Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman 2015

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
4. Public Goods.
Advertisements

1 Chapter 4 Public Goods. 2 Public Goods are goods for which exclusion is impossible. One example is National Defense: A military that defends one citizen.
Public Goods & Externalities
Public Goods & Common Resources ECO 230 J.F. OConnor.
Chapter 4 - Public Goods Public Economics.
Chapter 4: Public Goods Econ 330: Public Finance Dr. Reyadh Faras
Public Goods © Allen C. Goodman, 2002 Services in an Urban Setting Lots of services are provided through public funds Schools, police, fire protection,
Public Goods. A public good is one that is nonrival and nonexclusionary in consumption. Nonrival means that when you consume the good it does not diminish.
4. Provision of Public Goods
Chapter 36 Public Goods Suppose there are two nonsmokers and one smoker. Even if nonsmokers are entitled to clean air, they first have to agree among themselves.
Chapter 7: Public Goods Outline Optimal provision of public goods.
Fig. 1 The Value of Another Guitar Lessons $25 $23 $21 $19 $17 Demand Flo Flo (again) Joe Bo Zoe Price Number of Lessons per Week While the first.
The role of government Today: Public goods; government failure; taxation.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Distinguish among private goods, public goods,
Chapter 4 Public Goods Why is public goods?
Externalities and Public Goods
1 Public Goods. 2 A public good is one that is nonrival and nonexclusionary in consumption. Nonrival means that when you consume the good it does not.
 Group Quiz Thursday  Homework #2 Due Next Thursday  Exam #1 Next Thursday  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 27th.
Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman Public Goods Most important factor is that everyone gets the same amount. We have to get some agreement as.
1 Government production Should the government produce as a monopolist or try to act like a competitive firm?
Externalities, Commons and Public Goods
Theme 4 - Public Goods Public Economics.
1 Chapter 4 Public Goods. 2 Public Goods are goods for which exclusion is impossible. One example is National Defense: A military that defends one citizen.
Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman Public Goods Most important factor is that everyone gets the same amount. We have to get some agreement as.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 17: Public Goods The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger.
1 More on Fees and Charges © Allen C. Goodman, 2011.
Chapter 4 Efficiency: Public Goods and Externalities Chapter outline The rationale for government production of goods and services. 1.Public Goods, Private.
Demand: The Benefit Side of the Market. 2 Law of Demand  Law of Demand  People do less of what they want to do as the cost of doing it rises  Recall.
Chapter 5 ELEMENTS OF DEMAND AND CONSUMER CHOICE.
ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications 3e HALL & LIEBERMAN © 2005 Thomson Business and Professional Publishing Economic Efficiency and the Role of Government.
Public Finance (MPA405) Dr. Khurrum S. Mughal. Lecture 7: Public Goods Public Finance.
4-1 Session 3 Public Goods. 4-2 Public goods defined Goods can be classified according to two attributes: –whether they are excludable –whether they are.
1 Public Goods. Public Goods Defined 2 Pure public goods share two characteristics Nonrival – Cost of another person consuming the good is zero Nonexcludable.
Equity & Efficiency Does this system allocate limited resources efficiently? – Most economists agree that this system leads to a very efficient allocation.
Health Insurance Exchanges
Topics Externalities. The Inefficiency of Competition with Externalities. Regulating Externalities. Market Structure and Externalities. Allocating Property.
Public Goods Many definitions in use
AP MICROECONOMICS UNIT #6 MARKET FAILURE/ ROLE OF GOVERNMENT
Today The ice cream problem Market Demand Curves.
Power of the Market Free Enterprise.
Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2003 © McGraw-Hill
Perfect Competition: Short Run and Long Run
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2017
Rules for the game! No computers on
Citizens Make a Difference
Public Finance, 10th Edition
Chapter 4 - Public Goods Public Economics.
Economics, markets, and organizations
Mehdi Arzandeh, University of Manitoba
Market Failure (?): Public Goods & Common Property
Homework Chapter 3.
4. Provision of Public Goods
Which is the fairest way for income taxes?
Public Goods & Externalities
Public Goods Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* Micro:
Cost Minimization and Cost Curves
State and Local Government Expenditures
Chapter 4 Public Goods.
Privatization  Prices
Unit 1 Governing the People
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2017
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2019
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2019
Chapter 37 Public Goods Key Concept: Free Riding.
Today The ice cream problem Market Demand Curves.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Environmental Economics
7500_L_18_Hedonic_Prices © Allen C. Goodman, 2009
DEV 501: THE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE
Session 3: Market Efficiency and Sustainability
Presentation transcript:

Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman 2015 7/1/2018 Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman 2015

Public Goods Most important factor is that everyone gets the same amount. We have to get some agreement as to how much we’ll want (we’ll discuss that a lot). We’ll have to get some agreement as to how to pay for it (we’ll discuss that a lot, also).

What do you think about libraries? Go around class. What do you think about tennis courts? Go around class. What do you think about sidewalks? Go around class.

Query: Why, necessarily should tennis courts be provided publicly? Why shouldn’t people join private tennis clubs? Consider a Town Trying to decide how many tennis courts should be provided in public parks. Comes out to be a number per 10,000 people. Marginal benefit is in hundreds of dollars. Cost is in hundreds of dollars. Let’s assume MC is 32. We have people like Adam, Bert, and Charlie. Assume we have enough people to collect money to build what they might want.

Look at Adam What does this mean? MB = 30 - Q

Look at Bert MB = 20 - 2Q

Look at Charlie MB = 20 – 0.5Q

Building up the Curve Look at spreadsheet This isn’t what we usually do! A+B+C Why are we doing it this way? A+C A

Sum of Marginal Benefits – Calculation Efficient Amount at Q = 12 Why? At Q = 12, they are worth $1800 to Adam $0 to Bert $1400 to Charlie

What happens if demand changes? – Calculation Look at spreadsheet

Tricky Issue How do we pay for these. Why do it publicly? Suppose we say “How many tennis courts should we build?” assuming it costs $3,200 to build them. What will happen? A> No one here values a single court at $3,200, BUT collectively, they value 12!

Lindahl equilibrium With 12 courts Adam values them at 18(00) Bert values them at 0 Charlie values them at 14(00) If we “know” these values, we can charge the people accordingly. This is sometimes called a “Lindahl” equilibrium.

Problems w/ Lindahl Eq’m With private goods, people pay … it means that they value the goods at least that much. How do we get people to reveal preferences if we’re not withholding services from those who won’t pay? What if MC is close to 0? If we charge where MB = MC, we get close to 0 price, and may not be able to afford the good. It may be hard to exclude those who won’t pay, although for tennis court you could charge an hourly fee. Can’t do the same for police protection. Can’t do the same for religious services (!?).

Who provides? Some public goods are provided at the national level. National defense for example (at least in US) – although in some other (generally less developed) countries you often have local militias. Others at the state, county, or lower levels. Some amounts of goods are also provided privately. Ford, or GM do not depend on public police to guard their property, for example.

More Advanced – Public Goods It's helpful to derive a public good equilibrium. My favorite way is a simple one where we have a social welfare function in which: W = W(U1, U2, U3, ...) = Weighted Σ Ui for a community of individuals. We must decide how much public good to make. In the pure sense, the public good is nonexcludable and nonrival. Ui = Ui (xi , G) X =  xi = f (G) Constraint (why) f' < 0.

Public Goods So, optimize W = wiUi (xi, G) +  [ xi - f(G)] (1) w1 = -/U1x w2 = -/U2x w3 = -/U3x Etc. So, optimize W = wiUi (xi, G) +  [ xi - f(G)] (1) w.r.t. xi W/xi = wiUix +  = 0. (2) w.r.t. G W/G =  wiUiG - f' = 0 (3) From (2) wi = -/Uix Insert into (3) W/G =  UiG/UiX + f' = 0 (3) Factor out , and we get:  UiG/UiX + f' = 0   MRSGX = -f' = MRT Well-known Samuelson condition.

KEY Point With private goods, we can exclude others. We add demand horizontally. With public goods, we cannot exclude others. We add demand vertically. If everyone gets the same amount, then the appropriate benefit measure is “how much (together) they value the amount that they get.” This is a vertical summation.