Chapter 1: Two-Sector Models

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
4 Trade and Resources: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model 1 Heckscher-Ohlin
Advertisements

Trade and Factor Prices Factor Price Equalization.
Classic Trade Theory Ricardian Model - Technological Comparative Advantage: Basic 2 Good Ricardian model (Feenstra, Chapter 1) Continuum of Goods [Dornbush,
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Appendix 4.1 Alternate Proofs of Selected HO Theorems.
The Gains from Trade: A General Equilibrium View Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference–the one takes account of the.
2. Free Trade and Protection. Summary 1.Theory of Comparative Advantage: Why trade is good. 2.Where comparative advantage comes from: Heckscher-Ohlin.
Overview Introduction Setting up the Model Adding trade into the Model
Specific Factors and Income Distribution
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
Other Assumptions: two countries, two factors, two products; perfect competition in all markets; Free trade; Factors of production are available in fixed.
Lectures 4-5: The specific factors model
1 BA 187 – International Trade Specific Factors & Differential Gains from Trade.
The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Theorem
Differences in technology
The Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Shhhhh!!!! please Econ 355 Introduction  Ricardian: suggests all countries gain from trade: Moreover: every individual is better off  Trade has substantial.
The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Theorem
Chapter 3 Ricardian Model
Tools of Analysis for International Trade Models
Robinson Crusoe model 1 consumer & 1 producer & 2 goods & 1 factor: –two price-taking economic agents –two goods: the labor (or leisure x 1 ) of the consumer.
Tools of Analysis for International Trade Models
Factor Endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theory
The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Udayan Roy October 2009.
1 HO Model – Factor Proportions INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, ECO 486 Bertil Ohlin Eli F. Heckscher,
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
Prof. Dr. Volker Clausen Universität Duisburg-Essen Campus Essen 1 Ricardo, David (1817): On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London.
EC 355 International Economics and Finance
Trade: Factor Availability and Factor Proportions Are Key
© 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 4 Technology and International Income Distribution: The Ricardian Model.
New Classical Theories of International Trade
NEOCLASSICAL TRADE THEORY
Unit 1: Trade Theory Heckscher-Ohlin Model 2/3/2012.
Chapter 2 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model International Economics: Theory and Policy International Economics: Theory.
Gießen, Chapter 4: Increasing returns to scale 4.1 Empirical observations 4.2 Homogeneous products External economies of scale Contestable.
Supplementary notes Chapter 4.
Gießen, Differentiated products Vertical differentiation: different qualities Horizontal differentiation: equal qualities, but consumers.
Chapter 4 Factor Endowments and Hecksher-Ohlin Yanan University Finance and Economics Dep. Aihong Qin.
Note sparse e grafici sul modello di Heckscher e Ohlin Luca De Benedictis.
Ricardian Model A lesson in Comparative Advantage.
1 Chapter 3 -- Classical Model INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, ECO 486 Display your name card.
University of Papua New Guinea International Economics Lecture 6: Trade Models III – The Heckscher-Ohlin Model.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 The Heckscher- Ohlin Model.
4 1 Heckscher-Ohlin Model 2 Effects of Trade on Factor Prices 3
Trade and Resources The Heckscher-Ohlin model Dr. Petre Badulescu.
University of Papua New Guinea International Economics Lecture 12 - Revision Lecture: Trade Models.
Comparative Advantage and the Ricardian Model
International Economics
Factor endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin theory
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 9th Edition
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE
Study Unit 4.
Factor Endowments Theory and Heckscher-Ohlin Model
International Economics Tenth Edition
Chapter 3: Many Goods and Factors
The Production Possibility Frontier (Fixed Proportions)
International Trade and Economic Growth
Chapter 4 Resources and Trade:The Heckscher-Ohlin Model.
International Economics: Theory and Policy, Sixth Edition
Production Possibilities Schedules
Production Possibilities Schedules
Chapter 5: Factor Endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theory
Chapter 2: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 7th Edition
Chapter 2 Inter-Industry Trade Inter-industry trade Inter-firm trade.
The Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 1: Two-Sector Models Different Technologies: Ricardo Different Factor Endowments: Heckscher-Ohlin Assumptions: Factors: Immobile between countries, perfectly mobile between sectors. Goods: Perfectly mobile between countries. Identical homothetic utility functions relative quantities of consumption goods depend only on relative prices, not on income (distribution).

Topics of chapter 1 Ricardian model Equilibrium – factor prices Gains from trade Heckscher Ohlin model Equilibrium – factor price equalization Comparative Statics: Change in product prices Change in factor endowments Factor intensity reversals

1.1 Ricardian model 2 goods, 1 factor of production (labor). Notation: yi…domestically produced quantity of good i, i=1,2 ai…labor needed per unit of good i, ai= Li/yi. L…domestic labor force. A * refers to the foreign country, hence L*…labor force of the foreign country. Production function: yi = Li/ai,  marginal product of labor = 1/ai.

Equilibrium in autarky: Both goods are produced only if wage w is the same in both sectors. In equilibrium wage equals value of marginal product, hence w = p1/a1 = p2/a2. Using good 2 as numeraire we get in equilibrium p = p1/p2 = a1/a2. The domestic country has a comparative advantage in producing good 1 if pa < pa*  a1/a2 < a*1/a*2

Figure 1.1 Equilibria in Autarky

Free trade equilibrium: Relative demand d = d1/d2 is a decreasing function of (world market) price p. Relative supply y = (y1 + y*1)/(y2 + y*2) is an increasing step function of p: p < pa  y1 = 0 [y2 = L/a2, y*2 = L*/a*2]. pa* > p > pa  y2 = 0, y1 = L/a1, y*2 = L*/a*2. p > pa*  y1 = L/a1, y*1 = L*/a*1. If the equilibrium price with free trade is strictly between the autarky prices then there is complete specialization in both countries and both countries gain from trade.

Trade patterns (and gains from trade) are determined by comparative advantage. Absolute advantage matters for income determination: Suppose the domestic country has an absolute disadvantage in the production of both goods, i.e. a*1 < a1, a*2 < a2. w = p/a1 < p/a*1 < 1/ a*2 = w*.

Figure 1.2 Trade Equilibrium

Figure 1. 1a: Gains from trade of home country: let pa < p < pa Figure 1.1a: Gains from trade of home country: let pa < p < pa*, compete specialization (production at point B, consumption at point above indifference through A (production = consumption in autarky))

1.2 Two-Goods, Two-Factors Model “Small Country“ Assumption: World market prices exogenous. Two factors of production, capital K and labor L. Production functions: concave and increasing in L and K, homogeneous of degree one (constant returns to scale): yi = fi(Li,Ki), L1 + L2  L K1 + K2  K.

Production possibility frontier (PPF): Maximum value function of the optimization problem: max y2 = f2(L2,K2) s.t. y1 = f1(L1,K1) = y, L1 + L2  L, K1 + K2  K. Denote the solution as h(y1,L,K). h(…) is decreasing and concave in y1. Gross domestic product (GDP) function: G(p1,p2,L,K) = max p1y1 + p2y2 s.t y2 = h(y1,L,K).

This is equivalent to max G(y1) = p1y1 + p2h(y1,L,K), implying the FOC p1 + p2[h/y1] = 0 or p = p1/p2 = -h/y1 = -y2/y1, i.e. in the optimum the price ratio equals the slope of the PPF. By the envelope theorem we get G/pi = yi.

Equilibrium Conditions Unit cost functions: ci(w,r) = min wLi + rKi s.t. fi(Li,Ki)  1, Li,Ki  0. ci(w,r) is non-decreasing and concave in w and r. Denoting the optimal input-coefficients for labor and capital as aiL and aiK, it can be written as ci(w,r) = waiL + raiK. By the envelope theorem we get ci/w = aiL, ci/r = aiK.

Two sets of equilibrium conditions: 1. Zero-profit condition: p1 = c1(w,r) (E1) p2 = c2(w,r) (E2) 2. Full-employment condition: a1Ly1 + a2Ly2 = L, (E3) a1Ky1 + a2Ky2 = K. (E4)

Figure 1.3 Production Possibility Frontier

Factor prices Lemma: So long as both goods are produced and factor intensity reversals do not occur, then each price vector (p1, p2) corresponds to unique factor prices (w,r). Factor intensity reversals:  s such that a1K/a1L > a2K/a2L for r/w > s and a1K/a1L < a2K/a2L for r/w < s. Equilibrium conditions (E1,E2) have more than one intersection in (r,w)-space: total differential of zero-profit condition: 0 = aiLdw + aiKdr  dr/dw = -aiL/aiK.

Figure 1.4 Factor Price Insensitivity

Figure 1.5 Factor Intensity Reversal

Factor Price Equalization Theorem (Samuelson) 2 countries, two goods, both countries produce both goods in a free trade equilibrium, identical technologies, different factor endowments, no factor intensity reversals (FIRs)  factor prices (w,r) are equalized across countries. Proof: Figure 1.4 is the same for both countries  same equilibrium prices in both countries imply identical factor prices.

Stolper-Samuelson Theorem An increase in the relative price of a good will increase the real return to the factor used intensively in that good, and reduce the real return to the other factor. Proof: Let p = p1/p2,  = w/r. From the equilibrium conditions we get p = [a1L + a1K]/[a2L + a2K] implying

Rybczynski Theorem An increase in a factor endowment will increase the output of the industry using it intensively, and decrease the output of the other industry. Proof: Factor market clearing implies L = y1a1L + y2a2L K = y1a1K + y2a2K Define k  K/L und y  y2/y1, hence k = [a1K + ya2K]/[a1L + ya2L] implying

Interpretation: There is a unique relationship between relative factor endowments and relative outputs, the share of the capital intensive good increases when the capital endowment is increased. With identical homothetic preferences this implies that the capital intensive good must be relatively cheaper in the capital rich country. Absolute changes: totally differentiating the market clearing conditions yields: dL = a1Ldy1 + a2Ldy2 dK = a1Kdy1 + a2Kdy2

By Cramer‘s rule we get dy1 = [a2KdL - a2LdK]/[a1La2K - a2La1K] dy2 = [a1LdK - a1KdL]/[a1La2K - a2La1K] From the first equation follows dy1/dL  0  a1La2K - a2La1K  0  a1L/a1K  a2L/a2K Interpretation: An increase in the labor endowment induces an increase in the output of good 1 if and only if its production is more labor intensive than the production of good 2. Empirical Example: „Dutch disease“: discovery of oil moved resources away from less oil intensive export industries.

Alternative Illustration of the Rybczynski Theorem Recall the full employment conditions: L = y1a1L + y2a2L K = y1a1K + y2a2K Multiplying the vectors (a1L,a1K) and (a2L,a2K) by y1 and y2 respectively and summing them up yields the total vector endowments (L,K). Conversely, for each factor endowment (L,K) and vectors (aiL,aiK) there exist outputs yi, i=1,2 s.t. the factor markets are cleared. Figure 1.6 shows that outputs are positive iff endowment vector lies between factor requirement vectors.

Figure 1.6: Cone of diversification

Suppose next that L is increased to L‘. From Figure 1 Suppose next that L is increased to L‘. From Figure 1.7 it can be seen that full employment of factors can only be maintained if the quantity of the capital intensive good 2 is reduced and that of the labor intensive good 1 is increased.

Figure 1.7: Increase of Labor Endowment

Rybczynski line: As L (or K) is increased the PPF is shifted out. The Rybczynski line connects all equilibrium points for K (L) constant and L (K) changed. Its slope is obtained as follows: K = y1a1K + y2a2K a1Kdy1 + a2Kdy2 = 0  dy2/dy1 = -a1K/a2K< 0. (See Figure 1.8).

Figure 1.8: Rybczynski line

Integrated World Equilibrium Thought experiment: Consider a world with perfect mobility of all factors. Compute its equilibrium (Integrated World Equilibrium). How could factor endowments be distributed between two countries between which there is no factor mobility such that the IWE would be reproduced as a free trade equilibrium? Figure 1.9 shows the set of all such factor endowments (0A10*A2:  y,y* s.t. sum of input vectors equals world factor endowment).

Figure 1.9: Factor Price Equalization Set