THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Advertisements

UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
1 Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
Choices Involving Risk
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 20/1 Chapter 20 Asymmetric Information and Market Behaviour.
The Economics of Information. Risk a situation in which there is a probability that an event will occur. People tend to prefer greater certainty and less.
Asymmetric Information ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
Chapter 15 APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
EXPECTED UTILITY AND RISK AVERSION
Industrial Economics Fall INFORMATION Basic economic theories: Full (perfect) information In reality, information is limited. Consumers do not know.
Uncertainty and Information
Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,
Imperfect Information: Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons
Economics of Information Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard Chapter 17.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.1 Chapter 14: Market Failures and Government Policy Prepared by: Kevin Richter, Douglas College.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 11 th Edition, Copyright 2012 PowerPoint prepared by.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
The Economics of Information and Choice Under Uncertainty.
1 Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
What is ‘Managed Care’? A ‘type’ of health insurance –combines both the financing of care (insurance) with the provision of care –variations in MC plans.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 17 Choice Making Under Uncertainty.
1 Extra Topics. 2 Economics of Information Thus far we have assumed all economic entities have perfect information when making decisions - this is obviously.
Market Failure 11 Farid Abolhassani.
20 UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION © 2012 Pearson Education.
Econ 2610: Principles of Microeconomics Yogesh Uppal
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior.
Chapter 14Copyright ©2009 by South-Western, a division of Cengage Learning. All rights reserved 1 ECON Designed by Amy McGuire, B-books, Ltd. 14 CHAPTER.
Chapter Thirty-Six Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets u In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded.
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples
Asymmetric Information
Consumer Choice With Uncertainty Part II: Examples
THE MARKET FOR "LEMONS": QUALITY UNCERTAINTY AND THE MARKET MECHANISM
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
Compensating Wage Differentials
Asymmetric Information
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE
APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS
19 Uncertainty and Information CHAPTER
Asymmetric Information
Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if . . .
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Utility Maximization Ch7
Heterogeneity One limitation of the static LS model lies in the heterogeneity assumption. In reality, individuals differ in preference and in information.
Markets with Asymmetric Information
The Basic Tools of Finance
Choices Involving Risk
The Basic Tools of Finance
Tutorial 4: Asymmetric Information
The Role of Government Chapter 14
Walter Nicholson Christopher Snyder
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization
Chapter 38 Asymmetric Information
Social Insurance: Social Security
The Basic Tools of Finance
Presentation transcript:

THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS EIGHTH EDITION WALTER NICHOLSON Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Properties of Information Information is not easy to define it is difficult to measure the quantity of information obtainable from different actions there are too many forms of useful information to permit the standard price-quantity characterization used in supply and demand analysis

Properties of Information Studying information also becomes difficult due to some technical properties of information it is durable and retains value after its use it can be nonrival and nonexcludable in this manner it can be considered a public good

The Value of information In many respects, lack of information does present a problem involving uncertainty for a decision maker the individual may not know exactly what the consequences of a particular action will be Better information can reduce uncertainty and lead to better decisions and higher utility

The Value of Information Assume an individual forms subjective opinions about the probabilities of two states of the world “good times” (probability = g) and “bad times” (probability = b) Information is valuable because it helps the individual revise his estimates

The Value of Information Assume that information can be measured by the number of “messages” (m) purchased g and b will be functions of m

The Value of Information The individual’s goal will be to maximize E(U) = gU(Wg) + bU(Wb) subject to I = PgWg + PbWb + Pmm We need to set up the Lagrangian L = gU(Wg) + bU(Wb) + (I-PgWg-PbWb-Pmm)

The Value of Information First-order conditions for a constrained maximum are:

The Value of Information First-order conditions for a constrained maximum are:

The Value of Information The first two equations show that the individual will maximize utility at a point where the subjective ratio of expected marginal utilities is equal to the price ratio (Pg /Pb) The last equation shows the utility-maximizing level of information to buy

The Value of Information Suppose that a consumer knows that one restaurant charges $1.25 for a burger and another charges $0.75 the consumer would like to purchase a burger at the cheaper restaurant could select one randomly or invest in a phone call to see which place is cheaper

The Value of Information Suppose that the indirect utility function is V = 0.5IPX-0.5PY-0.5 Let I = $2, PX = $0.25, and PY may be either $0.75 0r $1.25

The Value of Information If the consumer chooses where to shop by flipping a coin, expected utility is E(U) = 0.5V(PY=0.75) + 0.5V(PY=1.25) E(U) = 0.5(2.309) + 0.5(1.789) = 2.409 If the consumer knew which store offered the lower price, utility would be E(U) = V(PY=0.75) = 2.309 Price information raises utility

Asymmetry of Information The level of information that a person buys will depend on the price per unit Information costs may differ across individuals some may possess specific skills for acquiring information some may have experience that is relevant some may have made different former investments in information services

Information and Insurance There are a number of information asymmetries in the market for insurance Buyers are often in a better position to know the likelihood of uncertain events may also be able to take actions that impact these probabilities

Moral Hazard Moral hazard is the effect of insurance coverage on individuals’ decisions to undertake activities that may change the likelihood of incurring losses parking an insured car in an unsafe area choosing not to install a sprinkler system in an insured home

Moral Hazard Suppose a risk-averse individual faces the risk of a loss (L) that will lower wealth The probability of a loss is  This probability can be lowered by the amount the person spends on preventive measures (A)

E(U) = E = (1-)U(W1) + U(W2) Moral Hazard Wealth in the two states is given by W1 = W0 - A W2 = W0 - A - L The individual chooses A to maximize E(U) = E = (1-)U(W1) + U(W2)

Moral Hazard The first-order condition for a maximum is The optimal point is where the expected marginal utility cost from spending one additional dollar on prevention is equal to the reduction in the expected value of the utility loss that may be encountered in bad times

Moral Hazard Suppose that the individual may purchase insurance (premium = P) that pays X if a loss occurs Wealth in each state becomes W1 = W0 - A - P W2 = W0 - A - P - L + X A fair premium would be equal to P = X

Moral Hazard The person can maximize expected utility by choosing X such that W1 = W2 The first-order condition is

Moral Hazard Since W1 = W2, this condition becomes At the utility maximizing choice, the marginal cost of an extra unit of prevention should equal the marginal reduction in the expected loss provided by the extra spending With full insurance and actuarially fair premiums, precautionary purchases still occur at the optimal level

Moral Hazard So far, we have assumed that insurance providers know the probability of a loss and can charge the actuarially fair premium this is doubtful when individuals can undertake precautionary activities the insurance provider would have to constantly monitor each person’s activities to determine the correct probability of loss

Moral Hazard In the simplest case, the insurer might set a premium based on the average probability of loss experienced by some group of people no variation in premiums allowed for specific precautionary activities each individual would have an incentive to reduce his level of precautionary activities

Adverse Selection Individuals may have different probabilities of experiencing a loss If individuals know the probabilities more accurately than insurers, insurance markets may not function properly it will be difficult for insurers to set premiums based on accurate measures of expected loss

Adverse Selection Assume that two individuals certainty line W * W * - L Assume that two individuals have the same initial wealth (W*) and each face a potential loss of L E W1

Adverse Selection Suppose that one person has a probability of loss equal to H, while the other has a probability of loss equal to L W2 certainty line F G Both individuals would prefer to move to the certainty line if premiums are actuarially fair W * - L E W1 W *

Adverse Selection The blue and green lines show the market opportunities for each person to trade W1 for W2 by buying fair insurance W2 certainty line F G The low-risk person will maximize utility at point F, while the high-risk person will choose G W * - L E W1 W *

Adverse Selection If insurers have imperfect information about which individuals fall into low- and high-risk categories, this solution is unstable point F provides more wealth in both states high-risk individuals will want to buy insurance that is intended for low-risk individuals insurers will lose money on each policy sold

Adverse Selection One possible solution would be for the insurer to offer premiums based on the average probability of loss H W2 certainty line F Since EH does not accurately reflect the true probabilities of each buyer, they may not fully insure and may choose a point such as M M G W * - L E W1 W *

Adverse Selection Point M is not an equilibrium because further trading opportunities exist for low-risk individuals UH UL W2 certainty line An insurance policy such as N would be unattractive to high- risk individuals, but attractive to low-risk individuals and profitable for insurers N F H M G W * - L E W1 W *

Adverse Selection If a market has asymmetric information, the equilibria must be separated in some way high-risk individuals must have an incentive to purchase one type of insurance, while low-risk purchase another

Adverse Selection Suppose that insurers offer policy G. High-risk individuals will opt for full insurance. UH W2 certainty line Insurers cannot offer any policy that lies above UH because they cannot prevent high-risk individuals from taking advantage of it F G W * - L E W1 W *

Adverse Selection The best policy that low-risk individuals can obtain is one such as J J W2 certainty line F The policies G and J represent a separating equilibrium UH G W * - L E W1 W *

Adverse Selection Low-risk individuals could try to signal insurers their true probabilities of loss insurers must be able to determine if the signals are believable insurers may be able to infer accurate probabilities by observing their clients’ market behavior the separating equilibrium identifies an individual’s risk category

Adverse Selection Market signals can be drawn from a number of sources the economic behavior must accurately reflect risk categories the costs to individuals of taking the signaling action must be related to the probability of loss

Important Points to Note: Information is valuable because it permits individuals to increase the expected utility of their decisions Information has a number of special properties that suggest that inefficiencies associated with imperfect and asymmetric information may be quite prevalent

Important Points to Note: The presence of asymmetric information may affect a variety of market outcomes insurers may have less information about potential risks than do insurance buyers If insurers are unable to monitor the behavior of insured individuals accurately, moral hazard may arise being insured will affect the willingness to make precautionary expenditures

Important Points to Note: Informational asymmetries can also lead to adverse selection in insurance markets the resulting equilibria may often be inefficient because low-risk individuals will be worse off than in the full information case market signaling may be able to reduce these inefficiencies