MODULE 13 (49) Consumer and Producer Surplus

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
CHAPTER 6: SECTION 1 Supply and Demand Together
Advertisements

Copyright © 2004 South-Western Welfare Economics Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers.
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
1 Excise Tax on a Market. 2 excise tax An excise tax is a tax on the seller of a product. We treat the tax as a cost of doing business. If there is no.
1 Surplus Measures 2 An Alternative View of the Demand Curve u An alternative interpretation of the demand curve is that it represents the consumer’s.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY. © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley Equilibrium is a situation in which opposing forces balance each other. Equilibrium in a market occurs.
College Textbook Market: On average, students spend $1,200 per semester An 82% rise in price from More than an 800% increase from 1978!!! So,
Chapter 4 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Efficiency and Deadweight Loss
Consumer and Producer Surplus AP Economics Mr. Bordelon.
Welfare Economics Consumer and Producer Surplus. Consumer Surplus How much are you willing to pay for a pair of jeans? As an individual consumer, you.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumer and Producer Surplus
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes
Chapter 3: Competitive Dynamics How Competitive Markets Operate Market Equilibrium:  The stable point at which demand and supply curves intersect PRICE.
Consumer and Producer Surplus!!
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Markets and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Welfare Economics Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers.
Supply. Quantity Supplied Amount of any good or service that sellers are willing and able to sell Law of Supply: Other things equal (ceteris paribus),
1 of 39 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 4 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Consumer and Producer Surplus.
1 of 39 WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 4 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Consumer and Producer Surplus.
© 2007 Worth Publishers Essentials of Economics Krugman Wells Olney Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano.
We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets?
Chapter 4 The Market Strikes Back ©2010  Worth Publishers Slides created by Dr. Amy Scott.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 6-1 CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all.
C onsumer and Producer Surplus Slide 5 - Discuss the difference between willingness to pay and the actual price paid. Notice different consumers value.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Welfare Economics Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Buyers.
Chapter 4 The Market Strikes Back ©2010  Worth Publishers Slides created by Dr. Amy Scott.
Supply and Demand A competitive market is a market in which there are   many buyers and sellers   of the same good or service. The supply and demand.
All image credits courtesy of Morgue File and/or FreeImages
Consumer Surplus2/16/16 I. Definition: the benefits from being able to purchase a good A. In other words: the difference between how much you are willing/able.
Intro To Microeconomics.  Cost is the money spent for the inputs used (e.g., labor, raw materials, transportation, energy) in producing a good or service.
ECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells with Margaret Ray and David Anderson SECOND EDITION in MODULES.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Producer Surplus >> ©2011  Worth Publishers.
Chapter 4: Demand and Supply
Definition: the benefits from being able to purchase a good
Module A: Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change
Consumer Surplus AP Micro 9/5/17.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Module 11 Consumer and Producer Surplus
4 chapter: >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Krugman/Wells
Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus
Module 12 Efficiency and Markets
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Producer Surplus Ap Micro 9/6/17.
Please read the following License Agreement before proceeding.
Demand and Supply Applications
Why is this image a good one to symbolize the chapter Supply?
Ch. 3: Demand and Supply Objectives Determinants of demand and supply
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Warm-Up How much are you willing to pay for gas?
Econ Unit One Day 8.
Chapter 4 Pollution Problems: Must We Foul Our Own Nests?
Section 2 Module 7.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
Consumer and Producer Surplus
UNIT TWO INTRODUCTION TO DEMAND & SUPPLY ANALYSIS
Ch. 3: Demand and Supply Objectives Determinants of demand and supply
Supply and equilibrium
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
제6장에서는 앞에서 배운 내용을 좀더 심화 학습하는 단계입니다.
4 chapter: >> Consumer and Producer Surplus Krugman/Wells
CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Chapter 8 Review.
Chapter 3 Lecture DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Presentation transcript:

MODULE 13 (49) Consumer and Producer Surplus Krugman/Wells

The meaning of consumer surplus and its relationship to the demand curve The meaning of producer surplus and its relationship to the supply curve.

Consumer Surplus and the Demand Curve A consumer’s willingness to pay for a good is the maximum price at which he or she would buy that good. Individual consumer surplus is the net gain to an individual buyer from the purchase of a good. It is equal to the difference between the buyer’s willingness to pay and the price paid.

The Demand Curve for Used Textbooks Price of book Aleisha $59 Potential buyers Willingness to pay Aleisha $59 45 Brad Brad 45 Claudia 35 35 Claudia Darren 25 Edwina 10 25 Darren Figure Caption: Figure 13.1 (49.1): The Demand Curve for Used Textbooks With only five potential consumers in this market, the demand curve is step-shaped. Each step represents one consumer, and its height indicates that consumer’s willingness to pay—the maximum price at which each will buy a used textbook—as indicated in the table. Aleisha has the highest willingness to pay at $59, Brad has the next highest at $45, and so on down to Edwina with the lowest willingness to pay at $10. At a price of $59, the quantity demanded is one (Aleisha); at a price of $45, the quantity demanded is two (Aleisha and Brad); and so on until you reach a price of $10, at which all five students are willing to purchase a book. A consumer’s willingness to pay for a good is the maximum price at which he or she would buy that good. 10 Edwina D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity of books

Willingness to Pay and Consumer Surplus Total consumer surplus is the sum of the individual consumer surpluses of all the buyers of a good. The term consumer surplus is often used to refer to both individual and total consumer surplus.

Consumer Surplus in the Used Textbook Market

Consumer Surplus in the Used Textbook Market 5 4 3 2 1 Aleisha Brad Claudia Darren D Edwina $59 45 35 30 10 25 Price of book Quantity of books Aleisha’s consumer surplus: $59 - $30 = $29 Brad’s consumer surplus: $45 - $30 = $15 Claudia’s consumer surplus: $35 - $30 = $5 The total consumer surplus is given by the entire shaded area - the sum of the individual consumer surpluses of Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia - equal to $29 + $15 + $5 = $49. Price = $30 Figure Caption: Figure 13.2 (49.2): Consumer Surplus in the Used-Textbook Market At a price of $30, Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia each buy a book but Darren and Edwina do not. Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia get individual consumer surpluses equal to the difference between their willingness to pay and the price, illustrated by the areas of the shaded rectangles. Both Darren and Edwina have a willingness to pay less than $30, so they are unwilling to buy a book in this market; they receive zero consumer surplus. The total consumer surplus is given by the entire shaded area—the sum of the individual consumer surpluses of Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia—equal to $29 + $15 + $5 = $49.

Consumer Surplus The total consumer surplus generated by purchases of a good at a given price is equal to the area below the demand curve but above that price. 1 million $1,500 Price of computers Quantity of computers D Consumer surplus Figure Caption: Figure 13.3 (49.3): Consumer Surplus The demand curve for computers is smooth because there are many potential buyers. At a price of $1,500, 1 million computers are demand- ed. The consumer surplus at this price is equal to the shaded area: the area below the demand curve but above the price. This is the total net gain to consumers generated from buying and consuming computers when the price is $1,500. Price = $1,500

How Changing Prices Affect Consumer Surplus A fall in the price of a good increases consumer surplus through two channels: a gain to consumers who would have bought at the original price. a gain to consumers who are persuaded to buy by the lower price.

Consumer Surplus and a Fall in the Price of Used Textbooks 5 4 3 2 1 D $59 45 35 30 10 25 20 Aleisha Brad Claudia Darren Edwina Price of book Quantity of books Increase in Aleisha’s consumer surplus Increase in Brad’s consumer surplus Increase in Claude’s consumer surplus Original price = $30 Figure Caption: Figure 13.4 (49.4): Consumer Surplus and a Fall in the Price of Used Textbooks There are two parts to the increase in consumer surplus generated by a fall in price from $30 to $20. The first is given by the dark blue rectangle: each person who would have bought at the original price of $30—Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia—receives an increase in consumer surplus equal to the total reduction in price, $10. So the area of the dark blue rectangle corresponds to an amount equal to 3 ×$10 =$30. The second part is given by the light blue area: the increase in consumer surplus for those who would not have bought at the original price of $30 but who buy at the new price of $20—namely, Darren. Darren’s willingness to pay is $25, so he now receives consumer surplus of $5. The total increase in consumer surplus is 3 ×$10 +$5 =$35, represented by the sum of the shaded areas. Likewise, a rise in price from $20 to $30 would decrease consumer surplus by an amount equal to the sum of the shaded areas. Darren’s consumer surplus New price = $20

A Fall in the Market Price Increases Consumer Surplus 1 million 200,000 1,500 $5,000 Price of computers Quantity of computers D Increase in consumer surplus to original buyers Consumer surplus gained by new buyers Figure Caption: Figure 13.5 (49.5): A Fall in the Price Increase Consumer Surplus A fall in the price of a computer from $5,000 to $1,500 leads to an increase in the quantity demanded and an increase in consumer surplus. The change in total consumer surplus is given by the sum of the shaded areas: the total area below the demand curve and between the old and new prices. Here, the dark blue area represents the increase in consumer surplus for the 200,000 consumers who would have bought a computer at the original price of $5,000; they each receive an increase in consumer surplus of $3,500. The light blue area represents the increase in consumer surplus for those willing to buy at a price equal to or greater than $1,500 but less than $5,000. Similarly, a rise in the price of a computer from $1,500 to $5,000 generates a decrease in consumer surplus equal to the sum of the two shaded areas.

A Matter of Life and Death Each year, about 4,000 people in the United States die while waiting for a kidney transplant. The UNOS is devising a new set of guidelines where kidneys would be allocated on the basis of who will receive the greatest net benefit, where net benefit is measured as the increase in lifespan from the transplant. This would increase the recipients’ extra years by 11,000. The “net benefit” concept is like consumer surplus: the individual consumer surplus generated from getting a new kidney.

Producer Surplus and the Supply Curve A potential seller’s cost is the lowest price at which he or she is willing to sell a good. Individual producer surplus is the net gain to a seller from selling a good. It is equal to the difference between the price received and the seller’s cost. Total producer surplus in a market is the sum of the individual producer surpluses of all the sellers of a good.

The Supply Curve for Used Textbooks Price of book Potential sellers S Cost Engelbert $5 $45 Engelbert Donna 15 25 Carlos 35 Donna Betty 35 45 Andrew 25 Carlos Figure Caption: Figure 13.6 (49.6): The Supply Curve for Used Textbooks The supply curve illustrates sellers’ cost, the lowest price at which a potential seller is willing to sell the good, and the quantity supplied at that price. Each of the five students has one book to sell and each has a different cost, as indicated in the accompanying table. At a price of $5 the quantity supplied is one (Andrew), at $15 it is two (Andrew and Betty), and so on until you reach $45, the price at which all five students are willing to sell. 15 Betty 5 Andrew 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity of books

Producer Surplus When the Price of a Used Textbook is $30

Producer Surplus in the Used Textbook Market 5 4 3 2 1 S $45 35 30 25 15 Price of book Quantity of books Engelbert Donna Carlos Betty Andrew Price = $30 Andrew’s producer surplus Betty’s producer surplus Carlos’s producer surplus Figure Caption: Figure 13.7 (49.7): Producer Surplus in the Used-Textbook Market At a price of $30, Andrew, Betty, and Carlos each sell a book but Donna and Engelbert do not. Andrew, Betty, and Carlos get individual producer surpluses equal to the difference between the price and their cost, illustrated here by the shaded rectangles. Donna and Engelbert each have a cost that is greater than the price of $30, so they are unwilling to sell a book and so receive zero producer surplus. The total producer surplus is given by the entire shaded area, the sum of the individual producer surpluses of Andrew, Betty, and Carlos, equal to $25 +$15 +$5 =$45.

Price of wheat (per bushel) Quantity of wheat (bushels) Producer Surplus The total producer surplus from sales of a good at a given price is the area above the supply curve but below that price. $5 1 million Price of wheat (per bushel) Quantity of wheat (bushels) S Price = $5 Producer surplus Figure Caption: Figure 13.8 (49.8): Producer Surplus Here is the supply curve for wheat. At a price of $5 per bushel, farmers supply 1 million bushels. The producer surplus at this price is equal to the shaded area: the area above the supply curve but below the price. This is the total gain to producers— farmers in this case—from supplying their product when the price is $5.

How Changing Prices Affect Producer Surplus When the price of a good rises, producer surplus increases through two channels: the gains of those who would have supplied the good even at the original, lower price the gains of those who are induced to supply the good by the higher price

A Rise in the Price Increases Producer Surplus 1.5 million $7 5 1 million Price of wheat (per bushel) Quantity of wheat (bushels) Increase in producer surplus to original sellers Producer surplus gained by new sellers S Figure Caption: Figure 13.9 (49.9): A Rise in the Price Increases Producer Surplus A rise in the price of wheat from $5 to $7 leads to an increase in the quantity supplied and an increase in producer surplus. The change in total producer surplus is given by the sum of the shaded areas: the total area above the supply curve but between the old and new prices. The dark red area represents the gain to the farmers who would have supplied 1 million bushels at the original price of $5; they each receive an increase in producer surplus of $2 for each of those bushels. The triangular light red area represents the increase in producer surplus achieved by the farmers who supply the additional 500,000 bushels because of the higher price. Similarly, a fall in the price of wheat generates a reduction in producer surplus equal to the sum of the shaded areas.

The willingness to pay of each individual consumer determines the demand curve. The difference between willingness to pay and price is the net gain to the consumer, the individual consumer surplus. Total consumer surplus in a market, the sum of all individual consumer surpluses in a market. A rise in the price of a good reduces consumer surplus; a fall in the price increases consumer surplus.

The cost of each potential producer, the lowest price at which he or she is willing to supply a unit of that good, determines the supply curve. If the price of a good is above a producer’s cost, a sale generates a net gain to the producer, known as the individual producer surplus. Total producer surplus in a market, the sum of the individual producer surpluses in a market, is equal to the area above the market supply curve but below the price.