Second Conference On Measuring Human Progress Going Beyond Income: Measuring Inequality March 4, 2013 Conchita DAmbrosio, University of Milan Alan Fuchs,

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
WP2 workshop, NIESR, November 24-25, 2005 Labour quality.
Advertisements

The Marginal Utility of Income Richard Layard* Guy Mayraz* Steve Nickell** * CEP, London School of Economics ** Nuffield College, Oxford.
© 2003 By Default!Slide 1 Poverty Measures Celia M. Reyes Introduction to Poverty Analysis NAI, Beijing, China Nov. 1-8, 2005.
Assessing “Success” in Anti-Poverty Policy Lars Osberg Dalhousie University October 1, 2004.
James Foster George Washington University and OPHI 2 nd Conference on Measuring Human Progress 4-5 March 2013, New York Reflections on the Human Development.
4. FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION
Methodological and Analytical Issues Gaia Dallera 6 June,
Stéfan Lollivier, Insee 27/06/2012 Improvements in the measurement of quality of life and well-being in France Measuring Well-Being and Fostering the Progress.
Milorad Kovacevic Human Development Report Office, UNDP Workshop on Measuring Human Development, June 14,2013 GIZ, Eschborn, Germany 1 HDI and Inequality.
The Human Development Indices
GENDER ISSUES ACADEMIC YEAR Measuring gender inequalities: the UNDP new gender inequality index (E.Chiappero-Martinetti)
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
Chapter 4 Multiple Regression.
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
A quick introduction to the analysis of questionnaire data John Richardson.
The Simple Regression Model
Chapter 18: Distributionally-Weighted Cost Benefit Analysis.
Chapter 11 Multiple Regression.
Reinert/Windows on the World Economy, 2005 Development Concepts CHAPTER 19.
HDI and its neglect in Pakistan
Human Development Index vs Unemployment Rate
Choices, Capabilities and Sustainability Second Conference on Measuring Human Development March 4 th -5 th 2012 Jean-Paul Fitoussi and Khalid Malik.
Poverty measures: Properties and Robustness
Critical Literature Review of the Human Development Indices Prepared for UNDP Practicum in International Affairs May 2009 Semra Hailelul Alula Alex Iyasu.
Constructing the Welfare Aggregate Part 2: Adjusting for Differences Across Individuals Bosnia and Herzegovina Poverty Analysis Workshop September 17-21,
Comments on Measuring Inequality in Human Development Second Conference on Measuring Human Progress NY, March 4-5, 2013 Carmen Herrero.
Introduction ► This slide deck provides a suggested framework for the financial evaluation of an investment project. When evaluating any such project,
Measuring Development
New Human Development Measures DOHA, 9-11 May, 2011 HDR 2010.
McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. Chapter 9 Hypothesis Testing.
Hypothesis Testing A hypothesis is a conjecture about a population. Typically, these hypotheses will be stated in terms of a parameter such as  (mean)
Statistical Techniques I
Review of Statistical Inference Prepared by Vera Tabakova, East Carolina University ECON 4550 Econometrics Memorial University of Newfoundland.
Chapter 9 Statistical Data Analysis
Chapter 3 Data Exploration and Dimension Reduction 1.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
Decomposing Variations in the Watts Multidimensional Poverty Index.
Xavier Sala-i-Martin Columbia University June 2008.
© Copyright McGraw-Hill CHAPTER 3 Data Description.
Introduction to Statistical Quality Control, 4th Edition
Gender disparities in human development Side event on the margins of the 59 th Commission on Status of Women Human Development Report Office Milorad Kovacevic,
Essential Statistics Chapter 131 Introduction to Inference.
World Bank’s Thematic Group on Health, Nutrition and Population and Poverty REACHING THE POOR CONFERENCE, February, 2004 ASSESSING CHANGES IN TARGETING.
By: Amani Albraikan.  Pearson r  Spearman rho  Linearity  Range restrictions  Outliers  Beware of spurious correlations….take care in interpretation.
Chapter 4 Control Charts for Measurements with Subgrouping (for One Variable)
1 Chapter 9 Hypothesis Testing. 2 Chapter Outline  Developing Null and Alternative Hypothesis  Type I and Type II Errors  Population Mean: Known 
Comment on Bosssert, D’Ambrosio & Grenier paper Branko Milanovic, World Bank.
1 Components of the Deterministic Portion of the Utility “Deterministic -- Observable -- Systematic” portion of the utility!  Mathematical function of.
Social Evaluation of Alternative Basic Income Schemes in Italy R. Aaberge (Statistics Norway, Oslo) U. Colombino (Department of Economics, Torino) S. Strøm.
DTC Quantitative Methods Bivariate Analysis: t-tests and Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) Thursday 14 th February 2013.
Constructing the Welfare Aggregate Part 2: Adjusting for Differences Across Individuals Salman Zaidi Washington DC, January 19th,
 Assumptions are an essential part of statistics and the process of building and testing models.  There are many different assumptions across the range.
Misure di povertà multidimensionale: recenti sviluppi e nuove proposte Measuring Multidimensional Poverty: the Generalized Counting Approach W. Bossert,
What is Quality of Life. How can we measure it
1 Measuring Poverty: Inequality Measures Charting Inequality Share of Expenditure of Poor Dispersion Ratios Lorenz Curve Gini Coefficient Theil Index Comparisons.
1 ICP PPP Methods Regional Course on Price Statistics and ICP Male, Maldives September 2005 TIMOTHY LO Statistician, International Comparison Program.
Regional Policy Guidance on monitoring TÓTH Gábor DG EMPL – Impact Assessment, Evaluation Unit ESF Evaluation Partnership meeting, Rome, 26 November 2014.
HUMAN DEVELOPMENT INDEX HDI Report 2014 IB ECONOMICS.
HUMAN DEVELOPMENT INDEX
Logistic Regression: Regression with a Binary Dependent Variable.
Stats Methods at IC Lecture 3: Regression.
DTC Quantitative Methods Bivariate Analysis: t-tests and Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) Thursday 20th February 2014  
Emerging and developing economies: measures of development
INTRODUCTORY STATISTICS FOR CRIMINAL JUSTICE
Chapter 9 Hypothesis Testing.
Point 2.1 of the agenda: net monthly income of the household
GDP and beyond Robin Lynch
AMIS 3300 Capital Budgeting.
GDP and beyond Robin Lynch
Presumptions Subgroups (samples) of data are formed.
Presentation transcript:

Second Conference On Measuring Human Progress Going Beyond Income: Measuring Inequality March 4, 2013 Conchita DAmbrosio, University of Milan Alan Fuchs, Human Development Report Office

Incorporating Equality when measuring Human Development Equality is at the core of the human development approach which intrinsically pursues the value of social justice

Inequality-Adjusted HDI Adjusts HDI for inequalities in distribution of each component Discounts average value according to inequality level Inequality measured by Atkinson-Kolm-Sen method: Allows use of different inequality aversion parameters Requires micro-data (household survey data) Difference between IHDI and HDI represents loss due to inequalities in distribution of achievements in each dimension

Inequality-Adjusted HDI Presumed policy relevance: Inform policies towards inequality reduction in each dimension HDI could be viewed as index of potential human development IHDI is index of actual human development

Issues related to IHDI Loss in HDI due to inequality needs better justification and interpretation Applying welfare-based Atkinson-Kolm-Sen measure to distributions of life expectancy and years of schooling is questionable Income index (log transformed) is adjusted by inequality from untransformed income data assuming that the percentage loss due to inequality in income distribution is the same for both average income and its log

Issues related to IHDI Combining inequalities that pertain to different years across dimensions may be misleading and misinterpreted IHDI is not association sensitive: it does not account for overlapping inequalities Values of indicators at the micro level need to be adjusted to non-negative/non-zero values uniformly across countries so that the geometric mean can be computed

Comments and suggestions on the IHDI by Walter Bossert, Conchita DAmbrosio and Louise Grenier IHDI is a good idea. The disadvantages we see are, to a large extent, due to complexities regarding transformations that are applied to the data and to the lack of satisfactory data availability. We argue that the most promising way forward in order to provide a meaningful index is to collect better data at the individual level.

Data available at the individual level Natural way to proceed: 1) Obtain first an individual development index: d i (h i, e i, x i ). 2) Then aggregate across the population. We do not see any advantage from path independence (which holds if mean of same order is applied in both stages). h h… h e e… e x x… x 1 2

d i is not known: A promising way to deal with the lack of exact knowledge regarding individual aggregation methods may be to assume that d i are within a parameterized class and calculate an expectation over the range of possible parameter values. An alternative method has been proposed by Seth (2009) where the individual development index is assumed to be a weighted mean of order ß, where ß reflects the degree of association among attributes.

The use of measures additively decomposable among population groups would allow issues such as disparities between different subgroups of the population to be addressed in a consistent manner. It is desirable to have one single method which allows us to understand not only how much of total inequality in human development is due to differences between gender groups but also how much inequality exists within each group, an issue which is neglected by the GII.

Until more comprehensive data are available, temporary improvements can be realized by computing for the countries where a possibility already exists the IHDI directly from the available datasets without modifying the HDI for the presence of inequality. We recommend a direct estimation of total inequality in the distribution of the three dimensions across the population. Disconnect the IHDI from the HDI For the time being

By having such an estimate we avoid at least three weaknesses of the current IHDI: (a)The assumption that the percentage loss due to inequality in income distribution is the same for both average income and its logarithm. (b)Adjusting the HDI components that refer to one year with the inequalities that refer to different years. (c)The IHDI will be completely independent from the HDI. This will possibly allow an easier explanation of the advantages generated from the fight against inequalities and offer an incentive for policy makers to reach this objective. Estimation of total inequality

For the EU countries individual data of good quality are available. We provide an application using EU-SILC from 2005 to 2009 of the IHDI as the general mean of general means and discuss some of the decisions that should be taken if this method were accepted. Estimation of total inequality

For the three basic dimensionsa decent standard of living, access to knowledge and a long and healthy life the following variables are in the dataset: disposable household income (per capita vs. equivalent), the highest International Standard Classification of Education (ISCED) level attained (seven categories), self-reported health status (five categories). Estimation of total inequality

Interpretation of loss Following our proposal of the direct estimation of total inequality in the distribution of the three dimensions, we could estimate directly the general means and compare these values to the corresponding arithmetic means. This gain would be expressed as a percentage as follows: This will provide incentives to cut inequality, since it will sound like We achieved the level of the HDI of 0.8 but if distributions were more equal, the HDI would be 0.9

Interpretation of loss

Non-negative/non-zero values These modifications do have a strong impact on the value of the inequality measure. The method reduces inequality by squeezing the range of the income distribution and also modifies inequality since the index is scale invariant (the transformation would be irrelevant had a translation-invariant measure been used). For these reasons we believe that it would be preferable to use another specification of the Atkinson-Kolm-Sen inequality index which would behave differently when the value of an observation is zero.

Non-negative/non-zero values We drop all observations with missing values in any of the dimensions and use sample weights in the estimation of the indices. We do not normalize the data and we compare the rankings of the countries for three cases: Case A) uses the income data as they appear in the dataset, hence the inclusion of zero and negative values in the measure; Case B) replaces zero and negative values by the minimum value of the bottom 0.5 percentile of the distribution of positive incomes; Case C) includes only positive incomes by dropping zero and negative values. Of course in Case A the geometric mean is not considered.

Non-negative/non-zero values

It seems to us that, once the functional form is chosen, then it has to be applied accepting all its consequences, and modifying the data to produce a more appealing situation somehow lacks legitimacy. If the functional form has to be maintained, dropping zero and negative incomes seems preferable to us since we do not know what is behind these unusual observations which would indicate a non-survival level for the individual. However, the same does not necessarily apply to education and health where a zero value represents exactly what is intended.

Means of different orders: alternative values of the inequality aversion parameter A possible improvement that reflects inequality aversion and imperfect substitutability across dimensions may be achieved by using an alternative member of the Atkinson-Kolm-Sen family that is based on the sum of means of an order strictly between 0 and 1 (this parameter restriction guarantees inequality aversion), such as a mean of order ½. We believe that this choice is preferable to modifying the data in order to avoid the exclusion of zero values.

Means of different orders: alternative values of the inequality aversion parameter

Income: per capita vs equivalent, log vs level We are in full agreement with Alkire and Foster (2010) that incomes rather than their logarithms should be used. Each dimension index is a proxy for capabilities in the corresponding dimension, the transformation function from income to capabilities is likely to be concave (Anand and Sen, 2000). The typical distribution of income has a long right tail, which renders this transformation inappropriate when computing the equality component for income. Computing inequality on the distribution of the log of income would imply a consistent reduction of the actual level of inequality.

Income: per capita vs equivalent, log vs level The standard practice within the IHDI is to divide household income by the number of household members to obtain per capita income. We expand this tradition and generate the results also for equivalent income, that is, for disposable household income divided by a smaller number in order to take into account economies of scale generated by cohabitation. The latter is more standard in the income distribution literature and preferred to the first as a proxy for material well-being. The equivalent scale we use is the modified OECD scale which assigns a coefficient of 1 to the first adult, 0.5 to any additional individual aged 14 and above and 0.3 if the additional individual is younger.

Income: per capita vs equivalent, log vs level

Conclusion We have proposed to compute the IHDI directly from the available data at the individual level, without going through the modification of the HDI. With an application to EU countries we have offered a sensitivity analysis of three main issues: 1)the transformation of the data in order to deal with negative and zero values; 2)income per capita as opposed to equivalent income; 3)alternative values of the inequality aversion parameter.

Conclusion Our preferred choice, for the various reasons we have highlighted, is a general mean of order r strictly between 0 and 1 (such as r=½) of general means of the same order applied to the unmodified distributions of equivalent incomes. We hope that the sensitivity analysis we have provided will be of help to the relevant parties in the decision on the type of IHDI for the next few years.

Conclusion Once individual data from a unique source will become available for many countries, more analysis is needed to test the effects of the individual-first aggregation procedure and alternative inequality indices such as those that are additively decomposable among population subgroups.