Rethinking the Inflation Target

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
ECO Global Macroeconomics TAGGERT J. BROOKS SPRING 2014.
Advertisements

Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 12: Stabilization.
The Federal Reserve Decision We will pause to consider the Fed’s announcements last week. It is an important new development We will return to Fed policies.
Monetary Policy Theory
Chapter 23 Monetary Policy Theory. © 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved.23-2 Response of Monetary Policy to Shocks Monetary policy should.
two policy debates: Should policy be active or passive?
Should policy be active or passive?
Money and Stabilization Policy. Monetary Policy In the US (and Euroland and Japan and most OECD economies), the central bank sets monetary policy by picking.
The Relationship Between Inflation and Unemployment An inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment until the 1970s 1970s  high inflation and.
Chapter 16: Inflation, Unemployment, and Federal Reserve Policy © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien,
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics Hubbard/O’Brien UPDATE EDITION. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 28 Inflation, Unemployment,
What is a Business or Economic Cycle?. The Economic Cycle This is a term used to describe the tendency of an economy to move its economic growth away.
Chapter 14 The Monetary Policy Approach to Stabilization.
Final Exam 3 questions: Question 1 (20%). No choice Question 1 (20%). No choice Question 2 (40%). Answer 8 out of 10 short questions. ONLY THE FIRST 8.
Why Some Inflation is Better Than Deflation. Some Benefits of Low Inflation: Inflation causes real interest rates to be lower than nominal interest rates.
Some Remarks on the Theory of Optimal Monetary Policy Marc Giannoni Columbia Business School CEPR, CIRANO, NBER HEC Montréal October 20, 2007.
Module 31 Monetary Policy & the Interest Rate
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 22 Understanding Business Cycles.
 Stabilization policies (fiscal and monetary) are applied to affect inflation and unemployment  The difficulty in stabilization is that inflation and.
Module Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate
Inflation, Unemployment, and Stabilization Policies: Money, Output, and Prices in the Long Run AP Economics Mr. Bordelon.
Module 32 Money Output & Prices in the Long Run. 1. What are the effects of an inappropriate monetary policy? 2. What is the concept of monetary neutrality?
Monetary Policy. The Optimal Inflation Rate? The Optimal Inflation Rate?  Inflation has steadily gone down in rich countries since the early 1980s. 
Pump Primer : Define monetary policy. 31. Module Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* 31 Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Monetary Policy. The Optimal Inflation Rate? The Optimal Inflation Rate?  Inflation has steadily gone down in rich countries since the early 1980s. 
3/7/20161 Inflation: a continuing rise in the general level of prices. Cost more to purchase goods & services that it cost to produced Period of inflation.
Noncompetitive division charts and policy questions The following pages provide a range of indicators (listed in alphabetical order) that you can use to.
Chapter 29: Monetary Policy in Canada Copyright © 2014 Pearson Canada Inc.
The liquidity trap, Mankiw’s 9 th principle, and inflation targets: the Bank of Canada dilemma Serge Coulombe Department of Economics University of Ottawa.
Krugman/Wells Macroeconomics in Modules and Economics in Modules Third Edition MODULE 38(74) Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate.
© 2001 South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning
Macroeconomic Equilibrium
Chapter 16 What Should Central Banks Do? Monetary Policy Goals, Strategy, and Targets.
How the Fed Conducts Monetary Policy
Higher inflation targets?
Chapter 16: The Federal Reserve & Monetary Policy Section 4: Applying Monetary and Fiscal Policy pgs
Professor Steven Kyle Cornell University January 24, 2017
The Fed’s Monetary Tools
MODULE 34 Inflation and Unemployment: The Phillips Curve
The Conduct of Monetary Policy: Strategy and Tactics
Chapter 27 Business cycles
Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply
MODULE 31 MONETARY POLICY AND THE INTEREST RATE
Chapter 28: Monetary Policy in Canada
The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves
Money and Banking Lecture 43.
GCSE Economics 3.4 Managing the Economy Monetary Policy.
Reviewing Monetary Policy Frameworks
Section 4 Module 19.
GDP and the Price Level in the Long Run Chapter 19
KRUGMAN’S Economics for AP® S E C O N D E D I T I O N.
Monetary Policy.
The Conduct of Monetary Policy: Strategy and Tactics
Monetary Policy: A Summing Up
Module Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate
Module The Modern Macroeconomic Consensus
Aggregate Demand and Supply
Monetary Policy.
Module Money, Output, and Prices in the Long Run
Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate
Monetary Policy Theory
Module Money, Output, and Prices in the Long Run
Money, Output, and Prices in the Long Run
Monetary Policy Theory
Part 13 FINAL THOUGHTS.
Module The Modern Macroeconomic Consensus
15(30) MONETARY POLICY Revised by Solina Lindahl.
Applying Monetary & Fiscal Policy
Module Money, Output, and Prices in the Long Run
Presentation transcript:

Rethinking the Inflation Target Frederic S. Mishkin Graduate School of Business, Columbia University Brookings Conference “Should the Fed Stick with the 2% Inflation Target or Rethink it? Washington, D.C., January 8, 2018

Rethinking the Inflation Target Frederic S. Mishkin Graduate School of Business, Columbia University Brookings Conference “Should the Fed Stick with the 2% Inflation Target or Rethink it? Washington, D.C., January 8, 2018

Key Lessons from Recent Years The zero-lower-bound (ZLB) constraint on policy interest rates binds more often than expected. Three reasons: Economy is non-linear (“over the cliff”). Shocks from financial disruptions can be huge. Natural rate of interest has fallen

Key Lessons from the Financial Crisis Once ZLB constraint occurs, it is much harder to stimulate the economy and raise inflation. Nonconventional tools less effective than hoped. Key dilemma for central banks in advance countries is that despite heroic measures, inflation remains below 2%

Should the Long-Run Inflation Target be Raised to Above 2%? Prominent economists (e.g., Blanchard) suggest target should be raised to something like 4%. Pros: With higher target, ZLB less likely to occur. With higher target, conventional monetary policy of lowering policy rate can ease more because higher expected inflation allows lower real rate.

Should the Long-Run Inflation Target be Raised to Above 2%? Cons: More difficult to stabilize inflation at 4% than 2%. 4% not consistent with Greenspan definition of price stability where inflation is not big factor in economic decisions. Once inflation rises above Greenspan definition at 4%, then why not 6%, or 8% and so on. Exactly what happened in U.S. starting in 60s: View that 4-5% inflation could be tolerated to achieve lower unemployment, with outcome of Great Inflation and high cost to getting inflation back down. One of great successes of central banks over last 20 years is anchoring of inflation expectations around 2%: Raising target to 4% would jeopardize hard-won success of establishing a strong nominal anchor. With higher target, ZLB less likely to occur With higher target, conventional monetary policy of lowering policy rate can ease more because higher expected inflation allows lower real rate.

Should the Long-Run Inflation Target be Raised to Above 2%? Additional Cons: Although raising target might have short-run benefits, it produces distortions in long run. These costs may be small for any given year, but they add up over time.

Should the Long-Run Inflation Target be Raised to Above 2%? Bottom line: Costs of raising inflation target to 4% outweigh the benefits. Answer to question above? NO

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? Inflation targeting as practiced is not history-dependent: treats bygones as bygones, so past undershoots do not affect policy. Woodford (2003) provides compelling theoretical argument for history-dependent target in which if the target has been undershot in recent past, the monetary policy should strive to overshoot in near future.

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? Price-level target is one form of history-dependent policy and it produces less output variance. Negative demand shock results in price level falling below target path, say 2% growth, requires raising price level back to path, so inflation rises above 2% temporarily. Expected inflation rises above 2%, lowering real interest rate, thereby stimulating economic activity. History-dependent price-level target is automatic stabilizer: negative shock leads to stabilizing expectations Even more effective when ZLB is binding (Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003).

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? Another similar history-dependent policy is nominal GDP target. Eggertsson and Woodford argue for target criterion of output-adjusted price level. Because “output-adjusted price level target” hard for public and markets to understand, Woodford (2012) argues for a simpler criterion of nominal GDP path which grows at the inflation target plus the growth rate of potential GDP.

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? Formidable challenges to price-level and nominal GDP targets: Hard to explain aiming for a target that is rising over time: targeting a level of inflation easier to explain. When inflation temporarily rises above 2%, may be hard to explain that commitment is to long-run 2% target. Nominal GDP target has additional problem because it requires that central bank takes a stance on number for potential GDP, which is highly uncertain and can lead to policy mistakes circa Fed in 1970s. Explains why have not been adopted.

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? Another way to skin the cat and adopt a history-dependent policy that can be explained to public and markets. 2% target should be for an average over a particular period, say 5-years, or over the business cycle, or since the ZLB started (Bernanke), rather than for a particular date such as 2-years ahead. If inflation had been running at 1.5% for a several years, then monetary policy would aim for 2.5% for several years. Would be particularly effective with ZLB because it would raise inflation expectations temporarily, lowering real interest rate. Additional benefit: encourages more expansionary policy in face of negative demand shocks.

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? This history-dependent policy has been implemented by the Reserve Bank of Australia, with 2-3% target “on average over the business cycle”. Economic performance in Australia has been excellent: Average inflation since 1995 is 2.7%--very close to 2.5% midpoint of target range--and no recession in 25 years. Curdia (2016) provided evidence that such a policy, which would have implied a temporary overshooting of 2% target to 2.5%, would have produced better outcomes in U.S.

Should Monetary Policy Ever Try to Overshoot the Inflation Target? Bottom line: Fed and other central banks should commit to achieve an average inflation rate of 2% over a fixed period say 5 years or since ZLB occurred, and if there have been undershoots, this implies having a target inflation rate above 2% for several years. However central bank should be very clear that it is continuing its commitment to long-run target of 2%