Alan S. Blinder Brookings Institution and Princeton University

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Discussion of Michael Ehrmann’s “Targeting Inflation from Below: How Do Inflation Expectations Behave?” Reflections on 25 Years of Inflation Targeting.
Advertisements

The stagnation regime of the new keynesian model and current US policy George Evans Discussion Frank Smets Asset prices, credit and macroeconomic policies.
Alan S. Blinder Princeton University Burt Malkiel Conference April 8, 2011 Rethinking Monetary Policy in a Very Low Inflation Environment.
Workshop, Fall 2005 Inflation Persistence and the Taylor Rule Christian Murray, David Papell, and Oleksandr Rzhevskyy.
Federal Reserve and Monetary Policy. Formal Structure of the Fed THE FEDERAL RESERVE (FED)
Chapter 18. Conduct of Monetary Policy Goals of monetary policy Using targets A History of monetary policy Policy Rules Goals of monetary policy Using.
Connecting Money and Prices: Irving Fisher’s Quantity Equation M × V = P × Y The Quantity Theory of Money V = Velocity of money The average number of times.
The Relationship Between Inflation and Unemployment An inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment until the 1970s 1970s  high inflation and.
What Caused the Decline in U. S. Business Cycle Volatility? Robert J. Gordon Northwestern University Presented at Reserve Bank of Australia, July 11, 2005.
Chapter 21. Stabilization policy with rational expectations
Chapter 16: Inflation, Unemployment, and Federal Reserve Policy © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien,
The Relationship Between Inflation and Unemployment
The Post-FOMC Post Mortem: QE not so Mortem 2013 Gulf Power Economic Symposium Sandestin, FL September 30, 2013.
Discussion of “Forward Guidance by Inflation-Targeting Central Banks” By Michael Woodford Sveriges Riksbank Conference “Two Decades of Inflation Targeting:
The Federal Reserve How our Central Bank is structured.
Norges Bank 1 Monetary policy framework in Norway Øistein Røisland Norges Bank.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 21 Monetary Policy Strategy.
Macroeconomics Chapter 151 Money and Business Cycles I: The Price-Misperceptions Model C h a p t e r 1 5.
BY: DALAL ALARBEED Effective Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 29 Monetary Policy.
AP STATISTICS LESSON 10 – 2 DAY 1 TEST OF SIGNIFICANCE.
1 Taylor Rule and the Term Structure Objectives: 1.To understand the relation between central bank policy and long term interest rates. 2.Understand “news”
Central Bank Independence: An Economists’ Idea That Shaped the World?
Alternative Inflation Measures. Comparison: core vs. overall Overall measures: very volatile, especially because of food & energy shocks Core = excluding.
Money and Banking Lecture 45. Review of the Previous Lecture Long-run Aggregate Supply Curve Equilibrium and Determination of Output and Inflation Impact.
1.  Recap of the housing crisis, and review of a few subprime myths and facts  Quick look at the current state of the housing markets  Review the macroeconomic.
Chapter 16 Data Analysis: Testing for Associations.
How Inflation Behavior Helps In the Estimation of Potential Real GDP Robert J. Gordon, Northwestern University Presented at Conference European and American.
Monetary Policy. The Optimal Inflation Rate? The Optimal Inflation Rate?  Inflation has steadily gone down in rich countries since the early 1980s. 
Chapter 17: Monetary Policy Targets and Goals Chapter Objectives Explain why the Fed was generally so ineffective before the late 1980s. Explain why macroeconomic.
The Interplay Among Inflation, Productivity, and Potential Real GDP Robert J. Gordon, Northwestern University Presented at Seminar, Council of Economic.
Monetary Policy. The Optimal Inflation Rate? The Optimal Inflation Rate?  Inflation has steadily gone down in rich countries since the early 1980s. 
The liquidity trap, Mankiw’s 9 th principle, and inflation targets: the Bank of Canada dilemma Serge Coulombe Department of Economics University of Ottawa.
US Monetary Policy Group 5 Day 2 Chien-Hui Chan, Julian Yang, Yi-Hau Li.
For more course tutorials visit ECO 203 Entire Course (Old Course) ECO 203 Week 1 DQ 1 Opportunity Costs ECO 203 Week 1 DQ 2 NYC Rent.
Correlation and Regression
Monetary policy at ZLB/ELB – a BPEA tradition
Chapter 18 Monetary Policy: Stabilizing the Domestic Economy Part 3
Welcome to the Central Bank
Higher inflation targets?
Step 1: Specify a null hypothesis
Inflation and Hyperinflation Term Structure of Interest Rates
(Taylor) Rules versus Discretion in U.S. Monetary Policy
Tanya Molodtsova, Alex Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy
The Taylor Principles Alex Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy
Rethinking the Inflation Target
Brookings Papers of Economic Activity
The Federal Reserve and Monetary Policy
Chapter 18 Monetary Policy: Stabilizing the Domestic Economy Part 3
Monetary Policy: A Summing Up
Policy Rule Legislation in Practice
Chapter 18 Monetary Policy: Stabilizing the Domestic Economy Part 4
Module Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate
14 MONETARY POLICY Part 1.
Joseph E. Gagnon November 15, 2018
Start Small and Retire Early With Weekly Options
Review: What influences confidence intervals?
Geology Geomath Chapter 7 - Statistics tom.h.wilson
“Should the Fed Be Subject to a Monetary Rule
Will the real Taylor Rule please stand up?
How our Central Bank is structured
BUSINESS CYCLES (continued)
John B. Taylor Stanford University January 8, 2000
Prediction and Accuracy
Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate
Economic Outlook Lake County Chamber of Commerce William Strauss
Introduction to Estimation
John B. Taylor Stanford University January 8, 2000
Economic Outlook EconoSummit 2019 William Strauss Las Vegas, NV
Chapter 18 Monetary Policy: Stabilizing the Domestic Economy Part 4
Presentation transcript:

Discussion of “Rules versus Discretion: A Reconsideration” by Narayana Kocherlakota Alan S. Blinder Brookings Institution and Princeton University BPEA, September 15, 2016

This is two mini-papers A theoretical discussion of why discretion is better than rules. A practical discussion of why the Fed was too timid in 2009 and 2010. And, implicitly, after that as well. The (non-missing) link: The Fed’s timidity was, in large measure, due to slavish adherence to the original Taylor rule.

Quick overall evaluation Critiques by an insider are extremely valuable—and rare. So thank you! My first reaction was to jump for joy. But then I realized two things: The real issue is comparing somewhat incorrect rules to imperfect use of discretion. (Tough to do mathematically—we need human judgment!) The link via the Taylor rule is a bit tenuous since R was constrained to “0”. The only Taylor-rule issues were when “liftoff” would occur and what path R would follow thereafter. The November 2009 Bluebook had liftoff in 2012. The November 2010 Tealbook had liftoff in 2014. In the end, I’m still joyful--but not quite jumping.

paper #1 rules vs. discretion: theory

The traditional theoretical tradeoff Inflation bias → rules Private information → discretion Thank heaven NK said “non-rulable information” rather than “private information”!

The inflation bias issue Kocherlakota’s version: πCB > πSOC But does this idea make any basic sense? Rogoff’s (1985) “conservative central banker” would have πCB < πSOC. Furthermore:

The inflation bias issue Barro and Gordon (1983) and Kydland and Prescott (1977) sought to explain the rising inflation of, say, 1965-1980. But: History since 1980 has been rather different.

The inflation bias issue Barro and Gordon (1983) and Kydland and Prescott (1977) sought to explain the rising inflation of, say, 1965-1980. But: History since 1980 has been rather different. The sharp disinflation was a result of discretion (e.g., Volcker’s), not of rules. The theory predicts inflation that is too high, not rising inflation. Vietnam + supply shocks provide a more convincing theory for 1965-1980—and what followed.

Kocherlakota’s main conclusions (supposing both bias and non-rulable info exist) It’s not that “rules are better than discretion” when there is inflation bias. It’s that very, very good rules can be better than discretion if the inflation bias is relatively large and the variance of rulable shocks is relatively large. Kocherlakota argues for small inflation bias at the Fed. I agree based on: Natural selection of central bankers Oaths of office are “commitment devices.” There is obviously a lot of non-rulable information. The question is: Is it quantitatively important. My answer: At certain crucial times, YES!

two other thoughts We probably don’t live in a stationary environment. → undermines the case for rules. Despite the indubitable brilliance of FOMC members, discretion is probably not practiced perfectly. → undermines the case for discretion

paper # 2: history: The fed’s “errors” Specifically, being too timid in 2009 and 2010 (after R hit “zero”)

The two most important tables (pp. 6-7) Aspirations 58% after 3 years 57% after 3 years 29% after 3 years (core was 1.3) 50% after 3 years (core was 1.0)

Kocherlakota’s basic case These are pretty low aspirations → the FOMC was “giving up” too easily.

Kocherlakota’s basic case These are pretty low aspiration levels → the FOMC was “giving up” too easily. At the meetings, Board staff offered more aggressive options on QE and/or forward guidance, but no FOMC participant supported them. I knew the FOMC was a bit hawkish then, but not a single member?

Some Evidence of a hawkish fomc August 2007 statement: “the Committee's predominant policy concern remains the risk that inflation will fail to moderate as expected” Bernanke testimony, July 2009: “The FOMC has been devoting considerable attention to issues relating to its exit strategy,…” November 2009 meeting: Two participants favored a higher rate path than the Taylor rule; no one favored a lower path. (p. 8, fn 14)

Kocherlakota’s basic case These are pretty low aspiration levels → the FOMC was “giving up” too easily. At the meetings, Board staff offered more aggressive options on QE and/or forward guidance, but no FOMC participant supported them. There were perhaps reasons to worry about more aggressive QE, but basically no reasons to worry about more aggressive forward guidance. Well, what about markets not understanding the conditionality?

Kocherlakota’s basic case These are pretty low aspiration levels → the FOMC was “giving up” too easily. At the meetings, Board staff offered more aggressive options on QE and/or forward guidance, but no FOMC participant supported them. There were perhaps reasons to worry about more aggressive QE, but basically no reasons to worry about more aggressive forward guidance. “… [more] stimulative steps received essentially no support within the FOMC—at least in part because they would have led to a larger deviation from… the prescriptions of the Taylor rule. “ (p. 12)

The staff taylor rule at the time R = 2.5 + π – 1.1(U-U*) + 0.5(π – 2) Note: This equation was not estimated. Note: No Rt-1 term! Note: 2.5% seems a bit high for the natural real rate. U3 instead of GDP gap Core PCE instead of GDP deflator

Technological regress? In my day (a long time ago!), we saw results from n Taylor rules. U vs. GDP gap Different U measures Different π measures Different coefficients With and without Rt-1 (if estimated, with) The range of R’s thereby produced was normally wide!

My conclusions I was pretty shocked to learn that one particular Taylor rule held that much sway. But remember, R was constrained to “zero” all this time. So how important was it? I agree with Kocherlakota that the Fed was too timid/hawkish, but... But: Once the funds rate hit “zero,” and after early QE1, they were down to pretty weak instruments. But: We should grade them on a curve: Most other CBs did worse. So I come here not to bury Messrs. Bernanke and Kohn in criticism, but to praise them.