Instrument taxonomy Early environmental policies, such as the Clean Air Act of 1970 and the Clean Water Act of 1972, relied almost exclusively on the command.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Getting More for Four Principles for Comprehensive Emissions Trading Jan Mazurek, Director Center for Innovation and the Environment 2002 Environmental.
Advertisements

Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 16 Stationary-Source Local Air Pollution.
EPA’s Clean Power Plan Proposed Rules for Reducing GHG Emissions from Power Plants Presentation to ACPAC June 16,
The Economics of Environmental Regulations Pollution Tax and Markets for Transferable Pollution Permits.
1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
Incentive-Based Strategies: Emission Charges and Subsidies
1 Topic 3.c: Tradable emission permits We have seen that tradable pollution permits compare favorably with other policy instruments we have considered.
THE ECONOMICS OF ENVIRONMENTAL QUALITY
Criteria for Evaluating Environmental Policies
Climate Change 1. What is climate change? IPCC: A change in the state of the climate that can be identified by changes in the mean and/or the variability.
Economic Solutions to Environmental Problems: The Market Approach
1 Topic 2: Production Externalities Examples of types of abatement activities analyzed: –Output reduction –Cleaner production involving  VC (ex: input-switching)
Policy for Market failure Prescriptive/Command and Control Strategies: “Standards”
Chapter 4 Conventional Solutions to Environmental Problems Command-and-Control Approach © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-Western Callan and Thomas, Environmental.
 Homework #3 Due Thursday  Quiz #2 Next Thursday Sept. 29th  Homework #4 Due Tuesday Oct. 11  Exam #2 Tuesday Oct. 11  Writing Assignment Due Oct.
The Economics of Environmental Regulation Public Regulation or the Market.
Chapter 4 Conventional Solutions to Environmental Problems: The Command-and-Control Approach © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Improving Air Quality: Controlling Stationary Sources Chapter 13 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternThomas and Callan, Environmental Economics.
Air Quality Beyond Ozone and PM2.5 Sheila Holman North Carolina Division of Air Quality 6 th Annual Unifour Air Quality Conference June 15, 2012.
1 Topic 3.a: Introduction At the end of Topic 2 we identified the efficient level of abatement/emissions. The question of policy is: What policies can.
Class 7 Environmental Policy Tools
Assessment of Mercury Rules for Electric Generators in North Carolina September 9, 2015 Presented to the Environmental Management Commission – Air Quality.
NTEC -- April 24, Utility Air Toxics Regulatory Finding National Tribal Environmental Council April 24, 2001 William H. Maxwell U.S. EPA OAQPS/ESD/CG.
1 EPA’s Climate Change Strategy Robert J. Meyers Principal Deputy Assistant Administrator U.S. EPA, Office of Air and Radiation December 3, 2007.
Chapter 4 Conventional Solutions to Environmental Problems: Command-and-Control Approach.
Policy for Market failure Prescriptive/Command and Control Strategies: “Standards”
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 17 The Economics of Environmental Protection.
Market Failures Multiple market failures at issue “No single instrument is superior along all dimensions relevant to a policy choice.” Typical Market Failures.
Market Failure Market failure refers to reasons why even a perfectly
1 Chapter Twenty-one Environmental Policy. 2 The Controversies Environmental policy creates both winners and losers –Losers could be those who pay but.
Command-and-Control Strategies: The Case of Standards Chapter 11.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 14 Stationary-Source Local Air Pollution.
Item #11 Alternative Approaches for Linking Greenhouse Gas Emissions Reductions to Metropolitan Transportation Planning Presentation to the National Capital.
Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”
Air Quality Management Comparison of Cap-and-Trade, Command-and Control and Rate-Based Programs Dr. Ruben Deza Senior Environmental Engineer Clean Air.
Improving Air Quality: Controlling Stationary Sources Chapter 12 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Unit 7 Vote for Pedro!!!. Who should control environmental- quality decision making??? Public sector (government)? Private sector (businesses & individuals)?
Proposed Carbon Pollution Standard For New Power Plants Presented by Kevin Culligan Office of Air Quality Planning And Standards Office of Air and Radiation.
Change picture on Slide Master It’s Not Easy Being Green: What’s Up on Warming in Washington? Virginia Bar Association July 25, 2009 PRESENTED BY Peter.
© 2013 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
Command And Control Strategies: The Case of Standards Lecture 18.
ExternalitiesExternalities. Overview Externalities –Negative: Action by one party imposes a cost on another party –Positive: Action by one party benefits.
Climate: ANPR, SIPs and Section 821 WESTAR October 2, 2008.
An Intro to the Economics of Climate Policy
A General Model of Pollution Control
Gov’t Solutions for Pollution
Topic 5: Public Policy Instruments
Policy Instruments February 6, 2013 Sustainable Energy Policy.
Clean Air Act Glossary.
NSPS Rulemakings for Greenhouse Gas Emissions
IMPLICATIONS AND STRATEGIES
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
The Failure of Cap and Trade in GHG Emissions Controls
NSPS Rulemakings for Greenhouse Gas Emissions
A General Model of Pollution Control
Methane Emission Standards for Crude Oil and Natural Gas Facilities
Environmental and Natural Resource Economics
Air Quality in Southern California and SCAQMD
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Department of Environmental Quality
Environmental and Natural Resource Economics 3rd ed. Jonathan M
Chapter 14 Environmental Economics
Taxes, Standards and Tradable Permits
AIR Quality Control Concepts
Incentive Based Strategies: Transferable Discharge Permits
Environmental Economics
Environmental Policy Mixes: Motivations, Evidence & Effectiveness
Policy Mix or Evolution?
The Economics of Environmental Quality
Session 7: Public Policy Instruments
Presentation transcript:

Policy for Market failure Prescriptive/Command and Control Strategies: “Standards”

Instrument taxonomy Early environmental policies, such as the Clean Air Act of 1970 and the Clean Water Act of 1972, relied almost exclusively on the command and control (standards) approach. (Stavins, 1998)

Types of standards Performance standard: a regulation prescribing a maximum allowable pollution level. Two common forms: Emissions rate: a never exceed level for a quantity of emissions from a polluter E.g. emissions/year; emissions/(unit of input); emissions/(unit of output) Ambient concentration: a never exceed level for a pollutant in the environment E.g. TMDLs (Total Maximum Daily Loads of contaminants in streams and rivers)

Types of standards Technology based standard: a regulation prescribing specifying the method (sometimes the actual equipment) that firms must use. 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments: new electric power plants required to install scrubbers to reduce SO2 in flue gas (K&O p. 130) catalytic converter required on automobiles to reduce concentrations of emissions

Example: Clean Air Act of 1970 Required that costly scrubbers be used by coal-fired electricity plants even though it would have been cheaper to achieve SO2 reductions by substituting to low sulfur coal. Imposed by senators from eastern states with high sulfur coal. Political feasibility: could not otherwise have passed congress. Hackett, S., Environmental and Natural Resources Economics: Theory, Policy, and the Sustainable Society, 3rd Edition (New York: M.E. Sharpe, 2006), p. 224.

1/27/16: California Energy Commission adopts nation's first-ever rules for LED lighting (Mulkern, Greenwire, 1/28/16) Claimed effect: >$4B energy savings over 13 years; conserve electricity to power ~400K average homes. http://www.eenews.net/greenwire/2016/01/28/stories/1060031314 http://www.energy.ca.gov/releases/2016_releases/2016-01-27_adoption_of_lighting_standards_nr.html

EPA Sets Thresholds for Greenhouse Gas Permitting July 2011: Clean Air Act permitting requirements for GHGs will kick in for large facilities all new facilities with GHG emissions of at least 100,000 tpy and modifications at existing facilities that would increase GHG emissions by at least 75,000 tpy must use best available control technologies to minimize GHG emission increases Update: 2013: http://www.epa.gov/nsr/ghgdocs/20120914CAAACPermitStreamlining.pdf http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/d0cf6618525a9efb85257359003fb69d/ea1bf25579e541b1852577220055c20c!OpenDocument http://www.biologicaldiversity.org/programs/climate_law_institute/global_warming_litigation/clean_air_act/pdfs/Clean-Air-Act-FAQ.pdf “In response to a Clean Air Act petition and litigation, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled in 2007 that greenhouse gases are “air pollutants” under the Clean Air Act and must be regulated if the EPA determines through an “endangerment finding” that they “may reasonably be anticipated to endanger public health or welfare.” The EPA has released a draft endangerment finding and is moving forward with greenhouse gas pollution reductions under several sections of the Clean Air Act — including sections that address mobile (e.g. automobiles, ships, and airplanes) and stationary (e.g. smokestacks) sources.” Update 12/23/10: http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/d0cf6618525a9efb85257359003fb69d/cad212db554919ec8525780200570c1c!OpenDocument Beginning in January 2011, industries that are large emitters of GHGs, and are planning to build new facilities or make major modifications to existing ones, must obtain air permits and implement energy efficiency measures or, where available, cost-effective technology to reduce their GHGs emissions. This includes the nation's largest GHG emitters, such as power plants, refineries and cement production facilities. Emissions from small sources, such as farms and restaurants are not covered by these GHG permitting requirements. 1/28/11: http://yosemite.epa.gov/opa/admpress.nsf/d0cf6618525a9efb85257359003fb69d/1803003975383dca85257826006a5fee!OpenDocument The agency is in the process of gathering information and seeking important input and, as part of a settlement agreement announced December 23, 2010, will propose GHG standards based on existing technologies for power plants in July 2011 and for refineries in December 2011. The agency will issue final standards in May 2012 and November 2012, respectively.

Basic model of performance standards Initial emissions, e1 Impose a standard of a maximum of e* tons/year emitted Given e*, what area represents: total abatement cost, TAC? total damage, TD? (standard pollution control model) b c

Basic model of performance standards Initial emissions, e1 Impose a standard of a maximum of e* tons/year emitted Given e*, what area represents: total abatement cost, TAC? total damage, TD? (standard pollution control model) b c

Empirical evidence of standards lack of cost effectiveness (Stavins, 1998) One survey of 8 empirical studies of air pollution control found that C&C standards were anywhere from 1.07 to 22.0 times more costly (TAC) to implement than the least-cost alternative policy instrument. 1.07 for sulfate emissions in the Los Angeles area to 22.0 for hydrocarbon emissions at all domestic DuPont plants www.tva.gov/

When might standards be preferable? Hotspots: market-based instruments may allow for areas of high pollution which is problematic for some emissions (e.g. mercury). Certain control technology may be so effective/ available that mandating is more effective than regulating “emissions” (e.g. double-hulled oil tankers). Too costly to effectively monitor emissions (e.g. catalytic converters on automobiles). NADP 2014: precipitation-weighted mean concentrations and deposition image: Yes I Can Science http://nadp.sws.uiuc.edu/maplib/pdf/mdn/hg_Conc_2014.pdf thinglink.com

Summary of conclusions on standards in policy Initially appear simple and straightforward Potential weaknesses: Lack of short- and long-run cost effectiveness Limited flexibility in achieving goals Weak incentive for innovation may lock in particular technologies Potential advantages: monitoring and enforcement costs avoiding “hotspots”

Additional slides for review outside of class

Standards are often set uniformly but this is not typically cost-effective Standards are often uniform (identical across firms). The central issue in assessing the cost effectiveness of standards Typically firms will have different MAC functions Uniform standard will not be cost-effective Could achieve greater reduction at same total cost, or Could achieve same reduction at reduced total cost

Cost effective pollution control: Minimizing costs $ e: emissions perf. standard What area represents total abatement costs (TACA) for this single polluter? MACA Z e0 e emissions, e abatement

Cost effective pollution control: Minimizing costs $ MACB e: emissions perf. standard (uniform across both A & B) What area represents total abatement costs, in agg. for both polluters: TAC = TACA +TACB? Is the uniform standard cost effective? MACA Y Z eA = eB = e0 e emissions, e

Cost effective pollution control: Minimizing costs $ MACB e: emissions perf. standard (uniform across both A & B) What area represents total abatement costs, in agg. for both polluters: TAC = TACA +TACB? Is the uniform standard cost effective? MACA Y Z eA = eB = e0 e emissions, e

Cost effective pollution control: Minimizing costs e * 2 = e*A + e*B reallocate abatement but keep aggregate emissions the same  non-uniform std. What area represents total abatement costs, in agg. for both polluters: TAC = TACA +TACB? What expression specifies reduced TAC from non-uniform standard? $ MACB MACA Y1 Note: Y=Y1+Y2 Z=Z1+Z2 Y2 X Z1 Z2 e0 eA = e*A e emissions, e eB = e*B

Arguments… For uniform standards: Lower implementation costs (likely lower than for non-uniform standards) to make non-uniform standards cost-effective, you need the MAC function for every source – a costly information requirement equity (treats everyone alike…which is not necessarily always a fair or equitable approach) Against uniformity: When marginal abatement costs differ among sources Uniformity is not cost-effective (assuming MAC curves known or “easy” to assess) Equity and leveling the economic playing field don’t necessarily imply equal standards.

Incentives generated by standards (long-run impacts) Technology innovation Conceptual model: + demand for abatement tech. + R&D  + technology innovation  MAC curve falls Standards: tend to freeze development of technologies which would lead to greater levels of control. Especially technology standards Little or no financial incentive to exceed control targets (Stavins, 1998) A business that adopts a new technology may be "rewarded" by being held to a higher standard of performance A business that adopts a new technology may be "rewarded" by being held to a higher standard of performance, NOT given the opportunity to benefit financially from its investment (except to the extent its competitors have even more difficulty reaching the new standard)

Use the basic model to examine incentives for innovation Start: MAC1 … innovationMAC2 Questions: Given a mandated standard of e2 (assume compliance is perfect) What level of abatement does the firm choose? (Under MAC1? MAC2?) What is the firm’s TAC (total abatement cost) at this level? What is the incentive (the benefit to the firm) to innovating? The new (post-innovation) socially efficient level of emissions is e3, What happens to R&D incentive if the firm believes the post-innovation standard will be set to e3?

Cost effective pollution control: Minimizing costs This is how your textbook presents the ideas from the slide “Cost effective pollution control: Minimizing costs”. (Can be more confusing for some.) What does the area described by c represent? K&O, figure 9.1