Defining Profit Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* Micro:

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Unit V Costs and Marginal Analysis (Chapter 9). In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:  Why are implicit as well as explicit costs.
Advertisements

Production, Cost and Profit
8/14/ Opportunity Costs Ch. 12 Claudia Garcia-Szekely.
Chapter 6 Cost of Production.
The Costs of Production 1 22 C H A P T E R Costs exist because resources Are scarce Productive Have alternative uses Use of a resource in a specific.
Business Costs and Revenues Reference 6.1 and 6.2.
By: Christopher Mazzei. Viewpoints The owner of a company wants to keep costs down. An employee of the company wants a high wage or salary. There is always.
Defining Profit Lesson 4.52, Understanding Profit (52) Profit = Total Revenue – Total Costs Explicit vs Implicit Costs – Explicit costs require.
March 7th, 2014 Lecture 20 Ch. 10 (up to p. 231) and Ch. 11
PRODUCTION AND COSTS: PROFIT AP Economics Mr. Bordelon.
ORGANIZING PRODUCTION 9 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain what a firm is and describe the economic problems.
Defining Profit Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* Micro:
The Cost Function Chapter 13.
AP Microeconomics Block 2B – Ryan Higgins. Implicit and Explicit Costs Implicit Costs are not involved in an outlay of money, they are measured by the.
Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition
Copyright©2004 South-Western Mods The Costs of Production.
Cost of Production. The Production Function A relationship between the number of units of inputs that a firm employs and the corresponding units of output.
AP Economics Mr. Bernstein Module 52: Defining Profit November 2015.
Forms of Business Organization Economics Breedlove.
KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* Defining Profit Margaret Ray and David Anderson Micro: Econ: Module.
Profits and costs. TR=P x Q Total revenue= price x quantity sold Profit= TR-cost Two types of costs: explicit costs-cost that requires an outlay of money.
LECTURE 4 types of costs.
Profit Maximization Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* 17 53
Chapter 20 The Costs of Production
Module 18 Making Decisions
Here’s a Gosh Dern PPT.
Mr. Bernstein Module 52: Defining Profit November 2016
CHAPTER 7 Making Decisions.
Ch. 19, R.A. Arnold, Economics 9th Ed
UNIT 6 COSTS AND PRODUCTION: LONG AND SHORT-RUN, TOTAL, FIXED AND VARIABLE COSTS, LAW OF DIMINISHING RETURNS, INCREASING, CONSTANT AND DIMINISHING RETURNS.
Production and Costs (Part 1)
Profit Maximization Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* 17 53
Profit Maximization Day 2
Production, Costs & Profits
Total Revenue, Total Cost, and Profit
Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition
Unit #3: Theory of the Firm
The Costs of Production
Costs of Production Microeconomics.
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 13
Business organization and behavior
Defining Profit.
Total Costs Chapter 13.
Section 10: BEHIND THE SUPPLY CURVE: PROFIT, PRODUCTION, AND COSTS
MODULE 53: PROFIT MAXIMIZATION
Please read the following License Agreement before proceeding.
Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition
AP Microeconomics Unit 3, Days 1 & 2 Rixie
Module 1: First Principles
Chapter 4 – Costs of Production
Introduction to Perfect Competition
24 Module The Time Value of Money KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP*
Profit Maximization Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* 17 53
AP Microeconomics Unit 3, Days 1 & 2 Rixie
Section 10: BEHIND THE SUPPLY CURVE: PROFIT, PRODUCTION, AND COSTS
The Cost Curve Model Chapter 13 Cost Curves.
Economics Chapter 5: Supply.
Graphing Perfect Competition
Graphing Perfect Competition
Module 29 The Market for Loanable Funds KRUGMAN'S
The Markets for Land and Capital
What are the advantages and disadvantages of a bank loan?
Costs: Economics and Accounting
Defining Profit Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* Micro:
Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition
Accountants vs. Economists
The Markets for Land and Capital
AP Microeconomics Unit 3, Days 1 & 2 Stater
Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition
FINA251 Fundamentals of Microeconomics Week
Presentation transcript:

Defining Profit Module KRUGMAN'S MICROECONOMICS for AP* 16 52 Micro: Margaret Ray and David Anderson

What you will learn in this Module: The difference between explicit and implicit costs and their importance in decision making. The different types of profit, including economic profit, accounting profit, and normal profit. How to calculate profit. The purpose of this module is to introduce and define profit. Firms are assumed to maximize profit, but economists and accountants differ in how they define profit.

Understanding Profit Implicit versus explicit costs Accounting profit versus economic profit Normal profit All costs are opportunity costs. They can be divided into explicit costs and implicit costs.   An explicit cost is a cost that involves actually laying out money. Examples include: Rent for office space, wages to employees, interest on debt, raw materials, depreciation on equipment, and utility bills. These are referred to as “accounting costs.” An implicit cost does not require an outlay of money; it is measured by the value, in dollar terms, of the benefits that are forgone. Examples include: forgone salary, interest income given up when savings were liquidated, a building or other capital that could be rented but is self-employed. These are referred to as “economic costs.”

π = total revenue – total cost Defining Profit Profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost Economists use the symbol π to represent profit π = total revenue – total cost π = TR – TC Total revenue equals the price paid times the number sold. TR = P x Q Firms are assumed to produce the level of output that maximizes profit. Profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost.   π  = Total Revenue – Total Cost Accountants and economists both define total revenue as equal to the quantity of units sold multiplied by the price at which they were told. In other words: TR = P*Q The more difficult component of profit is the precise definition of total cost (which comes up in module 55).

Implicit versus Explicit Costs An explicit cost is a cost that involves actually laying out money. Implicit versus Explicit Costs An explicit cost is a cost that involves actually laying out money. An implicit cost does not require an outlay of money; it is measured by the value, in dollar terms, of the benefits that are forgone. Businesses can face implicit costs for two reasons. A business’s capital could have been put to use in some other way. The owner devotes time and energy to the business that could have been used elsewhere. All costs are opportunity costs. They can be divided into explicit costs and implicit costs.   An explicit cost is a cost that involves actually laying out money. Examples include: Rent for office space, wages to employees, interest on debt, raw materials, depreciation on equipment, and utility bills. These are referred to as “accounting costs.” An implicit cost does not require an outlay of money; it is measured by the value, in dollar terms, of the benefits that are forgone. Examples include: forgone salary, interest income given up when savings were liquidated, a building or other capital that could be rented but is self-employed. These are referred to as “economic costs.”

Accounting versus Economic Profit Accounting costs include only EXPLICIT costs Accounting profit equals total revenue minus total EXPLICIT costs Accounting π = TR – TC (explicit) Economic costs include BOTH explicit and implicit costs Economic profit is total revenue minus total costs (including both explicit and implicit costs) π = TR – TC (explicit + implicit) Companies report their accounting profit, which is not necessarily equal to their economic profit.   Accounting profit of a business is the business’s revenue minus the explicit costs and depreciation. π = Total Revenue – Total Explicit Costs Economic profit of a business is its revenue minus the opportunity costs of its resources; both explicit and implicit. It is usually less than the accounting profit. π = Total Revenue – Total Explicit Costs – Total Implicit Costs

Normal Profit An economic profit equal to zero is known as a “Normal profit” A normal profit means that all costs (explicit and implicit) are covered by revenues. When a firm is earning a normal profit, it can do no better using resources in the next best alternative use. When economic profit is equal to zero, or break-even, the firm is said to be earning a “normal profit”.   What’s so great about breaking even? Of course Betsy would love to have a positive economic profit, but let’s see what a normal profit means. If Betsy has zero economic profit, Betsy has sold enough clothing to: 1. Pay all of her employees, insurance company, utilities, the bank, and her clothing suppliers. And! 2. Compensate her for all of the rental income she gave up and the Macy’s salary that she gave up. If you can earn enough total revenue to cover every cost, both out of pocket and the things you gave up, a normal profit is not such a bad thing.