Chapter 11 Profit Maximization.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter Nineteen Profit-Maximization.
Advertisements

Chapter 12 Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Modeling Firms’ Behavior Most economists treat the firm as a single decision-making unit the decisions are made by a single dictatorial manager who rationally.
1 Chapter 9 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 11: Managerial Decision in Competitive Markets.
Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets
Chapter 8 Costs © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS
Chapter 12 COSTS Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS.
Definitions of Costs It is important to differentiate between accounting cost and economic cost the accountant’s view of cost stresses out-of-pocket expenses,
Chapter 9 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Profit Maximization and Supply.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
PROFIT MAXIMIZATION AND SUPPLY
Part 7 Further Topics © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets
Chapter 3 Labor Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 8 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Costs.
1 Chapter 9 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 9 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION.
The Supply Curve and the Behavior of Firms
Chapter 8 Profit Maximization and Competitive Supply.
Chapter 11: Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets
Next page Chapter 5: The Demand for Labor. Jump to first page 1. Derived Demand for Labor.
KULIAH 6 Cost Functions Dr. Amalia A. Widyasanti Program Pasca Sarjana Ilmu Akuntansi FE-UI, 2010.
Profit Maximization Chapter 8
Chapter 8 Profit Maximization and Competitive Supply.
Theory of Production & Cost BEC Managerial Economics.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Lecture 8 Profit Maximization. Comparison of consumer theory with producer theory In consumer theory we learned that the main objective of consumer is.
Chapter 9 Profit Maximization. Profit-Maximizing Prices and Quantities A firm’s profit, , is equal to its revenue R less its cost C  = R – C Maximizing.
Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets BEC Managerial Economics.
1 Chapter 8 Practice Quiz Perfect Competition A perfectly competitive market is not characterized by a. many small firms. b. a great variety of.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
1 Chapter 11 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION. 2 Profit Maximization A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the sole goal of achieving.
Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets BEC Managerial Economics.
A Closer Look at Production and Costs
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 2
Theory of the Firm : Production
Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions
Last class: Today: Next class: Important dates:
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition
Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions
Chapter 5 The Demand for Labor McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter 8 Perfect Competition
Lecture 7.
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
UNIT 6 COSTS AND PRODUCTION: LONG AND SHORT-RUN, TOTAL, FIXED AND VARIABLE COSTS, LAW OF DIMINISHING RETURNS, INCREASING, CONSTANT AND DIMINISHING RETURNS.
Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions
Pure Competition in the Short-Run
Costs of Production in the Long-run
Chapter 9 Production and Cost in the Long Run
Profit Maximization and Perfect Competition
Chapter 11 Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets
Profit Maximization © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted.
Chapter 3 The Demand For Labor.
Factor Markets and Vertical Integration
CHAPTER 8 OUTLINE 8.1 Perfectly Competitive Markets 8.2 Profit Maximization 8.3 Marginal Revenue, Marginal Cost, and Profit Maximization 8.4 Choosing Output.
Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets
Profit Maximization © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted.
Production & Cost in the Long Run
A Closer Look at Production and Costs
Managerial Decisions in Competitive Markets
Cost Functions, Cost Minimization
Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions
Walter Nicholson Christopher Snyder
Walter Nicholson Christopher Snyder
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 11 Profit Maximization

Chapter Overview The Profit Maximization Condition Marginal Revenue and Elasticity Short Run Equilibrium Short Run Supply Curve for a Price Taking Firm Profit Function Producer Surplus 5. Profit Maximization and Input Demand Marginal Revenue product Substitution effect Output effect

Profit Maximization A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the sole goal of achieving maximum economic profits seeks to maximize the difference between total revenue and total economic costs If firms are strictly profit maximizers, they will make decisions in a “marginal” way examine the marginal profit obtainable from producing one more unit of hiring one additional laborer

(q) = R(q) – C(q) = p(q)q –C(q) Output Choice Total revenue for a firm is given by R(q) = p(q)q In the production of q, certain economic costs are incurred [C(q)] Economic profits () are the difference between total revenue and total costs (q) = R(q) – C(q) = p(q)q –C(q)

Output Choice The necessary condition for choosing the level of q that maximizes profits can be found by setting the derivative of the  function with respect to q equal to zero To maximize economic profits, the firm should choose the output for which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost

Second-Order Conditions MR = MC is only a necessary condition for profit maximization For sufficiency, it is also required that “marginal” profit must be decreasing at the optimal level of q

Marginal Revenue, Marginal Cost, and Profit Maximization A firm chooses output q*, so that profit, the difference AB between revenue R and cost C, is maximized. At that output, marginal revenue (the slope of the revenue curve) is equal to marginal cost (the slope of the cost curve). Δπ/Δq = ΔR/Δq − ΔC/Δq = 0 MR(q) = MC(q) The second-order condition prevents us from mistaking q which is less than q0 as a maximum

Marginal Revenue If a firm can sell all it wishes without having any effect on market price, marginal revenue will be equal to price If a firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, more output can only be sold if the firm reduces the good’s price If a firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, marginal revenue will be a function of output If price falls as a firm increases output, marginal revenue will be less than price

Marginal Revenue from linear demand function Suppose that the demand curve is q = 100 – 10p Solving for price, we get p = -q/10 + 10 This means that total revenue is R = pq = -q2/10 + 10q Marginal revenue will be given by MR = dR/dq = -q/5 + 10

Profit Maximization To determine the profit-maximizing output, we must know the firm’s costs If output can be produced at a constant average and marginal cost of $4, then MR = MC -q/5 + 10 = 4 q = 30

Marginal Revenue and Elasticity The concept of marginal revenue is directly related to the elasticity of the demand curve facing the firm The price elasticity of demand is equal to the percentage change in quantity that results from a one percent change in price

Marginal Revenue and Elasticity This means that if the demand curve slopes downward, eq,p < 0 and MR < p if the demand is elastic, eq,p < -1 and marginal revenue will be positive if the demand is infinitely elastic, eq,p = - and marginal revenue will equal price

Marginal Revenue and Elasticity eq,p < -1 MR > 0 eq,p = -1 MR = 0 eq,p > -1 MR < 0

The Inverse Elasticity Rule Because MR = MC when the firm maximizes profit, we can see that The “markup” will fall as the demand curve facing the firm becomes more elastic If eq,p > -1, MC < 0 This means that firms will choose to operate only at points on the demand curve where demand is elastic

Markup Pricing What does it mean? Where is it used? Why? Markup on price or cost? Should it be a constant? How does markup relate to profit maximization?

Markup Pricing What does it mean? Markup on price or cost? It is a pricing technique whereby a certain percentage of cost of goods sold or of price is added to the cost of goods sold in order to obtain the market price. Markup on price or cost? Suppose an item costs $50 to produce and is sold for $100. Whether it is 50 percent markup or a markup of 100 percent. In the 1st instance the margin is a markup on price (the proportion of the selling price that represents an amount added to the cost of the goods sold) In 2nd case the markup is the markup on cost (the proportion of the cost of goods sold that is added on to that figure to arrive at the selling price)

Profit Maximization & Markup Profit is maximum when: Profit maximizing markup is inversely related to price elasticity as follows:

Profit Maximization & Markup Note: As long as Ep (which is nearly always negative) has an absolute value larger than 1, m will be positive. Profit maximizing markup is lower the higher the absolute value of the own price elasticity of demand for the good or the service. Value of Elasticity Coefficient 100 x -1 / (Ep + 1) = Optimal percent markup on Cost -2 100 -3 50 -4 33.3 -5 25 -9 12.5 The formula relating to markup on price to elasticity : Markup = -1/Ep

Marginal Revenue Curve Average Revenue Curve If we assume that the firm must sell all its output at one price, we can think of the demand curve facing the firm as its average revenue curve shows the revenue per unit yielded Marginal Revenue Curve The marginal revenue curve shows the extra revenue provided by the last unit sold In the case of a downward-sloping demand curve, the marginal revenue curve will lie below the demand curve

Marginal Revenue Curve As output increases from 0 to q1, total revenue increases so MR > 0 Price As output increases beyond q1, total revenue decreases so MR < 0 p1 D (average revenue) Quantity per period q1 MR

Marginal Revenue Curve When the demand curve shifts, its associated marginal revenue curve shifts as well a marginal revenue curve cannot be calculated without referring to a specific demand curve

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC SAC P* = MR q* Maximum profit occurs where P = SMC SAVC Quantity per period

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC SAC P* = MR SAVC Since P > SAC, profit > 0 Quantity per period q*

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC If the price rises to P**, the firm will produce q** and  > 0 q** P** SAC P* = MR SAVC Quantity per period q*

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price If the price falls to P***, the firm will produce q*** q*** P*** SMC P* = MR SAC SAVC Profit maximization requires that P = SMC and that SMC is upward-sloping Quantity per period q*  < 0

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm The positively-sloped portion of the short-run marginal cost curve is the short-run supply curve for a price-taking firm it shows how much the firm will produce at every possible market price firms will only operate in the short run as long as total revenue covers variable cost the firm will produce no output if p < SAVC

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Thus, the price-taking firm’s short-run supply curve is the positively-sloped portion of the firm’s short-run marginal cost curve above the point of minimum average variable cost for prices below this level, the firm’s profit-maximizing decision is to shut down and produce no output

Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC The firm’s short-run supply curve is the SMC curve that is above SAVC SAC SAVC Quantity per period

SC(v,w,q,k) = vk1 + wq1/k1-/ Short-Run Supply Suppose that the firm’s short-run total cost curve is SC(v,w,q,k) = vk1 + wq1/k1-/ where k1 is the level of capital held constant in the short run Short-run marginal cost is

SAVC = SVC/q = wq(1-)/k1-/ Short-Run Supply The price-taking firm will maximize profit where p = SMC Therefore, quantity supplied will be To find the firm’s shut - down price, we need to solve for SAVC SVC = wq1/k1-/ SAVC = SVC/q = wq(1-)/k1-/

 = Pq - C(q) = Pf(k,l) - vk - wl Profit Functions A firm’s economic profit can be expressed as a function of inputs  = Pq - C(q) = Pf(k,l) - vk - wl Only the variables k and l are under the firm’s control the firm chooses levels of these inputs in order to maximize profits treats P, v, and w as fixed parameters in its decisions

Profit Functions Envelope Results A firm’s profit function shows its maximal profits as a function of the prices that the firm faces Envelope Results We can apply the envelope theorem to see how profits respond to changes in output and input prices

Producer Surplus in the Short Run The profit function is nondecreasing in output prices, we know that if P2 > P1 (P2,…)  (P1,…) The welfare gain to the firm of this price increase can be measured by welfare gain = (P2,…) – (P1,…) Mathematically, we can use the envelope theorem results

Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC P1 q1 If the market price is P1, the firm will produce q1 If the market price rises to P2, the firm will produce q2 P2 q2 Quantity per period

Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC The firm’s profits rise by the shaded area P2 P1 Quantity per period q1 q2

Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC Suppose that the firm’s shutdown price is P0 P0 P1 Quantity per period q1

Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC Producer surplus at a market price of P1 is the shaded area P1 P0 Quantity per period q1

Producer Surplus in the Short Run The extra profits available from facing a price of P1 are defined to be producer surplus Producer surplus is the extra return that producers make by making transactions at the market price over and above what they would earn if nothing were produced the area below the market price and above the supply curve

Producer Surplus in the Short Run Because the firm produces no output at the shutdown price, (P0,…) = -vk1 profits at the shutdown price are equal to fixed costs This implies that producer surplus = (P1,…) – (P0,…) = (P1,…) – (-vk1) = (P1,…) + vk1 producer surplus is equal to current profits plus short-run fixed costs

Profit Maximization and Input Demand A firm’s output is determined by the amount of inputs it chooses to employ the relationship between inputs and outputs is summarized by the production function A firm’s economic profit can also be expressed as a function of inputs (k,l) = Pq –C(q) = Pf(k,l) – (vk + wl) The FOCs for a maximum are /k = P[f/k] – v = 0 /l = P[f/l] – w = 0

Profit Maximization and Input Demand A profit-maximizing firm should hire any input up to the point at which its marginal contribution to revenues is equal to the marginal cost of hiring the input. MRPL = PL and MRPK = PK These FOCs for profit maximization also imply cost minimization they imply that MRTS = w/v

Profit Maximization and Input Demand To ensure a true maximum, SOCs require that kk = fkk < 0 ll = fll < 0 kk ll - kl2 = fkkfll – fkl2 > 0 capital and labor must exhibit sufficiently diminishing marginal productivities so that marginal costs rise as output expands

Input Demand Functions In principle, the first-order conditions can be solved to yield input demand functions Capital Demand = k(P,v,w) Labor Demand = l(P,v,w) These demand functions are unconditional they implicitly allow the firm to adjust its output to changing prices

Single-Input Case We expect l/w  0 diminishing marginal productivity of labor The first order condition for profit maximization was /l = P[f/l] – w = 0

Two-Input Case For the case of two (or more inputs), the story is more complex if there is a decrease in w, there will not only be a change in l but also a change in k as a new cost-minimizing combination of inputs is chosen when k changes, the entire fl function changes But, even in this case, l/w  0

Two-Input Case When w falls, two effects occur substitution effect if output is held constant, there will be a tendency for the firm to want to substitute l for k in the production process output effect a change in w will shift the firm’s expansion path the firm’s cost curves will shift and a different output level will be chosen

Substitution Effect If output is held constant at q0 and w falls, the firm will substitute L for K in the production process k per period Because of diminishing MRTS along an isoquant, the substitution effect will always be negative q0 l per period

Output Effect A decline in w will lower the firm’s MC Price Consequently, the firm will choose a new level of output that is higher P q0 q1 Quantity per period

Output Effect Output will rise to q1 k per period Thus, the output effect also implies a negative relationship between l and w q0 l per period

Input Demand For a fixed quantity, as price of labor decreases from $2 to $1, firm moves along its labor demand curve from B to A. Increase in output shifts the demand curve.

Cross-Price Effects No definite statement can be made about how capital usage responds to a wage change a fall in the wage will lead the firm to substitute away from capital the output effect will cause more capital to be demanded as the firm expands production

Substitution and Output Effects We have two concepts of demand for any input the conditional demand for labor, lc(v,w,q) the unconditional demand for labor, l(P,v,w) At the profit-maximizing level of output lc(v,w,q) = l(P,v,w)

Substitution and Output Effects Differentiation with respect to w yields substitution effect output effect total effect