Warrant exercise and bond conversion in competitive market

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
Advertisements

The Value of Common Stocks. Topics Covered  How Common Stocks are Traded  How To Value Common Stock  Capitalization Rates  Stock Prices and EPS 
7-1 CHAPTER 7 Bonds and Their Valuation Key features of bonds Bond valuation Measuring yield Assessing risk.
Dividend Policy 05/30/07 Ch. 21. Dividend Process Declaration Date – Board declares the dividend and it becomes a liability of the firm Ex-dividend Date.
1 Chapter 8 Stocks, Stock Valuation, and Stock Market Equilibrium Stocks, Stock Valuation, and Stock Market Equilibrium.
 3M is expected to pay paid dividends of $1.92 per share in the coming year.  You expect the stock price to be $85 per share at the end of the year.
Three Approaches to Value There are three general approaches that we use to value any asset. –Discounted Cash Flow Valuation –Relative Valuation –Contingent.
Stock and Its Valuation
Stocks & Stock Market Primary Market - Place where the sale of new stock first occurs. Initial Public Offering (IPO) - First offering of stock to the general.
The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 2000
Value of Bonds and Common Stocks
Lecture 7 The Value of Common Stocks Managerial Finance FINA 6335 Ronald F. Singer.
The Value of Common Stocks Chapter 4. Topics Covered  How Common Stocks are Traded  How To Value Common Stock  Capitalization Rates  Stock Prices.
Drake DRAKE UNIVERSITY MBA Stock Valuation A Discounted Cash Flow Approach.
The Value of Common Stocks
Warrants and Convertibles
FIN 819: lecture 2'1 Review of the Valuation of Common Stocks How to apply the PV concept.
Capital Structure.
Cost of Capital MF 807 Corporate Finance Professor Thomas Chemmanur.
Chapter 17 Payout Policy.
Right, Warrant and Option
“The Effects of a Firm’s Investment and Financing Decisions on the welfare of Its Security Holders” Eugene F. Fama, 1978 American Economic Review Hui-Ru.
Chapter 2- Capital Structure Determination. After studying this chapter, you should be able to: Define “capital structure.” Explain the net operating.
FIN 351: lecture 4 Stock and Its Valuation The application of the present value concept.
CORPORATE FINANCE Week 4 – 17&19 Oct Stock and Company Valuation – Dividend Growth Model, Free Cash Flow Model I. Ertürk Senior Fellow in Banking.
Ch 9. The Cost of Capital. Goals: To understand cost of capitals or hurdle rate To understand how to estimate cost components To understand how to estimate.
7-1 CHAPTER 7 Bonds and Their Valuation Key features of bonds Bond valuation Measuring yield Assessing risk.
1 Lecture 5: Levered Firms Discounted Cash Flow, Section 2.2 © 2004, Lutz Kruschwitz and Andreas Löffler.
When is The Financing Decision Irrelevant? MF 807: Corporate Finance Professor Thomas Chemmanur.
101 EXAMPLE, Historical Weights, using Market Value Weights In addition to the data from Ex. 10.7, assume that the security market prices are as follows:
Chapter 4 Principles of Corporate Finance Eighth Edition Value of Bond and Common Stocks Slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
Business Finance (MGT 232)
Bonds and Their Valuation Chapter 7  Key Features of Bonds  Bond Valuation  Measuring Yield  Assessing Risk 7-1.
MODIGLIANI – MILLER THEOREM ANASTASIIA TISETSKA. AGENDA:  MODIGLIANI–MILLER I – LEVERAGE, ARBITRAGE AND FIRM VALUE  MODIGLIANI–MILLER II – LEVERAGE,
Security Markets V Miloslav S Vošvrda Theory of Capital Markets.
Chapter 5 Principles PrinciplesofCorporateFinance Concise Edition The Value of Common Stocks Slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill.
Distributions to Shareholders: Dividends and Repurchases
BASIC MATHS FOR FINANCE
The Value of Common Stocks
DIVIDENDS AND EARNINGS
Chapter 14 Capital Structure in a Perfect Market
Intercorporate Investments and Consolidations
Corporate bonds 1.
Net Operating Income Approach MM Proposition I &II
Outline 7: Dividend Policy
Chapter 10. Basic Properties of Options
Chapter 4 The Value of Common Stocks Principles of Corporate Finance
CHAPTER 18 Derivatives and Risk Management
Topic 9 Reporting financial performance
Warrants and Convertibles
Dividends Chapter 14 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Cost of capital (Chapter 9)
Review for Midterm Dr.Sarina.
Fin 301-Stocks Valuation | Dr. Menahem Rosenberg
Stocks and Their Valuation
Capital Structure Determination
Chapter 10 Stock Valuation
Dividends and Dividend Policy
Chapter 16 Distribution Policy
Valuation: The value of control
MFRS 133 EARNINGS PER SHARE (EPS)
Lecture 4 The Value of Common Stocks
Convertibles, Exchangeables, and Warrants
© 2015 Pearson Education, Limited.
Security Analysis Aston Business School November, 15th, 2011 Session 4
Valuing Stocks -- Summary of Formula
Advanced Finance Warrants-Convertible bonds
Share dividends Mr. Singh BAT4M.
Financial Markets I Chapter 4.
Capital Structure Decisions: Modigliani and Miller 1958 JF
Presentation transcript:

Warrant exercise and bond conversion in competitive market 資管所 黃立文

Properties of all competitive equilibria An example

The definition of the firm’s value is 𝑥 𝑖 = 𝑁 𝑡 − 𝑛 𝑡 𝑆 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 + 𝑛 𝑡 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 (1) This implies the following useful lemma: 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 ≤𝑜𝑟≥ 𝑆 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 − 𝛽 𝑡 (2) 𝑆 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 ≥𝑜𝑟≤( 𝑥 𝑡 + 𝑛 𝑡 𝛽 𝑡 )/ 𝑁 𝑡 (3) 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 ≤𝑜𝑟≥ 𝑥 𝑡 + 𝑛 𝑡 𝛽 𝑡 𝑁 𝑡 − 𝛽 𝑡 =( 𝑥 𝑡 −( 𝑁 𝑡 − 𝑛 𝑡 ) 𝛽 𝑡 )/ 𝑁 𝑡 (4) Eq.(1) together with any one of inequalities (2),(3),and(4) implies the other two inequalities, and this completes the proof of the lemma.

By (1) W t = X t −( N t − n t ) S t n t If (2) W t > S t − β t X t −( N t − n t ) S t n t > S t − β t X t − N t − n t S t > n t S t − n t β t X t + n t β t > n t S t +( N t − n t ) S t X t + n t β t > N t S t X t + n t β t N t > S t (3)

Proposition 1. If assumptions 1 and 2 hold, and if the competitive warrant holders are indifferent between exercising their warrants or not at time t, then the stock and warrants are priced at time t as if all warrants are exercised immediately. Since warrant holders are indifferent between exercising their warrants or not, inequality (2) holds as an equality and therefore (3), and (4) are also equality. 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 = 𝑆 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 − 𝛽 𝑡 (2) 𝑆 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 =( 𝑥 𝑡 + 𝑛 𝑡 𝛽 𝑡 )/ 𝑁 𝑡 (3) 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 = 𝑥 𝑡 + 𝑛 𝑡 𝛽 𝑡 𝑁 𝑡 − 𝛽 𝑡 =( 𝑥 𝑡 −( 𝑁 𝑡 − 𝑛 𝑡 ) 𝛽 𝑡 )/ 𝑁 𝑡 (4)

Proposition 1 is also holds if the firm has senior debt, provided that the value of the senior debt is independent of the warrant exercise. Proposition 1 motivates the definition of a useful theoretical construct, the block warrant. Definition: A block warrant is an indivisible warrant issue which may be traded and exercised only as one block. We consider a firm identical to the one with competitive warrant holders, except that the warrant is a block. 𝑊 𝑡 :𝐸𝑥−𝑐𝑜𝑢𝑝𝑜𝑛 𝑤𝑎𝑟𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑡 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒, 𝑖𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑤𝑎𝑟𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑡 𝑖𝑠 𝑎 𝑏𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑘 𝑆 𝑡 :𝐶𝑢𝑚−𝑑𝑖𝑣𝑖𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑑 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒, 𝑖𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑤𝑎𝑟𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑡 𝑖𝑠 𝑎 𝑏𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑘

Proposition 2. If assumption 1 and 2 hold, then 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 ≤ 𝑊 𝑡 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 Proof. Given 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 in period t ,let 𝜏,𝜏≥𝑡 , be the first time at which the competitive warrant holders exercise some of their warrants. Then 𝑊 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 = 𝑆 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 − 𝛽 𝜏 By lemma1, 𝑊 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 = 𝑥 𝜏 + 𝑛 𝜏 𝛽 𝜏 𝑁 𝜏 − 𝛽 𝜏 In the holders of block warrant follow the generally suboptimal policy of doing nothing over [𝑡,𝜏) and exercising his warrant at time 𝜏 , then 𝑊 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 = 𝑥 𝜏 + 𝑛 𝜏 𝛽 𝜏 𝑁 𝜏 − 𝛽 𝜏 = 𝑊 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 And therefore 𝑊 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 = 𝑊 𝜏 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 , 𝑁 𝜏 , 𝑠 𝜏 If the holder follow its optimal policy instead, his warrant is at least as valuable as when he follow the suboptimal policy.

> 𝑥 𝜏 ̂ + 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ − 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ Proposition3. Given 𝑥 𝑡 , 𝑛 𝑡 , 𝑁 𝑡 , 𝑠 𝑡 ,let 𝜏,𝜏≥𝑡 ,be the first time after t at which the competitive warrant holders are indifferent between exercising or not some warrants; and let 𝜏 , 𝜏 ≥𝑡 ,be the first time after t at which the block warrant holders are indifferent between exercising or not his warrant block if assumption1,2 hold, then 𝜏 ≥𝜏 Proof. By the definition of the stopping time 𝜏 𝑊 𝜏 ̂ 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑠 𝜏 ̂ = 𝑥 𝜏 ̂ + 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ − 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ If 𝜏 <𝜏 then in the competitive equilibrium 𝑊 𝜏 ̂ 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑠 𝜏 ̂ > 𝑆 𝜏 ̂ 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑠 𝜏 ̂ − 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ > 𝑥 𝜏 ̂ + 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ − 𝛽 𝜏 ̂ > 𝑊 𝜏 ̂ 𝑥 𝜏 , 𝑛 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑁 𝜏 ̂ , 𝑠 𝜏 ̂ Contradicts proposition2, therefore 𝜏 ≥𝜏

An example-introduction A firm has 500 shares of stock with cum dividend price S per share, and 500 warrants with price W per warrant. Warrant can be exercised only at one of two time, now and maturity, which is one year from now. -Warrant exercise price 𝛽=9 -Conversion ratio : unity -Dividend : 5% of its assets , declared and paid one day from now and one day after maturity. Firm value before any warrants are exercised and any dividends are paid: 500𝑆+500𝑊=10000 If y warrant are exercised now , then the firm value will be 10000+9𝑦 One day from now, the firm declares and pays out 5% of assets as dividends. 𝐷𝑃𝑆= 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.05 500+𝑦 𝑟𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑖𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑐𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙= 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.95

And the remaining capital will be invested in a riskless production process over the next year, and earns the riskless rate of interest, taken to be 10%. So, the firm value after one year becomes 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.95∗1.10 If 𝑦 ′ warrant are exercised at maturity 𝑓𝑖𝑟𝑚 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒= 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.05∗1.10+9 𝑦 ′ 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 𝑝𝑒𝑟 𝑠ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑒= 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.05∗1.10+9 𝑦 ′ /(500+𝑦+ 𝑦 ′ )

An example – The block warrant holder’s problem One block warrant holder, holds the entire issue of 500 warrants and is constrained to exercise them as one block, whenever he decides to exercise them. He chooses 𝑦= 𝑦 ′ =0 𝑦= 𝑦 ′ =0 , 𝑦=0, 𝑦 ′ =500 ,(𝑦=500, 𝑦 ′ =0) to maximize the present value of cash flows. −9𝑦+ 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.05∗ 𝑦 500+𝑦 − 9 𝑦 ′ 1.1 + 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.95∗1.10+9 𝑦 ′ 1.1 ∗ 𝑦+ 𝑦 ′ 500+𝑦+ 𝑦 ′ The optimal decision is (𝑦=500, 𝑦 ′ =0) , exercise all warrant now , and present value of cash flow is $2750, and the warrant price is 𝑊 =2750/500 = 5.50. This price is compare to the warrant price in the competitive warrant holders’ equilibrium.

An example – The competitive warrant holder’s problem Assume that the warrants are infinitely divisible and are held by a large number of Non-colluding, rational investors, none of which holds sufficiently large fraction of the warrant to be able to affect prices through warrant exercise. Each holder makes following calculation : taking as given the aggregate number, y, of exercised warrants, the present value of the proceeds of a live warrant exercised one year from now, is 𝑊= 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.95∗1.10+ 500−𝑦 ∗9 1000∗1.1 − 9 1.1 But it can’t sustained in a competitive equilibrium at y =500. Because the 𝑊 =2750/500 = 5.50 but the 𝑊 = 5.59 , so each holder has incentive of $0.09 per warrant. (see next page.)

𝑆−9=−9+ 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.05 500+𝑦 + 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.95∗1.10+ 500−𝑦 ∗9 1.1∗1000 Now, taking as the given aggregate number, y, of exercised warrants, the present value of proceeds of exercising one warrant now is : 𝑆−9=−9+ 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.05 500+𝑦 + 10000+9𝑦 ∗0.95∗1.10+ 500−𝑦 ∗9 1.1∗1000 So the competitive equilibrium occurs at W=𝑆−9=5.50 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑦=247.

𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑑𝑖𝑣𝑖𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑑 𝑛𝑜𝑤 =10000∗0.05 ;𝑖𝑓 0 ≤𝑦 ≤1 Next, we try to illustrate Propositions 2 and 3 by a two competitive equilibrium example. In the first, the competitive warrant holders exercise his warrant at the same time that the block warrant holder exercises his warrant, that is , 𝜏 =𝜏. The price of divisible warrant is equal to block warrant. ( 𝑊 𝜏 = 𝑊 𝜏 ) In the second, the competitive warrant holders exercise his warrant before the block warrant holder exercises his warrant, that is , 𝜏 >𝜏. The price of divisible warrant is less than block warrant. ( 𝑊 𝜏 > 𝑊 𝜏 ) We modify the previous example in two respects: Exercise price is 12 now. Dividend policy is modified as following: 𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑑𝑖𝑣𝑖𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑑 𝑛𝑜𝑤 =10000∗0.05 ;𝑖𝑓 0 ≤𝑦 ≤1 =10000+12𝑦 ;𝑖𝑓 1 <𝑦 ≤500

For the holders of block warrant, Exercise now : 𝑊 =−12+ 10000+12∗500 1000 =4 Exercise at maturity: 𝑊 = 10000∗0.95∗1.1+500∗12 1000∗1.1 − 12 1.1 =4.045 So, the holders tend to exercise at maturity. And the ex-dividend stock price should be: 𝑆 𝑒𝑥 = 10000∗0.95∗1.1+500∗12 10000∗1.1 =14.954 𝑆 𝑐𝑢𝑚 = 𝑆 𝑒𝑥 + 10000∗0.05 500 =15.954

For the competitive warrant holders: In the first competitive equilibrium, none of warrants are exercised now, and all warrants are exercised at maturity. So the 𝑊=4.045,𝑆 𝑒𝑥 =14.95, 𝑆 𝑐𝑢𝑚 =15.95 In this equilibrium, 𝝉 =𝝉 and 𝑾 𝒕 = 𝑾 𝒕 In the second competitive equilibrium, all the warrants are exercise now. This also is a rational expectations equilibrium. The warrant price 𝑊=−12+ 10000+12∗500 1000 =4 And cum-dividend price 𝑆 𝑐𝑢𝑚 = 10000+12∗500 500+500 =16.00 Ex-dividend price 𝑆 𝑒𝑥 =0 (no assets remaining.) In this equilibrium, 𝝉 >𝝉 and 𝑾 𝒕 < 𝑾 𝒕 ,whereas the holders are better off if they all wait until maturity to exercise, the fear that some holders will exercise warrant now leads all the other holders to follow suit and the expectation is fulfilled.