Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 5 Some Applications of Consumer Demand, and Welfare Analysis.
Advertisements

Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by sellers.  An equilibrium.
Demand, elasticities, market equilibrium, revenue, deadweight loss (Course Micro-economics) Ch Varian Teachers: Jongeneel/Van Mouche.
CHAPTER 16 EQUILIBRIUM.
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market clears or is in equilibrium when the total quantity demanded by buyers exactly equals the total.
Taxation, income distribution, and efficiency
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Equilibrium Introduce supply Equilibrium The effect of taxes Who really “pays” a tax? The deadweight loss of a tax Pareto efficiency.
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by.
Consumption, Production, Welfare B: Competitive markets (partial eq) Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester 2013.
The Incidence of Taxation. The incidence of taxation Indirect taxes.
Chapter 15 Market Demand One can think of the market demand as the demand of some “ representative consumer ”.
Chapter 16 Equilibrium Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p): at any given price p, how many units.
Effect of a tax on price and quantity S + tax S O P1P1 Q1Q1 D P Q.
CHAPTER 16 EQUILIBRIUM Supply Supply curve  It measures how much the firm is willing to supply of a good at each possible market price.  The supply.
Chapter 4: Demand and Supply
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Equilibrium.
Application: The Costs of Taxation
PRICE AND QUANTITY DETERMINATION
Chapter 1 The Market Key Concept: Pareto Efficiency (如果能皆大歡喜那為什麼不做呢?)
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of markets
Chapter 15 Market Interventions McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Producer Surplus Ap Micro 9/6/17.
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 15
Taxation and Market Efficiency
Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes
SUPPLY & DEMAND Law of Demand Law of Supply Market Price – Equilibrium
Mr. Bernstein Module 50: Efficiency and Deadweight Loss October 2017
Chapter 32 Exchange Key Concept: Pareto optimum and Market Equilibrium
Application: The Costs of Taxation
Economics, Markets and Organizations
Taxes & Subsidies Economic Welfare Supplement
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumer Choice.
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 15
16 Equilibrium.
Microeconomics Graphs
Theoretical Tools of Public Finance
Econ Unit One Day 8.
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Tax Incidence.
Industrial Organization
Chapter 16 Equilibrium.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Chapter Sixteen Equilibrium.
Government Regulation
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
THE ECONOMY: THE CORE PROJECT
Chapter Six: Welfare Analysis.
Efficiency and Deadweight Loss
Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus is the value the consumer gets from buying a product, less its price (paying less than you are willing to pay) It is.
Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
Government Policy & Economic Welfare
Content from chapters 5-9
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
3.3 Excise Taxes Impact of an Excise Tax
Government Policy & Economic Welfare Week 4
CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus
Market Equilibrium – Consumer and Producer Surplus Graphically, we can identify the areas representing consumer and producer surplus, which.
Taxes & Subsidies Economic Welfare Supplement
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS
Chapter 25 Monopoly Key Concept: Monopolist chooses y so that p(y)+p’(y)y=MC(y). This is inefficient because for efficiency, the comparison should be p(y)=MC(y).
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be efficient.

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p): at any given price p, how many units the suppliers are willing to supply. We have the market demand D(p) and the market supply S(p). Basically the market curve is the horizontal sum of the individual curves. Now we can determine the market equilibrium.

Solve D(p*)=S(p*). Then at p* (taking price as given), consumers choose the best they can afford (utility maximization) and this results the quantity demanded by all consumers D(p*). Similarly, at p* (taking price as given), producers choose the best they can produce (profit maximization) and this results the quantity supplied by all suppliers S(p*).

Furthermore, D(p. )=S(p. ) implies that market clears Furthermore, D(p*)=S(p*) implies that market clears. So we have an equilibrium.

The idea is, at the equilibrium price, consumers max utilities, producers max profits, and the market clears. The equilibrium price is determined by all, yet any individual is small so that when making a choice, he takes the price as given.

When p< p*, typically D(p)>S(p), some suppliers realize that they can sell at a higher price to satisfy disappointed consumers. This results a price increase pressure. When p> p*, typically D(p)<S(p), some suppliers are unable to sell and they try to undercut the current price. This results a price decrease pressure.

The comparative statics is to see how the equilibrium changes when the demand or the supply changes. Look at an example: a quantity tax on a good. A quantity tax is a tax levied per unit of quantity bought or sold.

As it suggests, either suppliers or consumers are supposed to pay the tax t. So whether the tax incidence (who gets to pay and how much) will be the same in the two cases?

Consider the case where the supplier has to pay. Suppose at p, before the tax, suppliers supply x. After the tax, if the suppliers supply x, the price must be p+t since what matters is the price that the suppliers can put into their pockets.

Alternatively, suppose consumers have to pay the price. Suppose at p, before the tax, consumers consume x. After the tax, if consumers still consume x, the price must be p-t since what matters is the price that the consumers have to take out of their pockets. Are the two cases the same?

Fig. 16.3

Fig. 16.4

We can also talk about the tax incidence a bit We can also talk about the tax incidence a bit. Imagine two extreme cases. One where the supply is perfectly elastic, the other where it is perfectly inelastic. Suppose before the tax the equilibrium price is p.

supply is perfectly elastic vs supply perfectly inelastic In the former case, no way you can get producers to take in less than p. So consumers pay all the tax. In the latter case, no way you can make consumers pay more than p out of pockets, so producers pay all the tax.

Fig. 16.5

These two extreme cases suggest that the tax incidence has a lot to do with the elasticities of demand and supply. When it is more like the former, consumers pay most of the tax. When it is more like the latter, producers pay most of the tax.

Fig. 16.6

Can also talk about the welfare loss of a tax Can also talk about the welfare loss of a tax. A quantity tax t makes the marginal willingness to pay higher than the marginal willingness to supply by t. So for all units where MWP>MWS, there is a deadweight loss (should be produced, but are not produced).

Fig. 16.7

Alternatively, can calculates the change of consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus to reach the same conclusion.

So why on earth is the market equilibrium so efficient (Pareto efficient)? Think about what Pareto efficiency means. If MWPMWS, it is not efficient because say if MWP>MWS, at least a consumer and a producer can strike a price in-between to produce an additional unit and the consumer is better off while the producer is making more profit.

It is clear that market equilibrium makes MWP=MWS.

What about looking at consumers only What about looking at consumers only? If MWP1>MWP2 (say 5>4), then consumer 1 can buy a unit of good in concern from consumer 2 at the price of 4.5. This will make both 1 and 2 better off. Market equilibrium achieves MWP1=MWP2 because MWP1=p=MWP2.

Look at producers only, if MWS1>MWS2 (say 5>4), then producer 2 can produce a unit of good in concern more and this increases 2’s cost by 4. Producer 1 can reduce its production by a unit and this decreases 1’s cost by 5. So in total, a cost of 1 dollar is saved and this saved cost (saved resource) can be used to produce. Market achieves MWS1=MWS2 because MWS1=p=MWS2.

Market achieves MWP=MWS because the market clearing condition. Market achieves MWP1=MWP2 because MWP1=p=MWP2 (utility maximization). Market achieves MWS1=MWS2 because MWS1=p=MWS2 (profit maximization).

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be efficient.