8 UTILITY AND DEMAND. 8 UTILITY AND DEMAND Notes and teaching tips: 6, 12, 26, 27, 28, 29, 37, and 58. To view a full-screen figure during a class,

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 CHAPTER.
Advertisements

8 CHAPTER Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley CHAPTER 1. © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. You buy your music online and play it on an iPod. As the prices of a music download and an iPod have tumbled, the volume.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Calculate and graph a budget line that shows the.
12 Consumer Choice and Demand
© 2013 Pearson. How much would you pay for a song?
11 PART 4 Consumer Choice and Demand A CLOSER LOOK AT DECISION MAKERS
Chapter 21 - Consumer Choice
UTILITY AND DEMAND 7 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Describe preferences using the concept of utility and distinguish.
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
9 POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES © 2012 Pearson Education.
Utility and Demand CHAPTER 7. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain what limits a household’s consumption choices Describe preferences.
7 UTILITY AND DEMAND CHAPTER.
7 CHAPTER Utility and Demand
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. You want Coldplay’s latest hit album, Viva la Vida, and you want the Justin Timberlake and Madonna single, Four Minutes.
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND. 8 UTILITY AND DEMAND Notes and teaching tips: 6, 12, 26, 27, 28, 29, 37, and 58. To view a full-screen figure during a class,
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
UTILITY AND DEMAND 7 CHAPTER 效用與需求. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Describe preferences using the concept of utility and distinguish.
Chapter 20 – Consumer Choice
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
CHAPTERS 8 Utility and Demand
Utility and Demand Michael Parkin ECONOMICS 5e. TM 8-2 Copyright © 1998 Addison Wesley Longman, Inc. Learning Objectives Explain the household’s budget.
POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES 8 CHAPTER.
Utility and Demand CHAPTER 7. 2 After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain what limits a household’s consumption choices Describe preferences.
McTaggart, Findlay, Parkin: Microeconomics © 2007 Pearson Education Australia Chapter 8: Households’ Choices.
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
© 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints.
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. Preferences A household’s preferences determine the benefits or satisfaction a person receives consuming a good or service.
The Theory of Demand Lecture 7: The Theory of Demand Readings: Chapter 9.
Chapter 8: A Simple Model of Utility and Demand
n Individual’s demand curve: Why does it slopes downward? Why does it slopes downward? n Why do people demand goods and services? Receive satisfaction.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Utility and Demand PART 3Households’ Choices 8 CHAPTER.
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
Lecture by: Jacinto Fabiosa Fall 2005 Consumer Choice.
8 Utility and Demand After studying this chapter you will be able to  Explain the limits to consumption and describe preferences using the concept of.
Chapter 9: Going from Possibilities (Budget Constraint) and Preferences (Preference Function) to understanding Price and Income Effects.
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND. © 2012 Pearson Education © 2010 Pearson Education The choices you make as a buyer of goods and services is influenced by many factors,
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice.
Consumer Behavior: Utility Maximization
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Calculate and graph a budget line that shows.
Consumer Choice: Maximizing Utility and Behavioural Economics
A2 Economics Mr. Durham
Economics September Lecture 5 Chapter 8 Consumer Choice
Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
Principles of Marketing
6 Consumer Choice and Demand SLIDES CREATED BY ERIC CHIANG
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice
THE LOGIC OF INDIVIDUAL CHOICE: THE FOUNDATION OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY
ECONOMICS Twelfth Edition Chapter 8 Utility and Demand.
UTILITY AND DEMAND FACULTY OF ECONOMICS & ADMINISTRATIVE SCIENCES
CH6:Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Asst. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN
Consumer Choice Theory
Consumer Choice Theory
UTILITY AND DEMAND FACULTY OF ECONOMICS & ADMINISTRATIVE SCIENCES
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND.
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Asst. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN
Slides by Alex Stojanovic
Utility Maximization Ch7
Maximizing Utility Preferences
Consumer Behavior Ch. 7.
7 CHAPTER Utility and Demand
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
Twelfth Edition, Global Edition
12 Notes and teaching tips: 4, 6, 15, 23, 26, 40, 41, 45, 48, 57, 67, and 74. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the expand button. To.
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization
Twelfth Edition, Global Edition
DEV 501: THE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE
Presentation transcript:

8 UTILITY AND DEMAND

Notes and teaching tips: 6, 12, 26, 27, 28, 29, 37, and 58. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand” button. To return to the previous slide, click the red “shrink” button. To advance to the next slide, click anywhere on the full screen figure.

You want Ke$ha’s album, Animal. Will you buy the CD album from Amazon for $11.88 or will you download it from the iTunes store for $7.99? What determines our choices as buyers of recorded music? How much better off are we because we can download an album for less than $10 and some songs for less than $1? You know that diamonds are expensive and water is cheap. Doesn’t that seem odd? Why do we place a higher value on useless diamonds than on essential-to-life water?

Consumption Choices The choices you make as a buyer of goods and services is influenced by many factors, which economists summarize as Consumption possibilities Preferences Consumption Possibilities Consumption possibilities are all the things that you can afford to buy.

Consumption Choices We’ll study the consumption possibilities of Lisa, who buys only two goods: movies and soda. A Consumer’s Budget Line Consumption possibilities are limited by income, the price of a movie, and the price of soda. When Lisa spends all of her income, she reaches the limits of her consumption possibilities. Lisa’s budget line shows the limits of her consumption possibilities. The budget line is like a restaurant menu. This example has been well received: Emphasize that the consumer’s budget line is like a menu showing what affordable combinations of food and drink are available to the consumer. Ask them to compare the relative prices between two goods: food and drink and depict the affordable combinations a diner can purchase with a set income.

Consumption Possibilities Lisa has $40 to spend, the price of a movie is $8 and the price of soda is $4 a case.

Consumption Possibilities Lisa can afford any of the combinations at the points A to F. Some goods are indivisible and must be bought in whole units at the points marked. Other goods are divisible goods and can be bought in any quantity. The line through points A to F is Lisa’s budget line.

Consumption Possibilities The budget line is a constraint on Lisa’s consumption choices. Lisa can afford any point on her budget line or inside it. Lisa cannot afford any point outside her budget line.

Consumption Choice Preferences The choice that Lisa makes depends on her preferences—her likes and dislikes. Her benefit or satisfaction from consuming a good or service is called utility. Total Utility Total utility is the total benefit a person gets from the consumption of goods. Generally, more consumption gives more total utility.

Maximizing Utility Table 8.1 shows Lisa’s total utility schedule. Total utility from a good increases as the quantity of the good increases. For example, as Lisa sees more movies in a month, her total utility from movies increases. Where do the utility numbers come from? Year after year, you will get the same question from the curious student: “where do the utility numbers come from?” This edition tries to help with one answer to this question by telling the story of Lisa’s likes for movies and soda. We tell Lisa that we’re going to call the utility she gets from 1 movie a month 50 units of utility. Then we ask her to tell us, using the same scale, how much she would like 2, 3, and so on movies, and 1, 2, 3, and so on cases of soda. A second answer that you can’t give now, but you can promise when you get to the end of the chapter, is that we can infer the MU values from the prices (up to an arbitrary constant of multiplication). Because in consumer equilibrium, MUM/PM = MUS/PS = , we know that MUM = PM and MUS = PS. (Use this second explanation carefully, and don’t use the math as densely as we’re using it here. Spell it out at greater length in words and with intuition.)

Maximizing Utility Marginal Utility Marginal utility from a good is the change in total utility that results from a unit-increase in the quantity of the good consumed. As the quantity consumed of a good increases, the marginal utility from it decreases. We call this decrease in marginal utility as the quantity of the good consumed increases the principle of diminishing marginal utility.

Maximizing Utility Table 8.1 shows Lisa’s marginal utility schedules. Marginal utility from a good decreases as the quantity of the good increases. For example, as the number of movies seen in a month increases, marginal utility from movies decreases.

Maximizing Utility Figure 8.2(a) shows Lisa’s total utility and marginal utility from soda. Total utility from soda increases as more soda is consumed. The bars along the total utility curve show the extra total utility (marginal utility) from each additional case of soda.

Maximizing Utility Figure 8.2(b) illustrates diminishing marginal utility. As Lisa increases the quantity of soda she drinks, her marginal utility from soda diminishes.

Utility-Maximizing Choice The key assumption is that the household chooses the consumption possibility that maximizes total utility. A Spreadsheet Solution The direct way to find the utility-maximizing choice is to make a table in a spreadsheet and do the calculations. Find the just-affordable combinations Find the total utility for each just-affordable combination The utility-maximizing combination is the consumer’s choice

Utility-Maximizing Choice Find Just-Affordable Combinations Lisa has $40 a month to spend on movies and soda. The price of a movie is $8 and the price of soda is $4 a case. Each row of Table 8.2 shows a combination of movies and soda that exhausts Lisa’s $40.

Utility-Maximizing Choice Find the Total Utility for Each Just-Affordable Combination When Lisa sees 1 movie and drinks 8 cases of soda a month, she gets 50 units of utility from the 1 movie and 248 units of utility from the 8 cases of soda. Her total utility is 298 units.

Utility-Maximizing Choice Consumer Equilibrium Lisa chooses the combination that gives her the highest total utility. Lisa maximizes her total utility when she sees 2 movies and drinks 6 cases of soda a month. Lisa gets 90 units of utility from the 2 movies and 225 units of utility from the 6 cases of soda.

Utility-Maximizing Choice Consumer equilibrium is the situation in which Lisa has allocated all of her available income in the way that maximizes her total utility, given the prices of movies and soda. Lisa’s consumer equilibrium is 2 movies and 6 cases of soda a month.

Utility-Maximizing Choice A more natural way of finding the consumer equilibrium is to use the idea of choices made at the margin. Choosing at the Margin Having made a choice, would spending a dollar more or a dollar less on a good bring more total utililty? Marginal utility is the increase in total utility that results from consuming one more unit of the good. The marginal utility per dollar is the marginal utility from a good that results from spending one more dollar on it. Marginal decision making is the core of the economic way of thinking. Get your students to appreciate that, aside from the concept of opportunity cost, marginal reasoning is the most important tool for understanding the economic perspective. Remind them that we have been using marginal reasoning for many chapters now: In Chapter 2 we derived the marginal cost of production from the PPF. In Chapter 5 we discovered that competitive equilibrium is efficient because marginal benefit on the demand curve equals marginal cost on the supply curve. In this chapter, we discover that equalizing the marginal utility per dollar across all goods and services maximizes a consumer’s utility.

Utility-Maximizing Choice The marginal utility per dollar equals the marginal utility from a good divided by its price. Calling the marginal utility from movies MUM and the price of a movie PM, then the marginal utility per dollar from movies is MUM/PM . Calling the marginal utility of soda MUS and the price of soda PS , then the marginal utility per dollar from soda is MUS/PS. By comparing MUM/PM and MUS/PS , we can determine whether Lisa has allocated her budget in the way that maximizes her total utility. People don’t calculate and compare marginal utilities and prices. One of the challenges in teaching the marginal utility theory is getting the students to appreciate the fundamental role of a model of choice. The goal is to predict choices, not to describe the thought processes that make them. The physics model of the pool player’s choices (This Instructor’s Manual, Chapter 1) is relevant here. Gary Becker told the story a bit differently and more pointedly for present purposes. Here’s what he said (Parkin, Economics, first edition, 1990, p. 154): Cliff Lee [or substitute a currently hot pitcher] won the 2008 Cy Young award for the American League. He effectively knows all the laws of motion, of hand-eye coordination, about the speed of the bat and ball, and so on. He’s in fact solving a complicated physics problem when he steps up to pitch, but obviously he doesn’t have to know physics to do that. Likewise, when people solve economic problems rationally they’re really not thinking, “Well, I have this budget and I read this textbook and I look at my marginal utilities and the prices and determine what maximizes my utility.” People don’t do that, but it doesn’t mean they’re not being rational. Just because a Cy Young Award winner isn’t Albert Einstein doesn’t mean he can’t make rational decisions about pitching.

Utility-Maximizing Choice Utility-Maximizing Rule A consumer’s total utility is maximized by following the rule: Spend all available income Equalize the marginal utility per dollar for all goods Marginal decision making is the core of the economic way of thinking. Get your students to appreciate that, aside from the concept of opportunity cost, marginal reasoning is the most important tool for understanding the economic perspective. Remind them that we have been using marginal reasoning for many chapters now: In Chapter 2 we derived the marginal cost of production from the PPF. In Chapter 5 we discovered that competitive equilibrium is efficient because marginal benefit on the demand curve equals marginal cost on the supply curve. In this chapter, we discover that equalizing the marginal utility per dollar across all goods and services maximizes a consumer’s utility.

Utility-Maximizing Choice Lisa’s Marginal Calculation Figure 8.3 shows why the utility-maximizing rule works. Each row of the table (on the next slide) shows a just-affordable combination. Start by choosing a row—a point on the budget line. Why don’t consumers simply choose the goods with the highest marginal utility? Students will find it relatively easy to simply memorize the rule that maximizing utility requires that the marginal utility per dollar is equal across all goods, but, intuitively, students still often expect marginal utility to be the only determinant of utility maximization. To provide some additional intuition, ask them to think about two goods they’re trying to choose between, like a new shirt and a new CD. Say a new shirt would have a marginal utility of 20, while a new CD would have a marginal utility of 15. The price of a new shirt is $30, while the price of a new CD is $15. Should you purchase the new shirt because it has a higher marginal utility? Not necessarily. You might prefer the shirt, but it costs twice as much as the new CD. Only if you like the shirt at least twice as much as the new CD would you be willing to pay twice as much for the shirt. Even though the CD has the lower marginal utility, it has a higher marginal utility per dollar (1 as opposed to 2/3).

Utility-Maximizing Choice In row B, MUS/PS < MUM/PM. Lisa spends too much on soda and too little on movies.

Utility-Maximizing Choice If Lisa spends less on soda and more on movies, … MUS increases and MUM decreases.

Utility-Maximizing Choice In row D, MUS/PS > MUM/PM. Lisa spends too little on soda and too much on movies.

Utility-Maximizing Choice If Lisa spends more on soda and less on movies. MUS decreases and MUM increases.

Utility-Maximizing Choice In row C, MUS/PS = MUM/PM. Lisa is maximizing utility.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory A Fall in the Price of a Movie When the price of a good falls the quantity demanded of that good increases—the demand curve slopes downward. For example, if the price of a movie falls, we know that MUM/PM rises, so before the consumer changes the quantities bought, MUM/PM > MUS/PS. To restore consumer equilibrium (maximum total utility), the consumer increases the movies seen to drive down the MUM and restore MUM/PM = MUS/PS. The concept of utility is abstract and not comparable across people—and that can be a difficult idea to grasp. Students will initially be skeptical of measuring satisfaction with the concept of utility—not because the idea that consumer satisfaction increases with consumption is difficult to comprehend, but because there is no absolute standard by which different people’s satisfaction can be compared. Many students think that if one person’s utility can’t be converted into standardized units that are comparable across people, like converting spatial distance into miles or kilometers, then the concept simply isn’t worth understanding. (In mathematical terms, utility ordering is ordinal, not cardinal, making it impossible to directly compare separate utility functions.)

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory A change in the price of one good changes the demand for another good. You’ve seen that if the price of a movie falls, MUM/PM rises, so before the consumer changes the quantities consumed, MUM/PM > MUS/PS. To restore consumer equilibrium (maximum total utility), the consumer decreases the quantity of soda consumed to drive up the MUS and restore MUM/PM = MUS/PS.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Table 8.3 shows Lisa’s just-affordable combinations when the price of a movie is $4. Before Lisa changes what she buys MUM/PM > MUS/PS. To maximize total utility, Lisa sees more movies and drinks less soda.

Predictions Figure 8.4 illustrates these predictions. A fall in the price of a movie increases the quantity of movies demanded—a movement along the demand curve for movies, and decreases the demand for soda—a shift of the demand curve for soda.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory A Rise in the Price of Soda Now suppose the price of soda rises. We know that MUS/PS falls, so before the consumer changes the quantities bought, MUS/PS < MUM/PM. To restore consumer equilibrium (maximum total utility), the consumer decreases the quantity of soda consumed to drive up the MUS and increases the quantity of movies seen to drive down MUM. These changes restore MUM/PM = MUS/PS.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Table 8.4 shows Lisa’s just-affordable combinations when the price of soda is $8 and the price of a movie is $4. Before Lisa changes what she buys MUM/PM < MUS/PS. To maximize her total utility, Lisa drinks less soda.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Figure 8.5 illustrates these predictions. A rise in the price of soda decreases the quantity of soda demanded—a movement along the demand curve for soda.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory A Rise in Income When income increases, the demand for a normal good increases. Given the prices of movies and soda, when Lisa’s income increases from $40 to $56 a month, she buys more movies and more soda. Movies and soda are normal goods. Table 8.5 shows these predictions.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Table 8.5 shows Lisa’s just-affordable combinations when she has $56 to spend. With $40 to spend, Lisa sees 6 movies and drinks 4 cases of soda a month. With $56 to spend, Lisa spends the extra $16, so she buys more of both goods. She sees 8 movies and drinks 6 cases of soda a month.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Figure 8.6 illustrates these predictions.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory The Paradox of Value The paradox of value “Why is water, which is essential to life, far cheaper than diamonds, which are not essential?” is resolved by distinguishing between total utility and marginal utility. We use so much water that the marginal utility from water consumed is small, but the total utility is large. We buy few diamonds, so the marginal utility from diamonds is large, but the total utility is small.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Paradox Resolved The paradox is resolved by distinguishing between total utility and marginal utility. For water, the price is low, total utility is large, and marginal utility is small. For diamonds, the price is high, total utility is small, and marginal utility is high. But marginal utility per dollar is the same for water and diamonds.

Predictions … Value and Consumer Surplus The supply of water is perfectly elastic, so the quantity of water consumed is large and the consumer surplus from water is large. In contrast, the supply of diamonds in perfectly inelastic, so the price is high and the consumer surplus from diamonds is small.

Predictions of Marginal Utility Theory Temperature: An Analogy Utility is similar to temperature. Both are abstract concepts, and both have units of measurement that are arbitrary. The concept of utility helps us make predictions about consumption choices in much the same way that the concept of temperature enables us to predict when water will turn to ice or steam. The concept of utility helps us understand why people buy more of a good when its price falls and why people buy more of most goods when their incomes increases. If utility is arbitrary, what use is it? The concept of utility is abstract, but the implications of utility analysis are concrete. Help the students be less concerned about the abstract nature of measuring utility by emphasizing that it is enough to be able to carefully analyze one consumer’s consumption decisions and extrapolate what this behavior could imply for market behavior in general. Appeal to those concepts that students already understand from earlier chapters by linking the abstract concept of utility with concrete implications of consumer behavior. For example, utility-maximization rules explain the law of demand and shifts in demand, as seen in chapter 3.

New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices Behavioral Economics Behavioral economics studies the ways in which limits on the human brain’s ability to compute and implement rational decisions influences economic behavior—both the decisions that people make and the consequences of those decisions for the way markets work. There are three impediments to rational choice: Bounded rationality Bounded willpower Bounded self-interest

New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices Bounded Rationality Bounded rationality is rationality that is bounded by the computing power of the human brain. Faced with uncertainty, consumers cannot rationally make choices and instead rely on other decision-making methods such as rules of thumb, listening to the views of others, or gut instinct.

New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices Bounded Willpower Bounded will-power is the less-than-perfect willpower that prevents us from making a decision that we know, at the time of implementing the decision, we will later regret. Bounded Self-Interest Bounded self-interest is the limited self-interest that sometimes results in suppressing our own interests to help others. Main applications are in finance where uncertainty is the key factor and savings where future is the key factor.

New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices One behavior observed by behavioral economists is more general and might affect your choices. The Endowment Effect The endowment effect is the tendency for people to value something more highly simply because they own it.

New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices Neuroeconomics Neuroeconomics is the study of the activity of the human brain when a person makes an economic decision. Different decisions appear to activate different areas of the brain. Some decisions are made In the pre-frontal cortex where memories are stored and data analyzed and might be deemed rational. In the hippocampus where memories of anxiety and fear are stored and might be deemed irrational.

New Ways of Explaining Consumer Choices Controversy Should economics focus on explaining the decisions we observe or should it focus on what goes on inside people’s heads? This is the controversy. For most economists, the goal of economics is to explain the decisions that we observe people make, and not to explain what goes on inside people’s heads.