Rolf Aaberge, Statistics Norway and CHILD

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Fairness and Social Welfare Functions. Deriving the Utility Possibility Frontier (UPF) We begin with the Edgeworth Box that starts with individual 1,and.
Advertisements

Women, Taxes and Social Security Income Taxes Social Security.
SA-1 Probabilistic Robotics Planning and Control: Partially Observable Markov Decision Processes.
FTP Biostatistics II Model parameter estimations: Confronting models with measurements.
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Profit-Maximization. Economic Profit u Profit maximization provides the rationale for firms to choose the feasible production plan. u Profit is the difference.
Random effects estimation RANDOM EFFECTS REGRESSIONS When the observed variables of interest are constant for each individual, a fixed effects regression.
Silberschatz, Galvin and Gagne  2002 Modified for CSCI 399, Royden, Operating System Concepts Operating Systems Lecture 19 Scheduling IV.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
Visual Recognition Tutorial
Evaluating Alternative Representations of the Choice Set In Models of Labour Supply Rolf Aaberge, Ugo Colombino and Tom Wennemo Workshop on Discrete Choice.
A microeconometric model for analysing efficiency and distributional effects of tax reforms Evidence from Italy and Norway Rolf Aaberge (Research Department,
Chapter 14 – Efficient and Equitable Taxation
Chapter 18: Distributionally-Weighted Cost Benefit Analysis.
Chapter 2 – Tools of Positive Analysis
EHM Theory and Structure Behavioural Labour Supply Modelling in DWP Alan Duncan, 6 th May 2009.
Distributive Politics and Economic Growth Alberto Alesina and Dani Rodrik Economic Growth Spring Semester, 2009 Benedikte Fogh Larsen.
Estimation 8.
BINARY CHOICE MODELS: LOGIT ANALYSIS
The redistributive effects of Personal Income Tax reforms during the Great Recession in Spain M. Adiego (IEF), O. Cantó (UAH), M. Paniagua (IEF) and T.
Chapter 18: Introduction to Taxation This lecture discusses a few institutional and theoretical issues for understanding tax policy. Overview of the types.
The Tax-Transfer System and Labor Supply Michael P. Keane University of Oxford Becker – Friedman Institute University of Chicago September 27, 2013.
Unit 6 - Fiscal Policy  Fiscal Policy Governments make decisions regarding spending and taxation. Macroeconomics.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 3/1 Chapter 3 Demand Theory.
Monetary Policy Responses to Food and Fuel Price Volatility Eswar Prasad Cornell University, Brookings Institution and NBER.
University of Turin Frisch Centre - Oslo Slutsky elasticities when the utility is random John K. Dagsvik Statistics Norway and the Frisch Centre,
Alternative approaches to Long Term Care financing. Distributive implications and sustainability for Italy Massimo Baldini and Luca Beltrametti European.
Chapter 16 Income Taxation
Section 8.1 Estimating  When  is Known In this section, we develop techniques for estimating the population mean μ using sample data. We assume that.
Tax-benefits indicators from a work incentives perspective Comments upon Christopher Heady and Herwig Immervoll – “Rewarding Jobs: Government Policy and.
Trust-Aware Optimal Crowdsourcing With Budget Constraint Xiangyang Liu 1, He He 2, and John S. Baras 1 1 Institute for Systems Research and Department.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance © 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 1 of 43 Theoretical Tools.
ACTIVE WELFARE STATE POLICIES AND WOMEN LABOUR PARTICIPATION IN SPAIN Xisco Oliver and Amedeo Spadaro University of the Balearic Islands 2nd Microsimulation.
ECE 8443 – Pattern Recognition ECE 8423 – Adaptive Signal Processing Objectives: Deterministic vs. Random Maximum A Posteriori Maximum Likelihood Minimum.
LECTURER: JACK WU The Theory of Property Tax. Outline Topic I: What Are Property Taxes? Topic II: Property Tax Incidence Topic III: Property Tax Capitalization.
Time, Money and Inequality in International Perspective Lars Osberg -Dalhousie University -I.S.E.R. U of Essex.
SemiBoost : Boosting for Semi-supervised Learning Pavan Kumar Mallapragada, Student Member, IEEE, Rong Jin, Member, IEEE, Anil K. Jain, Fellow, IEEE, and.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 44 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance F ERNANDO.
Population ageing and future tax burdens An integrated micro-macro analysis of possible taxation policy changes R Aaberge, Statistics Norway U Colombino,
Designing Optimal Taxes with a Microeconometric Model of Labour Supply Evidence from Norway Rolf Aaberge, Statistics Norway and CHILD Ugo Colombino, Univ.
We estimate a microeconometric model of household labor supply which features: simultaneous treatment of spouses’ decisions exact representation of complex.
Behavioural and Welfare Effects of Basic Income Schemes Ugo Colombino (Department of Economics and CHILD-CCA ) and M. Locatelli, E. Narazani, I. Shima.
Social Evaluation of Alternative Basic Income Schemes in Italy R. Aaberge (Statistics Norway, Oslo) U. Colombino (Department of Economics, Torino) S. Strøm.
University of Turin Department of Economics MODELLING HOUSEHOLD CHOICES OF DWELLING AND LOCAL PUBLIC SERVICES: A Behavioural Simulation of the Effects.
Session 3 Review Distributions Pen’s parade, quantile function, cdf Size, spread, poverty Data Income vector, cdf Today Inequality and economics Welfare.
Lecture 3: MLE, Bayes Learning, and Maximum Entropy
Designing Optimal Taxes with a Microeconometric Model of Labour Supply Evidence from Norway Rolf Aaberge, Ugo Colombino and Tom Wennemo WPEG Conference,
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization Presented by: Kuan Chen.
Chapter 6. Supply of Labor to the Economy Importance of Labor Supply 1) Any country ’ s well-being in the long run heavily depends on the willingness of.
Unit 6 - Fiscal Policy Fiscal Policy
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza
An Empirical Framework for Large-Scale Policy Analysis, with an Application to School Finance Reform in Michigan Maria Marta Ferreyra Tepper School.
Lesson 8: Basic Monte Carlo integration
Optimal Income Taxation When Top Income Inequality Increases
EFFICIENT REDISTRIBUTION THROUGH THE REDUCTION OF COMPLIANCE COSTS
INCOME REDISTRIBUTION
KEY INDICATORS OF THE LABOUR MARKET - KILM
Author: Konstantinos Drakos Journal: Economica
The Theory of Individual Labor Supply
Behavioural Microsimulation and Policy Analysis
Theoretical Tools of Public Finance
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chap 3. The simplex method
Where did we stop? The Bayes decision rule guarantees an optimal classification… … But it requires the knowledge of P(ci|x) (or p(x|ci) and P(ci)) We.
Determinants of Household Allocation of Income in Iceland
Michal Horváth, Zuzana Siebertová Meeting of the Network of EU IFIs Workshop on Microsimulation Rome, 4th May, 2018.
Chapter 7: The Normality Assumption and Inference with OLS
Chapter 7 Functions of Several Variables
Presentation transcript:

Designing Optimal Taxes with a Microeconometric Model of Labour Supply Evidence from Norway Rolf Aaberge, Statistics Norway and CHILD Ugo Colombino, Univ. of Torino, Statistics Norway and CHILD IMA2007, 20-22 August, Vienna This paper is a joint work with Rolf Aaberge.

Purpose Identify optimal (personal income) tax rules in Norway, using a structural microeconometric model The purpose of the exercise consists in using a microeconometric model of household labour supply to identify optimal personal income taxes. The empirical application is to Norway.

Traditional approach to empirical optimal taxation The typical exercise (e.g as surveyed by Tuomala): Take some optimal tax formula derived from theory Calibrate the parameters (preferences, distribution of characteristics, elasticities etc.) using previous empirical results Compute optimal taxes There is a considerable (although not enormous) literature on empirical optimal taxation. Traditionally, the exercise goes as follows. Start with some optimal tax formula (derived from the theoretical literature: Mirlees etc.). The formula typically contains parameters with an empicical counterpart (preference parameters, elasticities, parameters of the distribution of population characteristics etc.). Then choose estimates of the parameters (usually from previous empirical work) and/or calibrate them so that some criterion of fitting is satisfied. Last, substitue the numerical values into the formula and compute optimal taxes.

Traditional approach in empirical optimal taxation Problem with this approach: theoretical results typically rely on some special assumptions; possible inconsistency between the assumptions of the theoretical model and the assumptions of the empirical analysis used to calibrate the parameters; difficult to include household decisions, participation decisions, quantity constraints. Recent contributions (Saez etc.) partially help in overcoming some of the problems mentioned. See an interesting application in this same session (Haan).

A microeconometric - computational approach The approach adopted in this paper is different: we do not start from a priori theoretical results; we directly identify the optimal tax rule by running a microeconometric model of household labour supply that simulates household choices and utility for any tax rule; the simulation searches for the tax rule that maximizes a social welfare function subject to the constraint of a constant total tax revenue. The traditional approach is analytical. A Social Welfare Function is analytically maximized so as to obtain a closed form solution for the optimal tax rule. Afterward, the theoretical formula is fed with numbers. Clearly, in order to obtain a tractable solution, many special and simplifying assumptions have to be made. The approach we follow here is computational, rather than analytical. We start from a complex and flexible microeconometric model of household labour supply. We then numerically maximize the Social Welfare Function by iteratively running the model.

The microeconometric model It is (basically) a MNL model. Each individual (or household) is assumed to choose within an opportunity set containing jobs. Each job is a bundle of hours of work, net income (given a tax rule t) and unobserved characteristics e(j). The tax rule is a function t: Gross  Net. u(j;t) = V(j;t)e(j) = utility attained at job j, given tax rule t The stochastic component e(j) account for the effect of unobserved job’s and household’s characteristics (effect of the job-household match). We use a sample containing both couples and singles. Therefore we apply two different versions of the model.

The microeconometric model Under suitable assumptions upon the distribution (extreme value) of the unbserved characteristics, one gets: Prob(j is chosen) = V(j;t)/∑iBV(i;t) The sum at the denominator goes across the opportunity set B. The opportunity set in general varies across individuals. For each individuals certain jobs are more or less easy to find, for some individual there are no jobs available, and so on and so forth.

The microeconometric model Main distinctive feature of the model with respect to other MNL models used in the labour supply literature: The job opportunity sets are different among individuals (we account for differing opportunities, differing quantity constraints etc.). The opportunity set in this version of the MNL model is not deterministic and fixed for everyone. It is stochastic itself. Each indivisual faces a specific opportunity set generated from a distribution which in general depends on the characteristics of the individual and of her einvironment.

An example of the opportunity set in the (income, hours, e) space Job J Job K In the actual opportunity set there is still a third dimension: the component e(j) = other characteristics. hours

Estimation V(j;t) – function of income, leisure and demographic characteristics - is given a flexible parametric specification The 78 parameters are estimated by ML The dataset is based on the 1995 Norwegian Survey of Level of Living It contains 1842 couples, 309 single females and 312 single males Only individuals with age between 20 and 62 are included V(j;t) is a Box-Cox utility function. Besides being flexible, it still allows for a direct economic interpretation of the parameters. Because of the stochastic nature of the opportunity set, the estimation method is actually a simulated ML.

Labour supply elasticities implied by the model Married couples The elasticities are reported just as an illustration of the behavioural implication of the model. We do not use the elasticities to simulate households’ choices nor to compute optmal taxes: instead we use the full model to simulate choices and to iteratively identify optimal taxes.

Simulating optimal tax rules STEP 1: Given a tax rule f, compute for each individual 1,…,N u = maxj V(j;f)e(j) STEP 2: Compute the Social Welfare Function W(u1,…,uN). The arguments u of the Social Welfare function are made interpersonally comparable by using a common utility function STEP 3: Iterate (on the set of tax rules) STEPS 1-2 so as to maximize W keeping constant the total net tax revenue In principle any common utility function would do. In fact we use an estimated utility function with common parameters and characteristics across the households. The maximization cannot be done with standard (derivative-based) algorithms. Essentially it has to be done with some more or less sophisticated version of a grid search over the tax parameter space.

Social Welfare Function In general we can write the SWF as: W = (∑iui/N)(1-I) = “Efficiency”  “Equality”. ∑iui/N = average utility (efficiency). I = index of inequality of the distribution of utility. In this exercise I is a rank-based index. It depends on the value of an inequality-aversion parameter. For different values of this parameter, one gets different special cases (Utilitarian, Gini, Bonferroni etc.). We also extend the above SWF to include a criterion of Equality of Opportunities (due to J. Roemer). The class of SWF we use is known in the literature as Rank-Dependent SWF. We will not say anymore about the Roemer’s EOp SWF since the simulation results are rather similar those obtained with the more usual approach (called the EO approach in the full paper).

6-parameter piecewise linear tax rules The optimal tax rule is defined by 6 parameters: E = exemption level Z1 = upper limit of first tax bracket Z2 = upper limit of the second tax bracket t1 = marginal rate of the first tax bracket t2 = marginal rate of the second tax bracket t3 = marginal rate of the third tax bracket It replaces the current 1994 rule, which is also piecewise linear, with seven income brackets and a smooth sequence of marginal rates (starting with .25 and ending up with .495) In this exercise, all transfers (social assistance, benefits etc.) are left unchanged. The top marginal tax rate is constrained to be less than or equal to .6 We constrained the top marginal up to 60% because that is approximately the the maximum valued judged as politically sustainable in the public debate in Norway.

Net t3 t2 t1 E Z1 Z2 Gross

Net t3 t2 t1 E Z1 Z2 Gross

Net t2 t1 Z1 Z2 Gross

Actual (1994) vs Optimal tax rules according to alternative social welfare criteria Actual (approx.) Bonferroni Gini Utilitarian E 17 6 8 t1 0.25-0.35 0.17 0.20 0.22 Z1 140 172 211 264 t2 0.35-0.45 0.38 0.37 0.33 Z2 235 700 690 720 t3 0.50 0.60 The values of E and of the Zs are in thousands of 1994 NOK. One Euro is approximately equal to 8 NOK. So, for example 700 means 87500 Euros.

BONFERRONI-optimal rule Average tax rates Gross income (NOK) Actual (1994) rule BONFERRONI-optimal rule 50000 17.5 17.0 100000 23.9 150000 26.3 200000 28.7 19.9 400000 38.5 29.0 700000 43.2 32.8 1000000 45.1 41.0 Overall, the optimal rules imply lower average tax rates. The distance between actual and optimale rates is largest for average income levels.

This is a zoom on the lower part of the income distribution (below 12500 Euros). In the actual system there is a modest non-convexity around 25000 NOK.

Percentage change in labour supply when the BONFERRONI-optimal tax rule is applied Household Income Decile Single male Single female Married male Married female I 89.5 65.9 36.3 47.8 II 17.9 25.2 22.9 13.4 III - VIII 2.8 3.0 4.2 4.6 IX 0.0 1.5 -0.2 X 1.2 -0.7 -1.5 All 7.0 6.1 6.4 7.8 The change in labour supply is total, i.e. it includes both the extensive margin (participation decision) and the intensive margin (hours decision).

Percentage of winners when the BONFERRONI-optimal tax rule is applied Household Income Decile Single male Single female Married male Married female I 74 62 63 II 68 55 70 III - VIII 83 69 79 82 IX 77 42 80 X 39 All 76 78 An individual is defined a winner if her utility increases with the optimal tax rule. Note than an optimal tax rule is Pareto-efficient but in general not Pareto-improving (upon the current system).

Comments Similar to the current rule, optimal tax rules imply a sequence of increasing marginal tax rates However, optimal rules are more progressive on high income levels and less progressive on low and average income levels (somehow consistent with the pattern of labour supply elasticities) Optimal rules imply a higher net income for almost any level of gross income  lower average tax rate: thanks to a sufficiently large labour supply response Other things being equal, a pattern of labour supply elasticities that decrease with income should recommend – according to the optimal taxation literature – higher marginal tax rates on higher income levels.

Comments Our results are partially at odds with the tax reforms that took place in many countries during the last decades. Those reforms, with the aim of improving efficiency and incentives, embodied the idea of lowering average tax rates by lowering the top marginal rates (OECD countries: from 67% to 47% in the period 1980-2000). Our results suggest instead to lower average tax rates by lowering marginal rates on average incomes and increasing marginal rates on very high incomes: this improves both efficiency and equality. Among major OECD countries, in the period 1980 – 2000, the top marginal tax rate on personal income has been lowered – on average – from 67% to 47%.

Work-in-progress Simulating tax rules with more parameters tax reforms implemented in many developed countries during the last decades. In most cases those reforms embodied the idea of improving efficiency and labour supply incentives through a lower average tax rate and lower marginal tax rates on higher incomes.[1] Our optimal tax computations give support to the first part (lowering the average tax rate), much less to the second; on the contrary our results suggest that a lower average tax rate should be obtained by lowering the marginal tax rates particularly on low and average income brackets[2]. The optimal tax rules efficiently exploit the pattern of heterogeneous responses from different households. Work-in-progress Simulating tax rules with more parameters Including transfers (social policies, lump-sum benefits or taxes etc.) – Preliminary results suggest that the current level of transfers in Norway might be close to optimal Of course the structure of trnsfers is a much more complicated matter. Even if the level were optimal, the structure of welfare policy might be suboptimal.

References Aaberge, R.., J.K. Dagsvik and S. Strøm (1995): "Labor Supply Responses and Welfare Effects of Tax Reforms", Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97, 4, 635-659. Aaberge, R., U. Colombino and S. Strøm (1999): “Labor Supply in Italy: An Empirical Analysis of Joint Household Decisions, with Taxes and Quantity Constraints”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14, 403-422. Aaberge, R., U. Colombino and S. Strøm (2000): “Labour supply responses and welfare effects from replacing current tax rules by a flat tax: empirical evidence from Italy, Norway and Sweden”, Journal of Population Economics, 13, 595-621. Aaberge, R., U. Colombino and S. Strøm (2004): "Do More Equal Slices Shrink the Cake? An Empirical Investigation of Tax-Transfer Reform Proposals in Italy“, Journal of Population Economics, 17 Aaberge, R. and U. Colombino (2006): “Designing Optimal Taxes with a Microeconometric Model of Household Labour Supply“, IZA DP 2468.