-maximizing spring water suppliers who sell bottles of identical quality at zero costs.

Cournot’s spring water duopoly

The Cournot model, continued The market demand for spring water is negatively sloped. Firms choose output levels simultaneously and independently.

Now, the confusing part: Once the firms choose quantities, the price adjusts so as to clear the market: that means the quantity demanded equals the total quantity produced by the two firms.

Who sets the market price? The firms choose their quantities, the price adjusts (by some magic mechanism) to clear the market. Example: The market demand is Q(p) = 12 – p. If q1 = 2, and q2 = 5, then the price that clears the market is… p = 5. If q1 = 5, and q2 = 2,

Assumption 1 Firms choose output levels simultaneously. What if firms choose quantities sequentially? For example first firm 1 then firm 2?

Assumption 2 Firms compete by choosing quantities (not prices). Some refer to the Cournot model as “quantity competition”. What happens when the two firms announce prices and then meet whatever demand they receive?

The truth is that this is not exactly what Cournot wrote in Chapter VII in that famous book

In chapter V titled “of monopoly”, he studied a … monopoly supplier of mineral water who picks the price to maximize profit. In chapter VII titled “of competition of producers” he wrote …

Let us now imagine two proprietors and two springs of which the qualities are identical and which on account of their similar positions supply the same market in competition. In this case the price is necessarily the same for each proprietor. If p is this price, D = F(p) the total sales, D1 the sales from the spring (1), and D2 the sales from the spring (2), then D1 + D2 = D.

If, to begin with, we neglect the cost of production, the respective incomes of the proprietors will be pD1 and pD2 and… each of them independently will seek to make this income as large as possible. Instead of adopting D = F(p) as before, in this case it will be convenient to adopt the inverse notation p = f(D).

So far, so good. But here comes the troubling part…

Proprietor (1) can have no direct influence on the determination of D2 Proprietor (1) can have no direct influence on the determination of D2. All that he can do when D2 has been determined by proprietor (2) is to choose for D1 the value which is best for him. This he will be able to accomplish by properly adjusting his price,… except as proprietor (2), who seeing himself forced to accept this price and this value of D1, may adopt a new value for D2 more favorable to his interests than the preceding one.

So, it was not clear what Cournot had in mind So, it was not clear what Cournot had in mind! Is it a … dynamic model in which firms adjust their choices in response to their rival’s earlier choices so that this process terminates at some point where no further adjustments are needed Or is it a … static model in which quantities are chosen simultaneously and once and for all.

And also.. Why say something like “proprietor (1) adjust his price…”

The modern approach. Use Nash’s method The modern approach. Use Nash’s method. Firms make their quantity decisions simultaneously. Focus on the Nash equilibrium quantities.

Definition of the Nash equilibrium quantities π1(qNE1, qNE2) ≥ π1(q1, qNE2) for any q1 π2(qNE1, qNE2) ≥ π2(qNE1, q2) for any q2

This is all too abstract Let’s do an example.

An example Demand Q(P) = 12 – P; Inverse demand P(Q) = 12 – Q q1 : output level of firm 1; q2 : output level of firm 2 For both firms all costs are zero. (In memory of Cournot) P is determined by Q = q1 + q2, so  We can write P = 12 – (q1 + q2) Firm 1 chooses q1 to maximize {12 – (q1 + q2)}xq1 Firm 2 chooses q2 to maximize {12 – (q1 + q2)}xq2

Firm 1 Profit table q2 , your rival’s quantity q1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 11 10 20 18 16 14 12 27 24 21 15 32 28 -4 35 30 25 -5 -10 36 -6 -12 -18 -7 -14 -21 -28 -8 -16 -24 -32 -40 -9 -27 -36 -45 -54 q1

Firm 2 Profit table q1 , your rival’s quantity q2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 11 10 20 18 16 14 12 27 24 21 15 32 28 -4 35 30 25 -5 -10 36 -6 -12 -18 -7 -14 -21 -28 -8 -16 -24 -32 -40 -9 -27 -36 -45 -54 q2

Computing the Cournot-Nash equilibrium Start with firm 1. Write the profit function (remember: all costs are zero) π1(q1 , q2) = P x q1 P = 12 – Q, and Q = q1 + q2. P = 12 – (q1 + q2) π1(q1 , q2) = {12 – (q1 + q2)} x q1 Differentiate π1 with respect to q1, and , set equal to 0: dπ1/dq1 = 12 – 2q1 – q2 = 0 Best response function for firm 1: q1 = 6 – q2/2

By definition of the Nash equilibrium, we must have q1 = 6 – qNE2/2 π1(qNE1, qNE2) ≥ π1(q1, qNE2) for any q1

By definition of the Nash equilibrium, we must have qNE1 = 6 – qNE2/2 Both firms have the same cost function (zero cost), so, it is most likely that in the Nash Equilibrium we have qNE1 = qNE2 Use qNE1 = qNE2 And … qNE1 = qNE2 = 4. In the Nash equilibrium each firm will produce 4 units of output.

qNE1 = 4, and qNE2 = 4 (and P = 4) These are the Nash equilibrium quantities of the Cournot model. The Nash Equilibrium is a law that no one wants to break alone even without enforcement. If q2 = 4, the best (profit maximizing) quantity for firm 1 is q1 = 4.

Consider this: Both firms can make more profit by producing a smaller quantity each, say 3 units. Suppose the law says that each firm must produce 3 units. This law must be enforced by punishing violations. Why? If q2 = 3, the best quantity for firm 1 is q1 = 4,5 (not 3) So unless there is police force that punishes firms that produce more than 3 units, this is not going to be self-sustaining situation.

Your turn now

Both firms have the same cost function: TC(q) = 30q Both firms have the same cost function: TC(q) = 30q. The inverse demand function is p(Q) = 120–Q, where Q is the total output. Compute the Nash equilibrium output levels and the price of the Cournot model. Don’t panic HELP is coming (see next slide)

Cost function: C(q) = 30q. The inverse demand p = 120–Q. A. Write the profit function for firm 1 as a function of q1 and q2. (remember: Q = q1 + q2) B. Find the best response function for firm 1. C. Firms have identical cost functions, so the Nash equilibrium output levels,q1* and q2*, will be the same for both firms. Use q1* = q2* in the best response function and compute q1*. You are done.

End of the lecture.