Subadditivity of Cost Functions

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Efficiency and Productivity Measurement: Index Numbers
Advertisements

U NNATURAL MONOPOLIES IN LOCAL TELEPHONE By Richard T. Shin * and John S. Ying* Sifat-E-Sharmeen Econ 435.
[Part 4] 1/25 Stochastic FrontierModels Production and Cost Stochastic Frontier Models William Greene Stern School of Business New York University 0Introduction.
Lecture XXIII.  In general there are two kinds of hypotheses: one concerns the form of the probability distribution (i.e. is the random variable normally.
If economic analysis is to be at all useful, then the multiproduct setting must be addressed. Concepts such as decreasing average cost and economies of.
ARE COMBINATION GAS AND ELECTRIC UTILITIES MULTIPRODUCT NATURAL MONOPOLIES? - Merrile Sing Presentation Eco 435 Date 31 January 2012.
Testing for Subadditivity of Vertically Integrated Electric Utilities Keith Gilsdorf.
Definition and Properties of the Cost Function
Definition and Properties of the Production Function Lecture II.
Applied Economics for Business Management
1 Costs Curves Chapter 8. 2 Chapter Eight Overview 1.Introduction 2.Long Run Cost Functions Shifts Long run average and marginal cost functions Economies.
Existence of Natural Monopoly in Multiproduct Firms Competition Policy and Market Regulation MEFI- Università di Pavia.
Mohammad S. A. Khan Mamun, PhD Department of Economics Cost of Production & Cost Curves.
Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX. Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with.
Cost Functions and the Estimation of Flexible Functional Forms Lecture XVIII.
Efficiency Measurement William Greene Stern School of Business New York University.
Comparative Statics and Duality of the Cost Function Lecture VII.
Copyright © 2005 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice eighth edition Chapter 9.
Overview of Optimization in Ag Economics Lecture 2.
5-5 Solving Quadratic Equations Objectives:  Solve quadratic equations.
Econ 102 SY Lecture 7 Profit Maximization and Supply August 21, 24 and 28, 2008.
DR MONIKA JAIN KEY MEASURES AND RELATIONSHIPS. REVENUE The total monetary value of the goods or services sold is called revenue. The difference between.
ECE 8443 – Pattern Recognition ECE 8423 – Adaptive Signal Processing Objectives: Normal Equations The Orthogonality Principle Solution of the Normal Equations.
Finding the Minimum Using Newton’s Method Lecture I.
Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Chapter 5: Production and Cost Copyright.
9-1 Learning Objectives  Graph a typical production isoquant and discuss the properties of isoquants  Construct isocost curves  Use optimization theory.
Lecture XXVII. Orthonormal Bases and Projections Suppose that a set of vectors {x 1,…,x r } for a basis for some space S in R m space such that r  m.
MathematicalMarketing Slide 3c.1 Mathematical Tools Chapter 3: Part c – Parameter Estimation We will be discussing  Nonlinear Parameter Estimation  Maximum.
AEC 506 INTRODUCTION TO LIVESTOCK ECONOMICS AND MARKETING LECTURE 5 MARGINAL COST AND RETURN AND LAW OF DIMNISHING MARGINAL RETURN.
Lecture 2, Costs and technology
Production and Cost in the Firm
The Costs of Production
Chapter 6 Production.
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
State Space Representation
UNIT 6 COSTS AND PRODUCTION: LONG AND SHORT-RUN, TOTAL, FIXED AND VARIABLE COSTS, LAW OF DIMINISHING RETURNS, INCREASING, CONSTANT AND DIMINISHING RETURNS.
Labor demand in the long run
Production, Costs & Profits
EMGT 6412/MATH 6665 Mathematical Programming Spring 2016
Chapter 9 Production and Cost in the Long Run
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
Production and cost.
Chapter 5: Production and Cost
Managerial Economics Eighth Edition Truett + Truett
Module 55: Firm Costs.
Continuous improvement is the process by which organizations frequently review their procedures, aiming to correct errors or problems. The most effective.
Review of the previous lecture
Principals of Economics Law Class
Economies of scale up output Q'
Chapter 20 Costs of Production.
Chapter 7 The Cost of Production.
Technology and Costs Lecture 4
7 The Production Process: The Behavior of Profit-Maximizing Firms
Production & Cost in the Long Run
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Microeconomics, 9e
Costs: Economics and Accounting
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Undergraduated Econometrics
State Space Analysis UNIT-V.
Chapter 7 Costs of Production.
Chapter 9 Costs.
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
Pattern Classification All materials in these slides were taken from Pattern Classification (2nd ed) by R. O. Duda, P. E. Hart and D. G. Stork, John.
Outline Unconstrained Optimization Functions of One Variable
Parametric Methods Berlin Chen, 2005 References:
Chapter 4. Time Response I may not have gone where I intended to go, but I think I have ended up where I needed to be. Pusan National University Intelligent.
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
7 The Production Process: The Behavior of Profit-Maximizing Firms
Copyright (c)2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
Presentation transcript:

Subadditivity of Cost Functions Lecture XX

Concepts of Subadditivity Evans, D. S. and J. J. Heckman. “A Test for Subadditivity of the Cost Function with an Application to the Bell System.” American Economic Review 74(1984): 615-23. The issue addressed in this article involves the emergence of natural monopolies. Specifically, is it possible that a single firm is the most cost-efficient way to generate the product.

In the specific application, the researchers are interested in the Bell System (the phone company before it was split up).

The cost function C(q) is subadditive at some output level if and only if: which states that the cost function is subadditive if a single firm could produce the same output for less cost. As a mathematical nicety, the point must have at least two nonzero firms. Otherwise the cost function is by definition the same.

Developing a formal test, Evans and Heckman assume a cost function based on two input: Thus, each of i firms produce ai percent of output q1 and bi percent of the output q2.

A primary focus of the article is the region over which subadditivity is tested. The cost function is subadditive, and the technology implies a natural monopoly. The cost function is superadditive, and the firm could save money by breaking itself up into two or more divisions.

The cost function is additive The notion of additivity combines two concepts from the cost function: Economies of Scope and Economies of Scale.

Under Economies of Scope, it is cheaper to produce two goods together Under Economies of Scope, it is cheaper to produce two goods together. The example I typically give for this is the grazing cattle on winter wheat. However, we also recognize following the concepts of Coase, Williamson, and Grossman and Hart that there may diseconomies of scope. The second concept is the economies of scale argument that we have discussed before.

As stated previously, a primary focus of this article is the region of subadditivity. In our discussion of cost functions, I have mentioned the concepts of Global versus local. To make the discussion more concrete, let us return to our discussion of concavity.

From the properties of the cost function, we know that the cost function is concave in input price space. Thus, using the Translog form: The gradient vector for the Translog cost function is then:

Given that the cost is always positive, the positive versus negative nature of the matrix is determined by: Comparing this results with the result for the quadratic function, we see that

Thus, the Hessian of the Translog varies over input prices and output levels while the Hessian matrix for the Quadratic does not. In this sense, the restrictions on concavity for the Quadratic cost function are global–they do not change with respect to output and input prices. However, the concavity restrictions on the Translog are local–fixed at a specific point, because they depend on prices and output levels.

Note that this is important for the Translog Note that this is important for the Translog. Specifically, if we want the cost function to be concave in input prices:

Thus, any discussion of subadditivity, especially if a Translog cost function is used (or any cost function other than a quadratic), needs to consider the region over which the cost function is to be tested.

Admissible Region q2 q1 C

Thus, much of the discussion in Evans and Heckman involve the choice of the region for the test. Specifically, the test region is restricted to a region of observed point.

Defining q. 1M as the minimum amount of q1 produced by any firm and q Defining q*1M as the minimum amount of q1 produced by any firm and q*2M as the minimum amount of q2 produced, we an define alternative production bundles as:

Thus, the production for any firm can be divided into two components within the observed range of output. Thus, subadditivity can be defined as:

If Subt(f,w) is less than zero, the cost function is subadditive, if it is equal to zero the cost function is additive, and if it is greater than zero, the cost function is superadditive. Consistent with their concept of the region of the test, Evans and Heckman calculate the maximum and minimum Subt(f,w) for the region.

Composite Cost Functions and Subadditivity Pulley, L. B. and Y. M. Braunstein. “A Composite Cost Function for Multiproduct Firms with an Application to Economies of Scope in Banking.” Review of Economics and Statistics 74(1992): 221-30.

Building on the concept of subadditivity and the global nature of the flexible function form, it is apparent that the estimation of subadditivity is dependent on functional form

Pulley and Braunstein allow for a more general form of the cost function by allowing the Box-Cox transformation to be different for the inputs and outputs.

If f=0, p=0 and t=1 the form yields a standard Translog with normal share equations. If f=0 and t=1 the form yields a generalized Translog:

If p=1,t=0 and U,Y=0, the specification becomes a separable quadratic specification

The demand equations for the composite function is:

Given the estimates, we can then measure Economies of Scope in two ways. The first measures is a traditional measure:

Another measure suggested by the article is “quasi” economies of scope

The Economies of Scale are then defined as: