Second degree price discrimination

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
+ Lecture 5: Price Discrimination AEM 4160: Strategic Pricing Prof. Jura Liaukonyte 1.
Advertisements

Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
Second degree price discrimination
ECON 171 First degree price discrimination. ECON 171 Introduction Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-off purchases Buying in bulk.
Price Discrimination A monopoly engages in price discrimination if it is able to sell otherwise identical units of output at different prices Whether a.
Economics of Management Strategy BEE3027 Lecture 4.
Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.
Chapter Twelve Pricing.
1 Price Discrimination. 2 Introduction Price Discrimination describes strategies used by firms to extract surplus from customers.
Ch. 23: Monopoly Del Mar College John Daly ©2003 South-Western Publishing, A Division of Thomson Learning.
Pricing Policies chapter 18
Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.
Are Monopolies Desirable?
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
Industrial Organization: Chapter 31 Chapter 3 Basic Monopoly Pricing and Product Strategies.
Monopoly Chapter 12. The Theory of Monopoly A firm is a monopoly if... There is one seller The single seller sells a product for which there is no close.
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.
Price Discrimination 1. Defined: Sellers engage in price discrimination when they charge different prices to different consumers for the same good, because.
As we wait for class to start, please sign in for today’s attendance tracking: Text to 37607: Lenovo44 netID Go online to: PollEv.com/dyson netID or.
Consumer & producer surplusslide 1 Analysis of Competitive Markets In this section, we examine the social welfare implications of competitive markets.
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Monopoly and Other Forms of Imperfect Competition
Chapter 15 Monopoly.
Non-linear price discrimination
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Chapter 26 Monopoly Behavior
Unit 4: Imperfect Competition
Perfect competition vis-à-vis monopolies
Price Discrimination.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior.
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 15
Advanced Pricing Techniques
Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if . . .
Chapter 14: Advanced Pricing Techniques
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
Lecture 6 Additional topics on monopoly
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Lecture 5 Monopoly Pricing
Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing
Pricing.
Ch. 13: Monopoly Causes of monopoly
Price Discrimination and Monopoly
LIPSEY & CHRYSTAL ECONOMICS 12e
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS: PART 2
Pure Monopoly.
Monopoly and Pricing.
Monopoly (Part 3) PRICE DISCRIMINATION.
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
Chapter 4: Essential Microeconomic Tools Everything should be made as simple as possible, but not simpler. Albert Einstein.
Monopoly and Pricing.
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
Walter Nicholson Christopher Snyder
Economic Effects of Export Subsidies in a Small Country
Monopoly © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a.
Market Structures I: Monopoly
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Chapter 11 Price Discrimination.
CHAPTER 6 Consumer and Producer Surplus
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Monopoly 15.
Presentation transcript:

Second degree price discrimination Nonlinear pricing Second degree price discrimination ECO 171

Self-selection What if the seller cannot distinguish between buyers? perhaps they differ in income (unobservable) Then the type of price discrimination just discussed is impossible High-income buyer will pretend to be a low-income buyer to avoid the high entry price to pay the smaller total charge Take a specific example Ph = 16 – Qh Pl = 12 – Ql MC = 4 ECO 171

Second-degree price discrimination 2 First-degree price discrimination requires: High Income: entry fee $72 and $4 per drink or entry plus 12 drinks for a total charge of $120 Low Income: entry fee $32 and $4 per drink or entry plus 8 drinks for total charge of $64 This will not work high income types get no consumer surplus from the package designed for them but get consumer surplus from the other package so they will pretend to be low income even if this limits the number of drinks they can buy Need to design a “menu” of offerings targeted at the two types ECO 171

Second-degree price discrimination 3 The seller has to compromise Design a pricing scheme that makes buyers reveal their true types self-select the quantity/price package designed for them Essence of second-degree price discrimination It is “like” first-degree price discrimination the seller knows that there are buyers of different types but the seller is not able to identify the different types A two-part tariff is ineffective allows deception by buyers Use quantity discounting ECO 171

Simple example p q 5 1 3 2 p q 4 1 2 mc = 0 If possible to separate: Sell 2 units to each. Charge consumer 1 a total of $8 and consumer 2 a total of $5. This does not work if unable to separate. Whatever alternative is offered to consumer 2, the other type could choose. Self-selection Instruments to discriminate: handicap one of the alternatives. How: making it smaller! Consumer 1 p q 5 1 3 2 Consumer 2 p q 4 1 2 ECO 171

Simple example - continued Size of package Value to consumer 1 Value to consumer 2 1 5 4 2 8 Consumer 1 p q 5 1 3 2 Looks like the self-selection problem of business and tourists. Discrimination: Set price of package with one unit = 4 Price of package with two units = 7 Profits = $11 Implementation: Sell two packages Offer a pair of two-part tariffs: F1=4, p1=3, F2=0, p2=4. Nonlinear price: unit 1 = $4, unit 2 = $3 Consumer 2 p q 4 1 2 ECO 171

Example 2 – discrimination not worthwhile Size of package Value to consumer 1 Value to consumer 2 1 4 3 2 6 5 Consumer 1 p q 4 1 2 Discrimination: Set price of package with one unit = 3 Price of package with two units = 5 Profits = $8 Alternative 1: two units for both: $10 Alternative 2: exclude consumer 2: $6 Consumer 2 p q 3 1 2 ECO 171

Example 2 – Exclude consumer 2 Size of package Value to consumer 1 Value to consumer 2 1 5 2 8 3 Consumer 1 p q 5 1 3 2 Discrimination: Set price of package with one unit = 2 Price of package with two units = 5 Profits = $7 Alternative 1: two units for both: $6 Alternative 2: exclude consumer 2: $8 Consumer 2 p q 2 1 ECO 171

Examples – conclusions Too discriminate, need to offer different alternatives. Consumers must self-select. This is done by “damaging” the alternative for low paying consumers: lower quantity Then offer a price for small package and price for large package. Cost: inefficient consumption of L type (deadweight loss) Gain: Extract more CS from high type When differences in willingness to pay are high, it pays to restrict quantity to L type. Leave no CS to L type: Charge the highest possible price This way get more from the L type and lower the CS of high type. ECO 171

Optimal exclusion of L type q p1 p2 Gain from including L type (1) Change in CS of high type (2) Example 1 1 5 4 2 3 Example 2 Example 3 Net: (1)-(2) 3 -1 2 not exclude exclude not exclude not exclude exclude exclude ECO 171

With continuous demand functions Sell 2 units to type L Set price for this two units equal to total surplus = area under demand = 2*2/2=2 What can offer to H type? Quantity = 4 Charge: ? Profits = 2 NL + 4 Nh e.g. if NL = Nh =N, profits = 6N Ph = 4 – Qh PL = 2 – QL MC = 0 ECO 171

Any better deal? Sell 1 units to type L Set price for this unit equal to total surplus = area under demand = (2+1)/2 x 1 = 3/2 What can offer to H type? Quantity = 4 CSh under L-plan = 2 Maximum charge: 8-2=6 Profits = 3/2 NL + 6 Nh e.g. NL = Nh = N, profit = 7 ½ N Ph = 4 – Qh PL = 2 – QL MC = 0 ECO 171

Optimal quantity Effect of a small decrease in qL Loss from excluding L type: NL x DqL x pL D CSh = Nh x DqL x (ph – pL ) Net gain DqL [ Nh x (ph – pL ) - NL x pL ] If Nh=NL this is positive if ph-pL>pL. Optimal quantity qL: cut quantity until Nh x (ph – pL ) = NL x pL Note: if marginal cost is positive, until Nh x (ph – pL ) = NL x (pL – mc ) DqL ECO 171

Optimal quantity (continued) In previous example, assuming Nh = NL ph = 4-q, pL= 2-q Condition is: (4-q – (2-q)) = 2-q  q=0! Best is to exclude completely type L. Suppose NL = 2 x Nh 2 = 2 x (2-q) q=1 Optimal quantity increases as NL / Nh increases Intuition: losses from excluding L are proportional to L and gain from more surplus extraction from h are proportional to Nh . ECO 171

Optimal packages In previous example with NL = 2 Nh qL = 1 Charge L: $ 0.5 (their total surplus) qh = 4 (always quantity is efficient for h type) Charge h: Total surplus minus utility under L plan = 8-2 = 6 Total profits: 0.5 x NL + 6 x Nh ECO 171

Optimal packages – general case Set qL so that Nh x (ph-pL) = NL x (pL- mc) Charge L-type their entire surplus (area under demand curve up to qL ) = Set qh at the efficient level: p(qh) = mc Charge H-type their entire surplus minus the utility they get under L-plan = ECO 171

Optimal packages – general principles Characteristics of second-degree price discrimination extract all consumer surplus from the lowest-demand group leave some consumer surplus for other groups the self-selection (also called incentive-compatibility) constraint. offer less than the socially efficient quantity to all groups other than the highest-demand group offer quantity-discounting Second-degree price discrimination converts consumer surplus into profit less effectively than first-degree Some consumer surplus is left “on the table” in order to induce high-demand groups to buy large quantities. Fundamental tradeoff – restricting output to lower types to increase surplus extracted from higher types. The higher the cost of this distortion or lower the added surplus extracted, the higher qL will be. It may be optimal to exclude L types. ECO 171

Generalization to many consumer types Total price F1 F2 Optimal price schedule Total price schedule is concave Derivative interpreted as marginal price, i.e price for the last unit. Can approximate by offering these two plans: T1 (q) = F1 + p1 × q T2 (q) = F2 + p2 × q Total quantity ECO 171

Non-linear pricing and welfare Non-linear price discrimination raises profit Does it increase social welfare? suppose that inverse demand of consumer group i is P = Pi(Q) marginal cost is constant at MC – c suppose quantity offered to consumer group i is Qi total surplus – consumer surplus plus profit –is the area between the inverse demand and marginal cost up to quantity Qi Price Demand Total Surplus c MC Qi Qi(c) Quantity ECO 171

Non-linear pricing and welfare 2 Pricing policy affects distribution of surplus output of the firm First is welfare neutral Second affects welfare Does it increase social welfare? Price discrimination increases social welfare of group i if it increases quantity supplied to group i Price Quantity Demand c MC Qi Qi(c) Total Surplus Q’i ECO 171

Non-linear pricing and welfare 2 First-degree price discrimination always increases social welfare extracts all consumer surplus but generates socially optimal output output to group i is Qi(c) this exceeds output with uniform (non-discriminatory) pricing Price Quantity Demand c MC Qi Qi(c) Total Surplus ECO 171

Non-linear pricing and welfare 3 Menu pricing is less straightforward suppose that there are two markets low demand high demand Low demand offered less than the socially optimal quantity Price PU L MC Uniform price is PU Qls QlU Quantity Price Menu pricing gives quantities Q1s, Q2s High demand offered the socially optimal quantity Welfare loss is greater than L Welfare gain is less than G PU G MC QhU Qhs Quantity ECO 171

Non-linear pricing and welfare 4 Price Quantity MC PU QlU QhU Qls Qhs L G It follows that ΔW < G – L = (PU – MC)ΔQ1 + (PU – MC)ΔQ2 = (PU – MC)(ΔQ1 + ΔQ2) A necessary condition for second-degree price discrimination to increase social welfare is that it increases total output “Like” third-degree price discrimination But second-degree price discrimination is more likely to increase output ECO 171

The incentive compatibility constraint Any offer made to high demand consumers must offer them as much consumer surplus as they would get from an offer designed for low-demand consumers. This is a common phenomenon performance bonuses must encourage effort insurance policies need large deductibles to deter cheating piece rates in factories have to be accompanied by strict quality inspection encouragement to buy in bulk must offer a price discount ECO 171