Demand for Health Insurance

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Correcting Market Distortions: Shadow Prices, Shadow Wages and Discount Rates Chapter 6.
Advertisements

Fall 2008 Version Professor Dan C. Jones FINA 4355 Class Problem.
Equity, Efficiency and Need
Health Insurance – Part 1 Eric Jacobson. Employer Health Benefits 2004 Annual Survey Kaiser Family Foundation
Health Insurance October 19, 2006 Insurance is defined as a means of protecting against risk. Risk is a state in which multiple outcomes are possible and.
317_L13, Feb 5, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture finished our discussion of the demand for healthcare today begin our discussion of market.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
317_L12, Feb 1, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture discussed the effect of proportional health insurance on the healthcare market => showed.
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
317_L15, Feb 8, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of why there is a demand for health insurance basic reason => people.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
Health System Reform © Allen C. Goodman, Major Themes Lower costs, or lower growth in costs. Provision of (more) equitable access to care for.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
The Demand for Health Insurance Why do people want health insurance? -To avoid or reduce risk -Risks of illness or injury that causes health status to.
Insurance and Health Care Health care normally considered a good that is different from most others Consumption of health care by many individuals is only.
The role of insurance in health care, part 2 Today: More on moral hazard Other issues in insurance Problems with insurance.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
317_L11, Jan 30, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of health insurance and its impact on the healthcare market Defined.
How insurance affects the demand for medical care
Chapter 6: Health Insurance Chapter 6 Health Insurance Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
The Private Health Insurance Market. Insurance Design Insurance is designed to spread risk Individuals can self-insure and face chance of paying for costs.
THE HEALTH CARE MARKET Chapter 9.
Chapter 20 Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation Social efficiency is maximized at the competitive equilibrium (in the absence.
MEDICAL INSURANCE IN HEALTH CARE SYSTEMS. Two Comments Second comment: Most of us are not aware of the financial burden we bear for health care provided.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples Agenda: 1.The Used Car Game 2.Insurance & The Death Spiral 3.The Market for Information 4.The Price.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
317_L16, Feb 12, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture Finished our discussion of why there is a demand for health insurance today begin our.
ECO 5550/6550 Exam Dr. Allen C. Goodman October 27, 2014.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Decision theory under uncertainty
What is ‘Managed Care’? A ‘type’ of health insurance –combines both the financing of care (insurance) with the provision of care –variations in MC plans.
More on managed care. Demand for MCOs Patients and/or employers may wish lower cost alternative. BUT, they might not like to have their options limited.
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
11-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported.
Market Failure 11 Farid Abolhassani.
Private Health Insurance
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization Presented by: Kuan Chen.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
Announcements HW #1 on the website 1/12/2015. How do we finance medical care? Federal expenditures in 2013: $586B in Medicare $265B in Medicaid (+ 1/3.
Chapter Thirty-Six Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets u In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded.
Health Insurance Supply
Health Insurance Exchanges
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples
Demand for Private Health Insurance
Chapter 19 Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization
Lesson 6-2 Protecting Income
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples
©2016 by McGraw-Hill Education Limited.
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
Personal Finance Health Insurance
Efficiency and Equity in a Competitive Market
Lecture 16 Assoc. Prof. Sencer Ecer HEALTH ECONOMICS
06 Consumer Behavior Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Warm Up: Why do you need insurance?
CHAPTER 2: THE SUPPLY OF LABOR
Health Insurance Personal Finance.
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS: PART 2
GOVERNMENT AND THE MARKET FOR HEALTH CARE
Medical Care.
A QUESTION OF ACCESS.
Health Insurance: The Basics
06 Consumer Behavior Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Module 5 HC Economics Students.
Social Insurance: Social Security
The Basic Tools of Finance
Presentation transcript:

Demand for Health Insurance Lecture 10 Assoc. Prof. Sencer Ecer HEALTH ECONOMICS

Health Insurance The market for different types of insurance Health insurance is pervasive: Table 10.1 Coverage rates in the US Medicare > 65 (mandatory) (Federal) Medicaid for poor (state-federal partnership) Turkish yesil kart (green (poverty) card) SCHIP for kids (state-federal partnership) “Save the women and children first” Too high income for Medicaid and no private health insurance

The Demand for Health Insurance We need to think of demand for medical care and insurance together, which we actually did before by thinking of demand conditional of having health insurance Health and illness is random. Health insurance insures the financial risk that medical care will cost that a rational person is expected to seek, the derived risk With no formal medical care, health insurance could be additional help in home production in the form of labor or simply help due to marriage (not the case by providing health insurance but by providing care and help as a substitute) No technology can help insure health directly, we can’t make it up hundred percent Reasons people want insurance: Figure 10.1 Two goods: income in bad state and income in good state p is the probability of bad state, 1-p: no loss p/(1-p) is the odds ratio Price should equal odds ratio in an actuarially fair world

A simple approach γ = (p/1-p)γ*, where γ*>1 is the positive real price of insurance Typo, p.304, line 2, should be γ not γ* Comparative statics: Flatter budget line (cheaper insurance) implies buying more coverage If marginal utility of income changes (decreases) rapidly with income, then that implies buying more coverage

A more detailed approach We assume stable preferences (don’t change with health or income shock etc.) and so income, health level, medical care consumption level all determine a person’s utility Risk aversion derives from decreasing marginal utility of income Figures 10.2 and 10.3 There is decreasing marginal utility to income Utility from expected income is higher than expected utility The expected utility can be obtained by a lower income level than expected income The difference is the risk premium, basis for insurance, assuming that the individual maximizes expected utility

The insurance proposition Offer payment at least as high as the IC and in return obtain the individual’s income IC depends o the variance of the gamble and the curvature of the utility curve r(I) = -U’’ / U’ Absolute risk aversion Welfare gain = u(E(IC)-insurance charge)-u(IC) Note: No trade unless E(IC)-insurance charge > IC

Choice of Insurance Policy Intuition of the maximization problem can be captured with choosing the best coinsurance rate Given coinsurance rate C and distribution of f, Expected Benefits from N different illnesses equal: E(B) = Σfi(1-C)pmmi or =(1-C)pmm* where m*= Σfimi pm could actually be pmi but we are simplifying to one type of medical care, such as hospital days The dependence between m and C is called the moral hazard (Pauly, 1968). It is a predictable response of rational consumers. To the extent that it can be planned for (see RHIS), it is not a big problem

Moral Hazard Initially, private insurance companies may not estimate patients visiting a doctor for every minor illness. This extra quantity demanded doesn’t just hurt profits but may cause the market to shrink, some may be left uninsured. Insurance may become dysfunctional Welfare loss due to value of marginal consumption being exceeded by its marginal cost Optimal choice of C optimizes between this welfare loss and the fundamental welfare gain from insurance

Example Figure 10.4 (think as representative consumer) A and B: welfare loss due to moral hazard E(B)=pm(f1m1+f2m2)(1-C) = $840 Total insurance premium = E(B) + loading fee (%10) = $924 Loading fee = risk bearing + profits + admin costs Consumer welfare gain depends on two things Amount of risk premium = .5 x r(I) x σ2 = .5 x -.0003 x $1,552,500 = $220 Size of A and B: MH=f1A+f2B=.3 x $200+.1 x $200 = $80 Consumer’s WTP=E(B)+risk premium-MH = $840 + $200 - $80 = $980 WTP-charge = $980 - $924 = $56 = welfare from risk reduction Pick optimal C by balancing A and B and risk reduction

Moral Hazard Figure 10.5 MH depends on demand elasticity for the medical care at hand The higher demand elasticity, the higher MH See formula at fn 15 Then, insurance companies will prefer not to insure such services

Empirical Regularities in Insurance Coverage Demand for insurance should be higher the higher the financial risk (measured by variance) and should be lower the more price elastic the demand for that type of medical care Confirmed Table 10.2 Hospital (highest financial risk and lowest elasticity) v dental (smallest financial risk and largest elasticity of demand) Dental insurance emerged relatively recently and probably because of tax treatment

Price of insurance R=(1+L)(1-C)pmm*, L=loading fee R= (1-C)pmm* (actuarially fair) If L increases then consumers choose a higher C, so that insurance portion will be lower

Prevention Normally, preventive care does not have much uncertainty, so insuring them may not seem to make sense as insuring medical risks. However, subsidizing them makes sense because: It can reduce financial risk from illness It can also reduce the expected welfare losses from MH Figure 10.6

Prevention example Without vaccination flu occurs w/prob. 30 %. Mean expenditure = πpm1 Variance = π(1-π)(p x m1)2 Risk premium = ½ x Variance x r, where (Assume that prevention completely eradicates the risk of illness) r= Arrow-Pratt measure of absolute risk aversion The Book omits 1/2 , so assume r=.0004 and use the calculations in the book, which yield $10.50. (P.316) Add $10.50 to $500 (flu treatment cost) x .30 = $160.50 If insured with C=.2 and assume demand increases by 20%, then m2=1.2m1 so mean = π x.2 x p x 1.2 x m1, and financial risk is original risk x .04 x 1.44 = .0576 => .0576 x $10.5 = $.60

Prevention example If insured, individual also captures the reduction in expected medical expense .30 x 120 = $36, so total gain for insured individual is $36.60 in contrast to the uninsured individual whose gain was $160.50 With vaccination, the insurance company saves $600 x (1-.2) x .3 = $144 > $36.60 So insurance company would like to induce the individual to get preventive action It can insurance prevention It can charge premium based on preventative behavior like in smoking status and life insurance (experience rating) –seldom happens due to group insurance Also, there are externalities: flu shot is worth it because it is effective for a given year, but benefits of obesity reduction may go to another insurer (due to directly changing the carrier or indirectly to changing jobs) (Externality). As such, employers have less risk than insurers, so they have more incentive to induce preventive care: wellness plans.

Self Selection =Adverse Selection People who suspect or plan high health expenditures buy more insurance coverage The people with low risks in the insurance pool will end up paying higher Figure 10.7 Budget curve is curved because price of health insurance changes with higher medical care consumption: not only more health care bills, but bigger amounts per bill due to moral hazard

Adverse Selection Figure 10.8 Marginal utility from X is higher for the healthy, so flatter indifference curve This would be the full information case. So, budget for the sickly would be smaller due to higher premium What if insurance companies can’t distinguish? Figure 10.9, limited coverage, experience rating Separating equilibrium, the standard outcome in a competitive market Healthy person made worse off

Community rating Figure 10.10 A budget curve between IS and IH Same price for a community e.g. New York State Pareto superior to separating equilibrium only if healthy people form a majority, they could be made worse off if in minority Sickly people will always be better off

Transaction Costs Group insurance through employers is similar to community rating People need to be healthy at least to some extent Median voter at firm wins in choosing the insurance plan Hence, most companies offer only one type of health insurance Long term insurance is very vulnerable to self-selection Hence it has just been forming

Job Lock Pre-existing conditions may prevent people from changing jobs

Empirical estimates of demand for insurance Micro v macro data Ecer and Koc (2011): micro Effect of income on demand Macro: Entire economy How total insurance premiums and income, loading fees, tax subsidies relate Income elasticity is <1 in micro data But we don’t know the income of median worker, who is probably calling the shots, so prediction is difficult In macro data income elasticity is between 1 and 2

Price effects Aggregate data yields -1.5 to -2 Elastic Micro data yields less than -1 Nothing comparable to RAND HIS exists for the demand for health insurance When Reagan reduced the tax subsidy for health insurance there was a considerable decline in, for example, hospital insurance

Optimal insurance Keeler (1988) estimated the best (maxing expected utility) plan in RAND HIS C=25% + $100-300 deductible