Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Strategic Pricing: Theory, Practice and Policy Professor John W. Mayo
Advertisements

The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry
Market Institutions: Oligopoly
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Strategic Interaction Finance 510: Microeconomic Analysis.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Chapter 12 Oligopoly. Chapter 122 Oligopoly – Characteristics Small number of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist Barriers to entry.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Ten.
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Basic Oligopoly Models
Chapter 11 Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers.
Chapter 12 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly.
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Strategic Pricing Techniques.
CHAPTER 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
Oligopoly and Strategic Interaction
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 27 Oligopoly.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers. Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially –one firm makes a move new product advertising.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Market structure and competition By A.V. Vedpuriswar.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Static Games and Cournot Competition.
CHAPTER 12 Imperfect Competition. The profit-maximizing output for the monopoly 2 If there are no other market entrants, the entrepreneur can earn monopoly.
Oligopoly. Structure Assume Duopoly Firms know information about market demand Perfect Information.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
CHAPTER 23 MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY.
Perfect competition, with an infinite number of firms, and monopoly, with a single firm, are polar opposites. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly.
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly. u A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. u A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. u An oligopoly.
Today n Oligopoly Theory n Economic Experiment in Class.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey.
1 Chapter 10 Price Competition 2 In a wide variety of markets firms compete in prices –Internet access –Restaurants –Consultants –Financial services.
Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets
Chapter 11 The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry.
Monopolistic competition and Oligopoly
Managerial Economics Game Theory Aalto University School of Science Department of Industrial Engineering and Management January 12 – 28, 2016 Dr. Arto.
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
Oligopoly Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers, when.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Lecture 6 Oligopoly 1. 2 Introduction A monopoly does not have to worry about how rivals will react to its action simply because there are no rivals.
Managerial Economics Game Theory
Imperfect Competition
Static Games and Cournot Competition
27 Oligopoly.
Chapter 28 Oligopoly.
Games Of Strategy Chapter 4 Dixit, Skeath, and Reiley
Today Oligopoly Theory Economic Experiment in Class.
Oligopoly Managerial Economics Kyle Anderson
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
BUS 525: Managerial Economics Basic Oligopoly Models
CHAPTER 12 OUTLINE Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Price Competition Competition versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma 12.5.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
Dynamic games and First and Second Movers (The Stackelberg Model)
Static Games and Quantity vs. Price Competition
CHAPTER 10 Oligopoly.
Lecture 10 The Bertrand Model
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Chapter Twenty-Seven Oligopoly.
Theory of Industrial Organisation
Presentation transcript:

Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model ECON 4100: Industrial Organization Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model

This would not be the case of an oligopolistic market... Oligopoly Models A puritan’s idea of hell is a place where everybody has to mind their own business (Wendell Phillips) This would not be the case of an oligopolistic market...

Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors In determining strategy each firm has to consider rival’s reactions strategic interaction in prices, outputs, advertising … This kind of interaction is analyzed using game theory assumes that players are rational Distinguish cooperative and noncooperative games focus on noncooperative games Also consider timing simultaneous versus sequential games

Oligopoly Theory No single theory Need a concept of equilibrium employ game theoretic tools that are appropriate outcome depends upon information available Need a concept of equilibrium players (firms?) choose strategies, one for each player combination of strategies determines outcome outcome determines pay-offs (profits etc) Equilibrium first formalized by Nash Once the strategies of the other players are revealed, no player would like to unilaterally change her strategy

Nash Equilibrium Equilibrium need not be the best possible outcome firms might do better by coordinating but such coordination may not be possible (or legal) or incentive-compatible Some strategies are never good strategies no matter what the rivals do: dominated strategies they are never employed and so can be eliminated elimination of a dominated strategy may result in another being dominated: it also can be eliminated One strategy that should be chosen no matter what the rivals do is a dominant strategy

An Example Two airlines Prices set: compete in departure times 70% of consumers prefer evening departure, 30% prefer morning departure If the airlines choose the same departure times they share the market equally Pay-offs to the airlines are determined by market shares Represent the pay-offs in a pay-off matrix

The example (cont.) What is the equilibrium for this game? The Pay-Off Matrix The left-hand number is the pay-off to Delta American Morning Evening Morning (15, 15) (30, 70) The right-hand number is the pay-off to American Delta Evening (70, 30) (35, 35)

The example (cont.) The morning departure is also a dominated strategy for American and again can be eliminated The morning departure is a dominated strategy for Delta and so can be eliminated. If American chooses a morning departure, Delta will choose evening If American chooses an evening departure, Delta will still choose evening The example (cont.) The Pay-Off Matrix American The Nash Equilibrium must therefore be one in which both airlines choose an evening departure Morning Evening Morning (15, 15) (30, 70) Delta (35, 35) Evening (70, 30) (35, 35)

The example (cont.) Now suppose that Delta has a frequent flier program When both airline choose the same departure times Delta gets 60% of the travelers This changes the pay-off matrix

The example (cont.) However, a morning departure is still a dominated strategy for Delta (Evening is still a dominant strategy. If Delta chooses a morning departure, American will choose evening The example (cont.) American has no dominated strategy The Pay-Off Matrix But if Delta chooses an evening departure, American will choose morning American American knows this and so chooses a morning departure Morning Evening Morning (18, 12) (30, 70) Delta (70, 30) Evening (70, 30) (42, 28)

Nash Equilibrium Again What if there are no dominated or dominant strategies? The Nash equilibrium concept can still help us in eliminating at least some outcomes Change the airline game to a pricing game: 60 potential passengers with a reservation price of $500 120 additional passengers with a reservation price of $220 price discrimination is not possible (perhaps for regulatory reasons or because the airlines don’t know the passenger types) costs are $200 per passenger no matter when the plane leaves the airlines must choose between a price of $500 and a price of $220 if equal prices are charged the passengers are evenly shared Otherwise the low-price airline gets all the passengers The pay-off matrix is now:

The example (cont.) If Delta prices high and American low then American gets all 180 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20 If both price high then both get 30 passengers. Profit per passenger is $300 The Pay-Off Matrix If Delta prices low and American high then Delta gets all 180 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20 American If both price low they each get 90 passengers. Profit per passenger is $20 PH = $500 PL = $220 PH = $500 ($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

Nash Equilibrium (cont.) There is no simple way to choose between these equilibria, but at least we have eliminated half of the outcomes as possible equilibria (PH, PH) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing high then neither wants to change There are two Nash equilibria to this version of the game Nash Equilibrium (cont.) (PH, PL) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices low then Delta would want to price low, too. The Pay-Off Matrix (PL, PL) is a Nash equilibrium. If both are pricing low then neither wants to change American (PL, PH) cannot be a Nash equilibrium. If American prices high then Delta should also price high PH = $500 PL = $220 ($9000, $9000) ($0, $3600) PH = $500 ($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

Nash Equilibrium (cont.) The only sensible choice for Delta is PH knowing that American will follow with PH and each will earn $9000. So, the Nash equilibria now is (PH, PH) Suppose that Delta can set its price first Sometimes, consideration of the timing of moves can help us find the equilibrium Nash Equilibrium (cont.) Delta can see that if it sets a high price, then American will do best by also pricing high. Delta earns $9000 The Pay-Off Matrix This means that PH, PL cannot be an equilibrium outcome American This means that PL,PH cannot be an equilibrium PH = $500 PL = $220 Delta can also see that if it sets a low price, American will do best by pricing low. Delta will then earn $1800 ($9,000, $9,000) ($0, $3600) PH = $500 ($9000,$9000) ($0, $3600) Delta ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800) ($1800, $1800) PL = $220 ($3600, $0) ($1800, $1800)

Oligopoly Models There are three dominant oligopoly models Cournot Bertrand Stackelberg They are distinguished by the decision variable that firms choose (price or quantity) the timing of the underlying game

Oligopoly Models There are three dominant oligopoly models Cournot Bertrand Stackelberg each embodies the Nash equilibrium concept all assume that the number of firms is fixed (no entry, due to high entry barriers) all usually assume that firms are identical (same product same production costs) We will start considering the simple Cournot model

The Cournot Model P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2) Start with a duopoly: consider identical product Demand for this product is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2) where q1 is output of Firm 1 and q2 is output of Firm 2 Marginal cost for each firm is constant at $c per unit To get the demand curve for one firm we treat the output of the other firm as constant (zero-conjecture) => Firm 2’s demand is P = (A - Bq1) - Bq2

The Cournot model (cont.) If the output of Firm 1 is increased the demand curve for Firm 2 moves to the left P = (A - Bq1) - Bq2 $ The profit-maximizing choice of output by Firm 2 depends upon the output of Firm 1 A - Bq1 A - Bq’1 Marginal revenue for Firm 2 is Solve this for output q2 Demand c MC MR2 = (A - Bq1) - 2Bq2 MR2 MR2 = MC q*2 Quantity A - Bq1 - 2Bq2 = c => q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2

The Cournot model (cont.) q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q1/2 This is the best response function for Firm 2 It gives Firm 2’s profit-maximizing choice of output for any choice of output by Firm 1 There is also a best response function for Firm 1 By exactly the same argument it can be written: q*1 = (A - c)/2B - q2/2 Cournot-Nash equilibrium requires that both firms be on their best response functions.

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium If Firm 2 produces (A-c)/B then Firm 1 will choose to produce no output The best response function for Firm 1 is q*1 = (A-c)/2B - q2/2 The Cournot-Nash equilibrium is at Point C at the intersection of the best response functions (A-c)/B Firm 1’s best response function If Firm 2 produces nothing then Firm 1 will produce the monopoly output (A-c)/2B The best response function for Firm 2 is q*2 = (A-c)/2B - q1/2 (A-c)/2B C qC2 Firm 2’s best response function q1 (A-c)/2B (A-c)/B qC1

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium q*1 = (A - c)/2B - q*2/2 q2 q*2 = (A - c)/2B - q*1/2 (A-c)/B Firm 1’s best response function => q*2 = (A - c)/2B - (A - c)/4B+q*2/4 => 3q*2/4 = (A - c)/4B (A-c)/2B  q*2 = (A - c)/3B C (A-c)/3B  q*1 = (A - c)/3B Firm 2’s best response function q1 (A-c)/2B (A-c)/B (A-c)/3B

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.) Competition between the firms => total output exceeds monopoly output. And price is lower than the monopoly price But output is less than the competitive output where price equals marginal cost P exceeds MC

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium N firms What if there are more than two firms? Much the same approach. Say that there are N identical firms producing identical products Total output Q = q1 + q2 + … + qN Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2 + … + qN) Consider Firm 1. It’s demand curve can be written: This denotes output of every firm other than Firm 1 P = A - B(q2 + … + qN) - Bq1 Use a simplifying notation: Q-1 = q2 + q3 + … + qN So demand for Firm 1 is P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1

The Cournot model N firms If the output of the other firms is increased the demand curve for Firm 1 moves to the left P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1 $ The profit-maximizing choice q1 by Firm 1 depends upon the output of the other firms A - BQ-1 A - BQ’-1 Marginal revenue for Firm 1 is Solve this for output q1 Demand c MC MR1 = (A - BQ-1) - 2Bq1 MR1 MR1 = MC q*1 Quantity A - BQ-1 - 2Bq1 = c  q*1 = (A - c)/2B - Q-1/2

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium N firms q*1 = (A - c)/2B - Q-1/2 As the number of firms increases output of each firm falls How do we solve this for q*1? The firms are identical. So in equilibrium they will have identical outputs => Q*-1 = (N - 1)q*1 As the number of firms increases aggregate output increases => q*1 = (A - c)/2B - (N - 1)q*1/2 As the number of firms increases price tends to marginal cost As the number of firms increases profit of each firm falls =>(1 + (N - 1)/2)q*1 = (A - c)/2B => q*1(N + 1)/2 = (A - c)/2B => q*1 = (A - c)/(N + 1)B => Q* = N(A - c)/(N + 1)B => P* = A - BQ* = (A + Nc)/(N + 1) Profit of Firm 1 is P*1 = (P* - c)q*1 = (A - c)2/(N + 1)2B

Cournot-Nash equilibrium different costs What if the firms do not have identical costs? Once again, much the same analysis can be used Assume that marginal costs of Firm 1 are c1 and of Firm 2 are c2. Demand is P = A - BQ = A - B(q1 + q2) We have marginal revenue for Firm 1 as before MR1 = (A - Bq2) - 2Bq1 Equate to marginal cost: (A - Bq2) - 2Bq1 = c1 Solve this for output q1 A symmetric result holds for output of Firm 2 => q*1 = (A - c1)/2B - q2/2 => q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - q1/2

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium q*1 = (A - c1)/2B - q*2/2 q2 The equilibrium output of Firm 2 increases and of Firm 1 falls As the marginal cost of Firm 2 falls its best response curve shifts to the right q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - q*1/2 What happens to this equilibrium when costs change? (A-c1)/B R1 => q*2 = (A - c2)/2B - (A - c1)/4B + q*2/4 =>3q*2/4 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/4B (A-c2)/2B => q*2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B C R2 => q*1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B q1 (A-c1)/2B (A-c2)/B

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.) In equilibrium the firms produce qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B; qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B Total output is, therefore, Q* = (2A - c1 - c2)/3B Recall that demand is P = A - BQ So price is P* = A - (2A - c1 - c2)/3 = (A + c1 +c2)/3 Profit of Firm 1 is (P* - c1)qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)2/9B Profit of Firm 2 is (P* - c2)qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)2/9B

Cournot-Nash Equilibrium (cont.) Equilibrium output is less than the competitive level Output is produced inefficiently: the low-cost firm should produce all the output

A Numerical Example with Different Costs Let demand be given by: P = 100 – 2Q; A = 100, B =2 Let c1 = 5 and c2 = 15 Total output is, Q* = (2A - c1 - c2)/3B = (200 – 5 – 15)/6 = 30 qC1 = (A - 2c1 + c2)/3B = (100 – 10 + 15)/6 = 17.5 qC2 = (A - 2c2 + c1)/3B = (100 – 30 + 5)/3B = 12.5 Price is P* = (A + c1 +c2)/3 = (100 + 5 + 15)/3 = 40 Profit of Firm 1 is (A - 2c1 + c2)2/9B =(100 – 10 +5)2/18 = $612.5 Profit of Firm 2 is (A - 2c2 + c1)2/9B = $312.5 Producers would be better off and consumers no worse off if Firm 2’s 12.5 units were instead produced by Firm 1

Concentration and Profitability Assume that we have N firms with different marginal costs We can use the N-firm analysis with a simple change Recall that demand for Firm 1 is P = (A - BQ-1) - Bq1 But then demand for Firm i is P = (A - BQ-i) - Bqi Equate this to marginal cost ci But Q*-i + q*i = Q* and A - BQ* = P* A - BQ-i - 2Bqi = ci This can be reorganized to give the equilibrium condition: A - B(Q*-i + q*i) - Bq*i - ci = 0 => P* - Bq*i - ci = 0 => P* - ci = Bq*i

Concentration and profitability (cont.) The price-cost margin for each firm is determined by its own market share and overall market demand elasticity P* - ci = Bq*i Divide by P* and multiply the right-hand side by Q*/Q* The average price-cost margin is determined by industry concentration as measured by the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index P* - ci BQ* q*i = P* P* Q* But BQ*/P* = 1/ (the inverse of the demand elasticity) and q*i/Q* = si (market share) P* - ci si so: =  P* Extending this we have P* - c H = P* 

Next: The Bertrand Model In the Cournot model price is set by some market clearing mechanism An alternative approach is to assume that firms compete in prices: this is the approach taken by Bertrand Read Chapter 10