LECTURE 2 MIXED STRATEGY GAME

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Mixed Strategies.
Advertisements

Game Theory Lecture 4 Game Theory Lecture 4.
Nash Equilibrium: Illustrations
This Segment: Computational game theory Lecture 1: Game representations, solution concepts and complexity Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science Department Carnegie.
Mixed Strategies CMPT 882 Computational Game Theory Simon Fraser University Spring 2010 Instructor: Oliver Schulte.
Stackelberg -leader/follower game 2 firms choose quantities sequentially (1) chooses its output; then (2) chooses it output; then the market clears This.
Mixed Strategies For Managers
Introduction to Game theory Presented by: George Fortetsanakis.
Simultaneous- Move Games with Mixed Strategies Zero-sum Games.
Game Theory “I Used to Think I Was Indecisive - But Now I’m Not So Sure” - Anonymous Mike Shor Lecture 5.
ECO290E: Game Theory Lecture 5 Mixed Strategy Equilibrium.
Eponine Lupo.  Questions from last time  3 player games  Games larger than 2x2—rock, paper, scissors  Review/explain Nash Equilibrium  Nash Equilibrium.
MIT and James Orlin © Game Theory 2-person 0-sum (or constant sum) game theory 2-person game theory (e.g., prisoner’s dilemma)
EC3224 Autumn Lecture #04 Mixed-Strategy Equilibrium
Lectures 7&8 Revisit Elections Now range is left-wing or right-wing politics. Candidate-Voter model Assume even distribution of voters. Voters will vote.
An Introduction to Game Theory Part I: Strategic Games
Chapter 6 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Game Theory.
Nash Equilibrium: Theory. Strategic or Simultaneous-move Games Definition: A simultaneous-move game consists of: A set of players For each player, a set.
1 Business System Analysis & Decision Making - Lecture 5 Zhangxi Lin ISQS 5340 July 2006.
EC102: Class 9 Christina Ammon.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
An Introduction to Game Theory Part II: Mixed and Correlated Strategies Bernhard Nebel.
Games of pure conflict two person constant sum. Two-person constant sum game Sometimes called zero-sum game. The sum of the players’ payoffs is the same,
Static Games of Complete Information: Equilibrium Concepts
Game theory The study of multiperson decisions Four types of games
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Review Midterm3/19 3/12.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Bargaining and Negotiation Review.
Nash Equilibrium - definition A mixed-strategy profile σ * is a Nash equilibrium (NE) if for every player i we have u i (σ * i, σ * -i ) ≥ u i (s i, σ.
EC941 - Game Theory Francesco Squintani Lecture 3 1.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Review Midterm3/23 3/9.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Bargaining and Negotiation Review.
Two-Stage Games APEC 8205: Applied Game Theory Fall 2007.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Bargaining and Negotiation Review.
Week 4 Nash Equilibrium and Strategic Uncertainty In some games even iterative dominance does not help us predict what strategies players might choose.
Game Theory “I used to think I was indecisive – but now I’m not so sure.” - Anonymous Topic 4 Mixed Strategies.
Minimax strategies, Nash equilibria, correlated equilibria Vincent Conitzer
Assoc. Prof. Yeşim Kuştepeli1 GAME THEORY AND APPLICATIONS UNCERTAINTY AND EXPECTED UTILITY.
© 2009 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Lecture Note II-3 Static Games of Incomplete Information Static Bayesian Game.
EC941 - Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Lecture 5 1.
The Science of Networks 6.1 Today’s topics Game Theory Normal-form games Dominating strategies Nash equilibria Acknowledgements Vincent Conitzer, Michael.
Lecture 5A Mixed Strategies and Multiplicity Not every game has a pure strategy Nash equilibrium, and some games have more than one. This lecture shows.
3.1.4 Types of Games. Strategic Behavior in Business and Econ Outline 3.1. What is a Game ? The elements of a Game The Rules of the Game:
Lecture 5 Introduction to Game theory. What is game theory? Game theory studies situations where players have strategic interactions; the payoff that.
Mixed Strategies and Repeated Games
Strategic Behavior in Business and Econ Static Games of complete information: Dominant Strategies and Nash Equilibrium in pure and mixed strategies.
1. 2 You should know by now… u The security level of a strategy for a player is the minimum payoff regardless of what strategy his opponent uses. u A.
5.1.Static Games of Incomplete Information
Topics to be Discussed Gaming and Strategic Decisions
Games of pure conflict two-person constant sum games.
9.2 Mixed Strategy Games In this section, we look at non-strictly determined games. For these type of games the payoff matrix has no saddle points.
By: Donté Howell Game Theory in Sports. What is Game Theory? It is a tool used to analyze strategic behavior and trying to maximize his/her payoff of.
Chapter 12 Game Theory Presented by Nahakpam PhD Student 1Game Theory.
Working Some Problems.
Game theory basics A Game describes situations of strategic interaction, where the payoff for one agent depends on its own actions as well as on the actions.
Q 2.1 Nash Equilibrium Ben
Mixed Strategies Keep ‘em guessing.
Nash Equilibrium: Theory
The Duality Theorem Primal P: Maximize
Simultaneous-Move Games: Mixed Strategies
Simultaneous Move Games: Discrete Strategies
CPS 570: Artificial Intelligence Game Theory
Games of pure conflict two person constant sum
Econ 805 Advanced Micro Theory 1
Game Theory Fall Mike Shor Topic 3.
Combining Sequential and Simultaneous Moves
THE ECONOMY: THE CORE PROJECT
Game Theory in Wireless and Communication Networks: Theory, Models, and Applications Lecture 2 Bayesian Games Zhu Han, Dusit Niyato, Walid Saad, Tamer.
Game Theory Chapter 12.
Lecture 20 Linear Program Duality
UNIT II: The Basic Theory
Presentation transcript:

LECTURE 2 MIXED STRATEGY GAME May 19, 2003 LECTURE 2 MIXED STRATEGY GAME Notes modified from Yongqin Wang @ Fudan University

Matching pennies Hence, NO Nash equilibrium -1 , 1 1 , -1 Player 1 Player 2 Tail Head -1 , 1 1 , -1 Head is Player 1’s best response to Player 2’s strategy Tail Tail is Player 2’s best response to Player 1’s strategy Tail Tail is Player 1’s best response to Player 2’s strategy Head Head is Player 2’s best response to Player 1’s strategy Head Hence, NO Nash equilibrium

Solving matching pennies Player 2 Head Tail Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 q 1-q r 1-r Randomize your strategies Player 1 chooses Head and Tail with probabilities r and 1-r, respectively. Player 2 chooses Head and Tail with probabilities q and 1-q, respectively. Mixed Strategy: Specifies that an actual move be chosen randomly from the set of pure strategies with some specific probabilities.

Mixed strategy A mixed strategy of a player is a probability distribution over player’s (pure) strategies. A mixed strategy for Chris is a probability distribution (p, 1-p), where p is the probability of playing Opera, and 1-p is that probability of playing Prize Fight. If p=1 then Chris actually plays Opera. If p=0 then Chris actually plays Prize Fight. Battle of sexes Pat Opera Prize Fight Chris Opera (p) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-p) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Solving matching pennies Player 2 Head Tail Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Expected payoffs r 1-2q 1-r 2q-1 q 1-q Player 1’s expected payoffs If Player 1 chooses Head, -q+(1-q)=1-2q If Player 1 chooses Tail, q-(1-q)=2q-1

Solving matching pennies Player 2 Head Tail Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Expected payoffs r 1-2q 1-r 2q-1 q 1-q 1 q r 1/2 Player 1’s best response B1(q): For q<0.5, Head (r=1) For q>0.5, Tail (r=0) For q=0.5, indifferent (0r1)

Solving matching pennies Player 2 Head Tail Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Expected payoffs r 1-2q 1-r 2q-1 q 1-q Expected payoffs 2r-1 1-2r Player 2’s expected payoffs If Player 2 chooses Head, r-(1-r)=2r-1 If Player 2 chooses Tail, -r+(1-r)=1-2r

Solving matching pennies Player 2 Head Tail Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 1-2q 2q-1 Expected payoffs r 1-r q 1-q Expected payoffs 2r-1 1-2r 1 q r 1/2 Player 2’s best response B2(r): For r<0.5, Tail (q=0) For r>0.5, Head (q=1) For r=0.5, indifferent (0q1)

Solving matching pennies Player 2 Head Tail Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Player 1’s best response B1(q): For q<0.5, Head (r=1) For q>0.5, Tail (r=0) For q=0.5, indifferent (0r1) Player 2’s best response B2(r): For r<0.5, Tail (q=0) For r>0.5, Head (q=1) For r=0.5, indifferent (0q1) Check r = 0.5  B1(0.5) q = 0.5  B2(0.5) r 1-r q 1-q Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium 1 q r 1/2

Mixed strategy: example Matching pennies Player 1 has two pure strategies: H and T ( 1(H)=0.5, 1(T)=0.5 ) is a Mixed strategy. That is, player 1 plays H and T with probabilities 0.5 and 0.5, respectively. ( 1(H)=0.3, 1(T)=0.7 ) is another Mixed strategy. That is, player 1 plays H and T with probabilities 0.3 and 0.7, respectively.

Mixed strategy: example Player 2 L (0) C (1/3) R (2/3) Player 1 T (3/4) 0 , 2 3 , 3 1 , 1 M (0) 4 , 0 0 , 4 2 , 3 B (1/4) 3 , 4 5 , 1 0 , 7 Player 1: (3/4, 0, ¼) is a mixed strategy. That is, 1(T)=3/4, 1(M)=0 and 1(B)=1/4. Player 2: (0, 1/3, 2/3) is a mixed strategy. That is, 2(L)=0, 2(C)=1/3 and 2(R)=2/3.

Expected payoffs: 2 players each with two pure strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Player 1 plays a mixed strategy (r, 1- r ). Player 2 plays a mixed strategy ( q, 1- q ). Player 1’s expected payoff of playing s11: EU1(s11, (q, 1-q))=q×u1(s11, s21)+(1-q)×u1(s11, s22) Player 1’s expected payoff of playing s12: EU1(s12, (q, 1-q))= q×u1(s12, s21)+(1-q)×u1(s12, s22) Player 1’s expected payoff from her mixed strategy: v1((r, 1-r), (q, 1-q))=rEU1(s11, (q, 1-q))+(1-r)EU1(s12, (q, 1-q))

Expected payoffs: 2 players each with two pure strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Player 1 plays a mixed strategy (r, 1- r ). Player 2 plays a mixed strategy ( q, 1- q ). Player 2’s expected payoff of playing s21: EU2(s21, (r, 1-r))=r×u2(s11, s21)+(1-r)×u2(s12, s21) Player 2’s expected payoff of playing s22: EU2(s22, (r, 1-r))= r×u2(s11, s22)+(1-r)×u2(s12, s22) Player 2’s expected payoff from her mixed strategy: v2((r, 1-r),(q, 1-q))=qEU2(s21, (r, 1-r))+(1-q)EU2(s22, (r, 1-r))

Expected payoffs: example Player 2 H (0.3) T (0.7) Player 1 H (0.4) -1 , 1 1 , -1 T (0.6) Player 1: EU1(H, (0.3, 0.7)) = 0.3×(-1) + 0.7×1=0.4 EU1(T, (0.3, 0.7)) = 0.3×1 + 0.7×(-1)=-0.4 v1((0.4, 0.6), (0.3, 0.7))=0.40.4+0.6(-0.4)=-0.08 Player 2: EU2(H, (0.4, 0.6)) = 0.4×1+0.6×(-1) = -0.2 EU2(T, (0.4, 0.6)) = 0.4×(-1)+0.6×1 = 0.2 v2((0.4, 0.6), (0.3, 0.7))=0.3×(-0.2)+0.7×0.2=0.08

Expected payoffs: example Player 2 L (0) C (1/3) R (2/3) Player 1 T (3/4) 0 , 2 3 , 3 1 , 1 M (0) 4 , 0 0 , 4 2 , 3 B (1/4) 3 , 4 5 , 1 0 , 7 Mixed strategies: p1=( 3/4, 0, ¼ ); p2=( 0, 1/3, 2/3 ). Player 1: EU1(T, p2)=3(1/3)+1(2/3)=5/3, EU1(M, p2)=0(1/3)+2(2/3)=4/3 EU1(B, p2)=5(1/3)+0(2/3)=5/3. v1(p1, p2) = 5/3 Player 2: EU2(L, p1)=2(3/4)+4(1/4)=5/2, EU2(C, p1)=3(3/4)+3(1/4)=5/2, EU2(R, p1)=1(3/4)+7(1/4)=5/2. v1(p1, p2) = 5/2

Mixed strategy equilibrium A probability distribution for each player The distributions are mutual best responses to one another in the sense of expected payoffs It is a stochastic steady state

Mixed strategy vs. Correlated strategy

Mixed strategy equilibrium: 2-player each with two pure strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: A pair of mixed strategies ((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*)) is a Nash equilibrium if (r*,1-r*) is a best response to (q*, 1-q*), and (q*, 1-q*) is a best response to (r*,1-r*). That is, v1((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  v1((r, 1-r), (q*, 1-q*)), for all 0 r 1 v2((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  v2((r*, 1-r*), (q, 1-q)), for all 0 q 1

Find mixed strategy equilibrium in 2-player each with two pure strategies Find the best response correspondence for player 1, given player 2’s mixed strategy Find the best response correspondence for player 2, given player 1’s mixed strategy Use the best response correspondences to determine mixed strategy Nash equilibria.

Employee Monitoring Employees can work hard or shirk Salary: $100K unless caught shirking Cost of effort: $50K Managers can monitor or not Value of employee output: $200K Profit if employee doesn’t work: $0 Cost of monitoring: $10K

Employee Monitoring Employee’s best response B1(q): 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (r=0) if q<0.5 Work (r=1) if q>0.5 Any mixed strategy (0r1) if q=0.5 Expected payoffs 50 100(1-q) Expected payoffs 100r-10 200r-100 Manager Monitor ( q ) Not Monitor (1-q) Employee Work ( r ) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (1-r ) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Employee Monitoring Manager’s best response B2(r): 50 , 90 50 , 100 Monitor (q=1) if r<0.9 Not Monitor (q=0) if r>0.9 Any mixed strategy (0q1) if r=0.9 Expected payoffs 50 100(1-q) Expected payoffs 100r-10 200r-100 Manager Monitor ( q ) Not Monitor (1-q) Employee Work ( r ) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (1-r ) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Employee Monitoring r q Employee’s best response B1(q): Shirk (r=0) if q<0.5 Work (r=1) if q>0.5 Any mixed strategy (0r1) if q=0.5 Manager’s best response B2(r): Monitor (q=1) if r<0.9 Not Monitor (q=0) if r>0.9 Any mixed strategy (0q1) if r=0.9 Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium ((0.9,0.1),(0.5,0.5)) 1 q r 0.5 0.9

Battle of sexes Chris’ expected payoff of playing Opera: 2q Chris’ expected payoff of playing Prize Fight: 1-q Chris’ best response B1(q): Prize Fight (r=0) if q<1/3 Opera (r=1) if q>1/3 Any mixed strategy (0r1) if q=1/3 Pat Opera (q) Prize Fight (1-q) Chris Opera ( r ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-r) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Battle of sexes Pat’s expected payoff of playing Opera: r Pat’s expected payoff of playing Prize Fight: 2(1-r) Pat’s best response B2(r): Prize Fight (q=0) if r<2/3 Opera (q=1) if r>2/3 Any mixed strategy (0q1) if r=2/3, Pat Opera (q) Prize Fight (1-q) Chris Opera ( r ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-r) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Battle of sexes Chris’ best response B1(q): Pat’s best response B2(r): Prize Fight (r=0) if q<1/3 Opera (r=1) if q>1/3 Any mixed strategy (0r1) if q=1/3 Pat’s best response B2(r): Prize Fight (q=0) if r<2/3 Opera (q=1) if r>2/3 Any mixed strategy (0q1) if r=2/3 Three Nash equilibria: ((1, 0), (1, 0)) ((0, 1), (0, 1)) ((2/3, 1/3), (1/3, 2/3)) 1 q r 2/3 1/3

Battle of sexes The limitation of best-response approach Can only deal with simple games Comments of mixed strategies Randomization vNM expected utility Choice under uncertainty

2-player each with two strategies Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 2-player each with two strategies Player 2 s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Theorem 1 (property of mixed Nash equilibrium) A pair of mixed strategies ((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*)) is a Nash equilibrium if and only if v1((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  EU1(s11, (q*, 1-q*)) v1((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  EU1(s12, (q*, 1-q*)) v2((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  EU2(s21, (r*, 1-r*)) v2((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  EU2(s22, (r*, 1-r*))

Expected payoffs: 2 players each with two pure strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Player 1 plays a mixed strategy (r, 1- r ). Player 2 plays a mixed strategy ( q, 1- q ). Player 1’s expected payoff of playing s11: EU1(s11, (q, 1-q))=q×u1(s11, s21)+(1-q)×u1(s11, s22) Player 1’s expected payoff of playing s12: EU1(s12, (q, 1-q))= q×u1(s12, s21)+(1-q)×u1(s12, s22) Player 1’s expected payoff from her mixed strategy: v1((r, 1-r), (q, 1-q))=rEU1(s11, (q, 1-q))+(1-r)EU1(s12, (q, 1-q))

Expected payoffs: 2 players each with two pure strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Player 1 plays a mixed strategy (r, 1- r ). Player 2 plays a mixed strategy ( q, 1- q ). Player 2’s expected payoff of playing s21: EU2(s21, (r, 1-r))=r×u2(s11, s21)+(1-r)×u2(s12, s21) Player 2’s expected payoff of playing s22: EU2(s22, (r, 1-r))= r×u2(s11, s22)+(1-r)×u2(s12, s22) Player 2’s expected payoff from her mixed strategy: v2((r, 1-r),(q, 1-q))=qEU2(s21, (r, 1-r))+(1-q)EU2(s22, (r, 1-r))

Theorem 1: illustration Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Theorem 1: illustration Matching pennies Player 2 H (0.5) T (0.5) Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Player 1: EU1(H, (0.5, 0.5)) = 0.5×(-1) + 0.5×1=0 EU1(T, (0.5, 0.5)) = 0.5×1 + 0.5×(-1)=0 v1((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5))=0.50+0.50=0 Player 2: EU2(H, (0.5, 0.5)) = 0.5×1+0.5×(-1) =0 EU2(T, (0.5, 0.5)) = 0.5×(-1)+0.5×1 = 0 v2((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5))=0.5×0+0.5×0=0

Theorem 1: illustration Matching pennies Player 2 H (0.5) T (0.5) Player 1 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Player 1: v1((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5))  EU1(H, (0.5, 0.5)) v1((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5))  EU1(T, (0.5, 0.5)) Player 2: v2((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5))  EU2(H, (0.5, 0.5)) v2((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5))  EU2(T, (0.5, 0.5)) Hence, ((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 1.

Theorem 1: illustration Employee’s expected payoff of playing “work” EU1(Work, (0.5, 0.5)) = 0.5×50 + 0.5×50=50 Employee’s expected payoff of playing “shirk” EU1(Shirk, (0.5, 0.5)) = 0.5×0 + 0.5×100=50 Employee’s expected payoff of her mixed strategy v1((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5))=0.950+0.150=50 Employee Monitoring Manager Monitor (0.5) Not Monitor (0.5) Employee Work (0.9) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (0.1) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Theorem 1: illustration Manager’s expected payoff of playing “Monitor” EU2(Monitor, (0.9, 0.1)) = 0.9×90+0.1×(-10) =80 Manager’s expected payoff of playing “Not” EU2(Not, (0.9, 0.1)) = 0.9×100+0.1×(-100) = 80 Manager’s expected payoff of her mixed strategy v2((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5))=0.5×80+0.5×80=80 Employee Monitoring Manager Monitor (0.5) Not Monitor (0.5) Employee Work (0.9) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (0.1) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Theorem 1: illustration Employee v1((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5))  EU1(Work, (0.5, 0.5)) v1((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5))  EU1(Shirk, (0.5, 0.5)) Manager v2((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5))  EU2(Monitor, (0.9, 0.1)) v2((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5))  EU2(Not, (0.9, 0.1)) Hence, ((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 1. Employee Monitoring Manager Monitor (0.5) No Monitor (0.5) Employee Work (0.9) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (0.1) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Theorem 1: illustration Use Theorem 1 to check whether ((2/3, 1/3), (1/3, 2/3)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Battle of sexes Pat Opera (1/3) Prize Fight (2/3) Chris Opera (2/3 ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1/3) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Mixed strategy equilibrium: 2-player each with two strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Theorem 2 Let ((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*)) be a pair of mixed strategies, where 0 <r*<1, 0<q*<1. Then ((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if EU1(s11, (q*, 1-q*)) = EU1(s12, (q*, 1-q*)) EU2(s21, (r*, 1-r*)) = EU2(s22, (r*, 1-r*)) That is, each player is indifferent between her two strategies. Significance: it gives conditions for a mixed strategy NE in terms of each player’s expected payoffs only to her pure strategies

Use indifference to find mixed Nash equilibrium (2-player each with 2 strategies) Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibria Solve EU1(s11, (q*, 1-q*)) = EU1(s12, (q*, 1-q*)) Solve EU2(s21, (r*, 1-r*)) = EU2(s22, (r*, 1-r*))

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Matching pennies Player 2 H ( q ) T ( 1–q ) Player 1 H ( r ) -1 , 1 1 , -1 T ( 1–r ) Player 1 is indifferent between playing Head and Tail. EU1(H, (q, 1–q)) = q×(-1) + (1–q)×1=1–2q EU1(T, (q, 1–q)) = q×1 + ×(1–q) (-1)=2q–1 EU1(H, (q, 1–q)) = EU1(T, (q, 1–q)) 1–2q = 2q–1 4q = 2 This give us q = 1/2

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Matching pennies Player 2 H ( q ) T ( 1–q ) Player 1 H ( r ) -1 , 1 1 , -1 T ( 1–r ) Player 2 is indifferent between playing Head and Tail. EU2(H, (r, 1–r)) = r ×1+(1–r)×(-1) =2r – 1 EU2(T, (r, 1–r)) = r×(-1)+(1–r)×1 = 1 – 2r EU2(H, (r, 1–r)) = EU2(T, (r, 1–r)) 2r – 1= 1 – 2r 4r = 2 This give us r = 1/2 Hence, ((0.5, 0.5), (0.5, 0.5)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 2.

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Employee’s expected payoff of playing “work” EU1(Work, (q, 1–q)) = q×50 + (1–q)×50=50 Employee’s expected payoff of playing “shirk” EU1(Shirk, (q, 1–q)) = q×0 + (1–q)×100=100(1–q) Employee is indifferent between playing Work and Shirk. 50=100(1–q) q=1/2 Employee Monitoring Manager Monitor ( q ) Not Monitor (1–q ) Employee Work (r) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (1–r) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Manager’s expected payoff of playing “Monitor” EU2(Monitor, (r, 1–r)) = r×90+(1–r)×(-10) =100r–10 Manager’s expected payoff of playing “Not” EU2(Not, (r, 1–r)) = r×100+(1–r)×(-100) =200r–100 Manager is indifferent between playing Monitor and Not 100r–10 =200r–100 implies that r=0.9. Hence, ((0.9, 0.1), (0.5, 0.5)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 2. Employee Monitoring Manager Monitor ( q ) Not Monitor (1–q ) Employee Work (r) 50 , 90 50 , 100 Shirk (1–r) 0 , -10 100 , -100

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Use Theorem 2 to find a mixed Nash equilibrium Battle of sexes Pat Opera (q) Prize Fight (1-q) Chris Opera ( r ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-r) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Use Theorem 2 to find a mixed Nash equilibrium Example Player 2 L (q) R (1-q) Player 1 T ( r ) 6 , 4 2 , 6 B (1-r) 3 , 3 6 , 1

Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium A mixed strategy of a player is a probability distribution over the player’s strategies. Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium A probability distribution for each player The distributions are mutual best responses to one another in the sense of expected payoffs

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Chris’ expected payoff of playing Opera EU1(O, (q, 1–q)) = q×2 + (1–q)×0 = 2q Chris’ expected payoff of playing Prize Fight EU1(F, (q, 1–q)) = q×0 + (1–q)×1 = 1–q Chris is indifferent between playing Opera and Prize EU1(O, (q, 1–q)) = EU1(F, (q, 1–q)) 2q = 1–q 3q = 1 This give us q = 1/3 Battle of sexes Pat Opera (q) Prize Fight (1-q) Chris Opera ( r ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-r) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Pat’s expected payoff of playing Opera EU2(O, (r, 1–r)) = r ×1+(1–r)×0 = r Pat’s expected payoff of playing Prize Fight EU2(F, (r, 1–r)) = r×0+(1–r)×2 = 2 – 2r Pat is indifferent between playing Opera and Prize EU2(O, (r, 1–r)) = EU2(F, (r, 1–r)) r = 2 – 2r 3r = 2 This give us r = 2/3 Battle of sexes Pat Opera (q) Prize Fight (1-q) Chris Opera ( r ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-r) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Use Theorem 2 to find mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: illustration Hence, ( (2/3, 1/3), (1/3, 2/3) ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. That is, Chris chooses Opera with probability 2/3 and Prize Fight with probability 1/3. Pat chooses Opera with probability 1/3 and Prize Fight with probability 2/3. Battle of sexes Pat Opera (q) Prize Fight (1-q) Chris Opera ( r ) 2 , 1 0 , 0 Prize Fight (1-r) 0 , 0 1 , 2

Example 1 Bruce and Sheila determine whether to go to the opera or to a pro wrestling show. Sheila gets utility of 4 from going to the opera and 1 from pro wrestling. Bruce gets utility of 1 from going to the opera and 4 from pro wrestling. They agree to decide what to do in the following way: Bruce and Sheila each puts a penny below an issue of the TV guide on the coffee table (assume they don’t cheat by looking at the other). They count to 3 and simultaneously reveal which side of their penny is up. If the pennies match (both heads, or both tails), Sheila decides what to watch, while if the pennies don’t match (heads, tails or tails, heads) then Bruce decides.

Example 1 Bruce’s expected payoff of playing Head Sheila H ( q ) T ( 1–q ) Bruce H ( r ) 1 , 4 4 , 1 T ( 1–r ) Bruce’s expected payoff of playing Head EU1(H, (q, 1–q)) = q×1 + (1–q)×4 = 4–3q Bruce’s expected payoff of playing Tail EU1(T, (q, 1–q)) = q×4 + (1–q)×1 = 1+3q Bruce is indifferent between playing Head and Tail EU1(H, (q, 1–q)) = EU1(T, (q, 1–q)) 4–3q = 1+3q 6q = 3 This give us q = 1/2

Example 1 1 , 4 4 , 1 Sheila’s expected payoff of playing Head H ( q ) T ( 1–q ) Bruce H ( r ) 1 , 4 4 , 1 T ( 1–r ) Sheila’s expected payoff of playing Head EU2(H, (r, 1–r)) = r ×4+(1–r)×1 = 3r + 1 Sheila’s expected payoff of playing Tail EU2(T, (r, 1–r)) = r×1+(1–r)×4 = 4 – 3r Sheila is indifferent between playing Head and Tail EU2(H, (r, 1–r)) = EU2(T, (r, 1–r)) 3r + 1 = 4 – 3r 6r = 3 This give us r = ½ ( (1/2, 1/2), (1/2, 1/2) ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Example 2 Player 1’s expected payoff of playing T L ( q ) R ( 1–q ) Player 1 T ( r ) 6 , 0 0 , 6 B ( 1–r ) 3 , 2 Player 1’s expected payoff of playing T EU1(T, (q, 1–q)) = q×6 + (1–q)×0 = 6q Player 1’s expected payoff of playing B EU1(B, (q, 1–q)) = q×3 + (1–q)×6 = 6-3q Player 1 is indifferent between playing T and B EU1(T, (q, 1–q)) = EU1(B, (q, 1–q)) 6q = 6-3q 9q = 6 This give us q = 2/3

Example 2 6 , 0 0 , 6 3 , 2 Player 2’s expected payoff of playing L L ( q ) R ( 1–q ) Player 1 T ( r ) 6 , 0 0 , 6 B ( 1–r ) 3 , 2 Player 2’s expected payoff of playing L EU2(L, (r, 1–r)) = r ×0+(1–r)×2 =2- 2r Player 2’s expected payoff of playing R EU2(R, (r, 1–r)) = r×6+(1–r)×0 = 6r Player 2 is indifferent between playing L and R EU2(L, (r, 1–r)) = EU2(R, (r, 1–r)) 2- 2r = 6r 8r = 2 This gives us r = ¼ ( (1/4, 3/4), (2/3, 1/3) ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Example 3:Market entry game Two firms, Firm 1 and Firm 2, must decide whether to put one of their restaurants in a shopping mall simultaneously. Each has two strategies: Enter, Not Enter If either firm plays “Not Enter”, it earns 0 profit If one plays “Enter” and the other plays “Not Enter” then the firm plays “Enter” earns $500K If both plays “Enter” then both lose $100K because the demand is limited

Example 3:Market entry game Firm 2 Enter ( q ) Not Enter ( 1–q ) Firm 1 Enter ( r ) -100 , -100 500 , 0 Not Enter ( 1–r ) 0 , 500 0 , 0 How many Nash equilibria can you find? Two pure strategy Nash equilibrium (Not Enter, Enter) and (Enter, Not Enter) One mixed strategy Nash equilibrium ((5/6, 1/6), (5/6, 1/6)) That is r=5/6 and q=5/6

Example 4 How many Nash equilibria can you find? Player 2 L ( q ) R ( 1–q ) Player 1 T ( r ) 1 , 1 1 , 2 B ( 1–r ) 2 , 3 0 , 1 How many Nash equilibria can you find? Two pure strategy Nash equilibrium (B, L) and (T, R) One mixed strategy Nash equilibrium ((2/3, 1/3), (1/2, 1/2)) That is r=2/3 and q=1/2

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Each of two players simultaneously announces either Rock, or Paper, or Scissors. Paper beats (wraps) rock Rock beats (blunts) scissors Scissors beats (cuts) paper The player who names the winning object receives $1 from her opponent If both players name the same choice then no payment is made

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock Paper Scissors Player 1 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Can you guess a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium?

Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: 2-player each with two pure strategies s21 ( q ) s22 ( 1- q ) Player 1 s11 ( r ) u1(s11, s21), u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s22), u2(s11, s22) s12 (1- r ) u1(s12, s21), u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s22), u2(s12, s22) Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: A pair of mixed strategies ((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*)) is a Nash equilibrium if (r*,1-r*) is a best response to (q*, 1-q*), and (q*, 1-q*) is a best response to (r*,1-r*). That is, v1((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  v1((r, 1-r), (q*, 1-q*)), for all 0 r 1 v2((r*, 1-r*), (q*, 1-q*))  v2((r*, 1-r*), (q, 1-q)), for all 0 q 1

2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies Set of players: {Player 1, Player 2} Sets of strategies: player 1: S1= { s11, s12, ..., s1J } player 2: S2= { s21, s22, ..., s2K } Payoff functions: player 1: u1(s1j, s2k) player 2: u2(s1j, s2k) for j = 1, 2, ..., J and k = 1, 2, ..., K

2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies s21 (p21) s22 (p22) ....... s2K (p2K) s11 (p11) u2(s11, s21) u1(s11, s21) u2(s11, s22) u1(s11, s22) u2(s11, s2K) u1(s11, s2K) s12 (p12) u2(s12, s21) u1(s12, s21) u2(s12, s22) u1(s12, s22) u2(s12, s2K) u1(s12, s2K) .... ...... s1J (p1J) u2(s1J, s21) u1(s1J, s21) u2(s1J, s22) u1(s1J, s22) u2(s1J, s2K) u1(s1J, s2K) Player 1 Player 1’s mixed strategy: p1=(p11, p12, ..., p1J ) Player 2’s mixed strategy: p2=(p21, p22, ..., p2K )

Expected payoffs: 2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies Player 1’s expected payoff of pure strategy s11: EU1(s11, p2)=p21×u1(s11, s21)+p22×u1(s11, s22)+...+p2k×u1(s11, s2k)+...+p2K×u1(s11, s2K) Player 1’s expected payoff of pure strategy s12: EU1(s12, p2)=p21×u1(s12, s21)+p22×u1(s12, s22)+...+p2k×u1(s12, s2k)+...+p2K×u1(s12, s2K) ......... Player 1’s expected payoff of pure strategy s1J: EU1(s1J, p2)=p21×u1(s1J, s21)+p22×u1(s1J, s22)+...+p2k×u1(s1J, s2k)+...+p2K×u1(s1J, s2K) Player 1’s expected payoff from her mixed strategy p1: v1(p1, p2)=p11EU1(s11, p2)+p12EU1(s12, p2)+...+p1jEU1(s1j, p2)+... +p1JEU1(s1J, p2)

Expected payoffs: 2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies Player 2’s expected payoff of pure strategy s21: EU2(s21, p1)=p11×u2(s11, s21)+p12×u2(s12, s21)+...+p1j×u2(s1j, s21)+...+p1J×u2(s1J, s21) Player 2’s expected payoff of pure strategy s22: EU2(s22, p1)=p11×u2(s11, s22)+p12×u2(s12, s22)+...+p1j×u2(s1j, s22)+...+p1J×u2(s1J, s22) ........... Player 2’s expected payoff of pure strategy s2K: EU2(s2K, p1)=p11×u2(s11, s2K)+p12×u2(s12, s2K)+...+p1j×u2(s1j, s2K)+...+p1J×u2(s1J, s2K) Player 2’s expected payoff from her mixed strategy p2: v2(p1, p2)=p21EU2(s21, p1)+p22EU2(s22, p1) +...+p2kEU2(s2k, p1)+.... +p2KEU2(s2K, p1)

Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium: 2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies A pair of mixed strategies (p1*, p2*), where p1*=(p11*, p12*, ..., p1J* ) p2*=(p21*, p22*, ..., p2K* ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium if player 1’s mixed strategy p1* is a best response to player 2’s mixed strategy p2*, and p2* is a best response to p1*. Or, v1(p1*, p2*) v1(p1, p2*), for all player 1’s mixed strategy p1, and v2(p1*, p2*)  v2(p1*, p2), for all player 2’s mixed strategy p2. That is, given player 2’s mixed strategy p2*, player 1 cannot be better off if she deviates from p1*. Given player 1’s mixed strategy p1*, player 2 cannot be better off if she deviates from p2*.

2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies Theorem 3 (property of mixed Nash equilibrium) A pair of mixed strategies (p1*, p2*), where p1*=(p11*, p12*, ..., p1J* ) p2*=(p21*, p22*, ..., p2K* ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if v1(p1*, p2*)  EU1(s1j, p2*), for j = 1, 2, ..., J and v2(p1*, p2*)  EU2(s2k, p1*), for k= 1, 2, ..., K

2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies Theorem 4 A pair of mixed strategies (p1*, p2*), where p1*=(p11*, p12*, ..., p1J* ) p2*=(p21*, p22*, ..., p2K* ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if they satisfies the following conditions: player 1: for any m and n, if p1m*>0 and p1n*>0 then EU1(s1m, p2*) = EU1(s1n, p2*); if p1m*>0 and p1n*=0 then EU1(s1m, p2*)  EU1(s1n, p2*) player 2: for any i and k, if p2i*>0 and p2k*>0 then EU2(s2i, p1*) = EU2(s2k, p1*); if p2i*>0 and p2k*=0 then EU2(s2i, p1*)  EU2(s2k, p1*)

2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies What does Theorem 4 tell us? A pair of mixed strategies (p1*, p2*), where p1*=(p11*, p12*, ..., p1J* ), p2*=(p21*, p22*, ..., p2K* ) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if they satisfies the following conditions: Given player 2’s p2*, player 1’s expected payoff of every pure strategy to which she assigns positive probability is the same, and player 1’s expected payoff of any pure strategy to which she assigns positive probability is not less than the expected payoff of any pure strategy to which she assigns zero probability. Given player 1’s p1*, player 2’s expected payoff of every pure strategy to which she assigns positive probability is the same, and player 2’s expected payoff of any pure strategy to which she assigns positive probability is not less than the expected payoff of any pure strategy to which she assigns zero probability.

2-player each with a finite number of pure strategies Theorem 4 implies that we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium in the following situation Given player 2’s mixed strategy, Player 1 is indifferent among the pure strategies to which she assigns positive probabilities. The expected payoff of any pure strategy she assigns positive probability is not less than the expected payoff of any pure strategy she assigns zero probability. Given player 1’s mixed strategy, Player 2 is indifferent among the pure strategies to which she assigns positive probabilities. The expected payoff of any pure strategy she assigns positive probability is not less than the expected payoff of any pure strategy she assigns zero probability.

Theorem 4: illustration Player 2 L (0) C (1/3) R (2/3) Player 1 T (3/4) 0 , 2 3 , 3 1 , 1 M (0) 4 , 0 0 , 4 2 , 3 B (1/4) 3 , 4 5 , 1 0 , 7 Check whether ((3/4, 0, 1/4), (0, 1/3, 2/3)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium Player 1: EU1(T, p2) = 00+3(1/3)+1(2/3)=5/3, EU1(M, p2) = 40+0(1/3)+2(2/3)=4/3 EU1(B, p2) = 30+5(1/3)+0(2/3)=5/3. Hence, EU1(T, p2) = EU1(B, p2) > EU1(M, p2)

Theorem 4: illustration Player 2 L (0) C (1/3) R (2/3) Player 1 T (3/4) 0 , 2 3 , 3 1 , 1 M (0) 4 , 0 0 , 4 2 , 3 B (1/4) 3 , 4 5 , 1 0 , 7 Player 2: EU2(L, p1)=2(3/4) + 00 + 4(1/4)=5/2, EU2(C, p1)=3(3/4) + 40 + 1(1/4)=5/2, EU2(R, p1)=1(3/4) + 30 + 7(1/4)=5/2. Hence, EU2(C, p1)=EU2(R, p1)EU2(L, p1) Therefore, ((3/4, 0, 1/4), (0, 1/3, 2/3)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 4.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) Check whether there is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium in which p11>0, p12>0, p13>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) If each player assigns positive probability to every of her pure strategy, then by Theorem 4, each player is indifferent among her three pure strategies.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) Player 1 is indifferent among her three pure strategies: EU1(Rock, p2) = 0p21+(-1) p22+1 p23 EU1(Paper, p2) = 1 p21+0 p22+(-1) p23 EU1(Scissors, p2) = (-1) p21+1 p22+0 p23 EU1(Rock, p2)= EU1(Paper, p2)= EU1(Scissors, p2) Together with p21+ p22+ p23=1, we have three equations and three unknowns.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) 0p21+(-1) p22+1 p23= 1 p21+0 p22+(-1) p23 0p21+(-1) p22+1 p23 = (-1) p21+1 p22+0 p23 p21+ p22+ p23=1 The solution is p21= p22= p23=1/3

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) Player 2 is indifferent among her three pure strategies: EU2(Rock, p1)=0p11+(-1) p12+1 p13 EU2(Paper, p1)=1 p11+0 p12+(-1) p13 EU2(Scissors, p1)=(-1) p11+1 p12+0 p13 EU2(Rock, p1)= EU2(Paper, p1)=EU2(Scissors, p1) Together with p11+ p12+ p13=1, we have three equations and three unknowns.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) 0p11+(-1) p12+1 p13=1 p11+0 p12+(-1) p13 0p11+(-1) p12+1 p13=(-1) p11+1 p12+0 p13 p11+ p12+ p13=1 The solution is p11= p12= p13=1/3

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (1/3) Paper (1/3) Scissors (1/3) Player 1 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Player 1: EU1(Rock, p2) = 0(1/3)+(-1)(1/3)+1(1/3)=0 EU1(Paper, p2) = 1(1/3)+0(1/3)+(-1)(1/3)=0 EU1(Scissors, p2) = (-1)(1/3)+1(1/3)+0(1/3)=0 Player 2: EU2(Rock, p1)=0(1/3)+(-1)(1/3)+1(1/3)=0 EU2(Paper, p1)=1(1/3)+0(1/3)+(-1)(1/3)=0 EU2(Scissors, p1)=(-1)(1/3)+1(1/3)+0(1/3)=0 Therefore, (p1=(1/3, 1/3, 1/3), p2=(1/3, 1/3, 1/3)) is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 4.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) Check whether there is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium in which one of p11, p12, p13 is positive, and at least two of p21, p22, p23 are positive. The answer is No.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) Check whether there is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium in which two of p11, p12, p13 is positive, and at least two of p21, p22, p23 are positive. The answer is No.

Example: Rock, paper and scissors Player 2 Rock (p21) Paper (p22) Scissors (p23) Player 1 Rock (p11) 0 , 0 -1 , 1 1 , -1 Paper (p12) Scissors (p13) Therefore, (p1=(1/3, 1/3, 1/3), p2=(1/3, 1/3, 1/3)) is the unique mixed strategy Nash equilibrium by Theorem 4.

Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 We first consider pure-strategy Nash equilibria. How many can you find? In order to find all Nash equilibria, we need to consider 15 more cases by Theorem 4. We first consider complicated cases. Some cases are very easy.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 1: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0 By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12= 3p11+1 p12 = 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these equations. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 2: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0 By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12= 3p11+1 p12  3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 3: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0 By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 = 3p11+2 p12  3p11+1 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 4: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0 By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 3p11+1 p12 = 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 5: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23=0 (Note this implies p21=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 3p11+1 p12 and 2p11+2 p12 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23=0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23=0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 6: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23=0 (Note this implies p22=1) By theorem 4, we should have 3p11+1 p12  2p11+2 p12 and 3p11+1 p12  3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23=0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23=0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 7: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22=0, p23>0 (Note this implies p23=1) By theorem 4, we should have 3p11+2 p12  2p11+2 p12 and 3p11+2 p12  3p11+1 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 =3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22=0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12>0, p21=0, p22=0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 8: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0 (Note this implies p11=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12= 3p11+1 p12 = 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 9: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0 (Note this implies p11=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12= 3p11+1 p12  3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 10: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0 (Note this implies p11=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 3p11+1 p12  3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 11: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11>0, p12=0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0 (Note this implies p11=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 3p11+1 p12 = 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11>0, p12=0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 12: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0 (Note this implies p12=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12= 3p11+1 p12 = 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 13: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0 (Note this implies p12=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12= 3p11+1 p12  3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23 3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22>0, p23=0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 14: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0 (Note this implies p12=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 3p11+1 p12  3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23  3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21>0, p22=0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.

Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 Lecture 6 May 27, 2003 Exercise 138.1 of Osborne Player 2 L (p21) M (p22) R (p23) Player 1 T (p11) 2 , 2 0 , 3 1 , 3 B (p12) 3 , 2 1 , 1 0 , 2 Case 15: check whether there is a mixed strategy in which p11=0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0 (Note this implies p12=1) By theorem 4, we should have 2p11+2 p12 3p11+1 p12 = 3p11+2 p12 and p11+p12=1. We should have 2p21+0 p22+1 p23  3p21+1 p22+0 p23 and p21+ p22+ p23 = 1 Solve these. If we can get a solution that satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0 then we have a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Otherwise, if we can not find a solution or we find a solution that does not satisfies p11=0, p12>0, p21=0, p22>0, p23>0, then we do not have such a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium.