TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
THE CASE FOR TRADE: Comparative Advantage
Advertisements

Overview Introduction Setting up the Model Adding trade into the Model
TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL
3 Gains and Losses from Trade in the Specific-Factors Model 1
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
Differences in technology
TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL
Shhhhh!!!! please Econ 355 Introduction  Ricardian: suggests all countries gain from trade: Moreover: every individual is better off  Trade has substantial.
GAINS AND LOSSES FROM TRADE IN THE SPECIFIC-FACTORS MODEL
The Classical Model of International Trade
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
Foundations of Modern Trade Theory: Comparative Advantage
Economics Theories of International Trade
Classical Theories of International Trade
Chapter Two: The Law of Comparative Advantage
Weeks 1 and 2: Outline 3 conditions for General Equilibrium –Producer Optimization (Px/Py = MRT) –Consumer Optimization (Px/Py = MRS) –Market Clearing.
The “internationalization” or “globalization” of the U. S
Overview Introduction Setting up the Model
1 Ch. 3: Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage – The Ricardian Model.
The Gains from Trade: A General Equilibrium View Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference–the one takes account of the.
International Economics
Unit 1: Trade Theory Heckscher-Ohlin Model 2/3/2012.
Chapter 2 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model International Economics: Theory and Policy International Economics: Theory.
Chapter Two: The Law of Comparative Advantage. 2.2 The Mercantilists’ View on Trade  In the 17 th century a group of men (merchants, bankers, government.
The Classical Model of International Trade
OUTLINE 2.1 Introduction 2.2 The Mercantilists’ Views on Trade
Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Readings: Chapter 2 sections
International Economics
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
International Trade Theory The Law of Comparative Advantage MC 2009.
ESA International Economics, 2 Lecture 7 Giorgia Giovannetti Professor of Economics, University of Firenze
EF310: International Trade and Business Lecture 17 Theories of International Trade.
Lecture 1. Classic and Neoclassic Trade Models.
The Specific-factors model Dr. Petre Badulescu. Topics to be covered 1.Specific-factors model 2.Earnings of Labor 3.Earnings of Capital and Land Dr. Petre.
Lecture 2 : The law of Comparative Advantage Summary: 1.This chapter examined the development of trade theory from the mercantilists to Smith, Ricardo,
Why Countries Trade Chapter 1
E&D International Economics, 2 Lecture 8 Giorgia Giovannetti
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model
The PPF & Trade Dr. Jennifer P. Wissink ©2011 John M. Abowd and Jennifer P. Wissink, all rights reserved.
International Economics Tenth Edition
International Economics Eleventh Edition
The Standard Trade Model
Comparative Advantage and the Ricardian Model
International Trade Theory
International Trade Theory
Study Unit 4.
International Trade.
International Economics Tenth Edition
Economics and Development International trade
Factor Endowments Theory and Heckscher-Ohlin Model
The Standard Trade Model
Comparative Advantage
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 9th Edition
Classic Theories of International Trade
Chapter 2: The law of comparative advantage
Chapter Two: The Law of Comparative Advantage
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 9th Edition
Technology and Trade Dr. Petre Badulescu.
International Trade.
International Economics Twelfth Edition
Lecture 1. Classic and Neoclassic Trade Models.
Asst. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN
GAINS AND LOSSES FROM TRADE IN THE SPECIFIC-FACTORS MODEL
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model.
Production Possibilities Schedules
Comparative Advantage
Chapter 6: The United States in the Global Economy
Free Markets and Utility: Adam Smith
Presentation transcript:

TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL 2 TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL

International Economics Why do nations trade? In this chapter, we will investigate why nations trade with each other Since nations enter into trade voluntarily, it must be assumed that they benefit from this exchange of goods and services. This is not obvious and has not always been accepted Nations often trade simply because of proximity, but we will examine trade theory, which attempts to explain why trade occurs and what trade patterns we will observe Trade theory has evolved over time, and we will start by examining trade theories based on technology, i.e. absolute advantage and comparative advantage International Economics

Thomas Munn (1571-1641) - mercantilism Mercantilism was a school of thought highly critical of international trade. A well know proponent of the detrimental effects of international trade was Thomas Munn: “Although a Kingdom may be enriched by gifts received, or by purchase taken from some other Nations, yet these are things uncertain and of small consideration when they happen. The ordinary means therefore to increase our wealth and treasure is by Foreign Trade wherein we must ever observe this rule; to sell more to strangers yearly than we consume of theirs in value. For …. that part of our stock (exports) which is not returned to us in wares (imports) must necessarily be brought home in treasure.” International Economics

International Economics Adam Smith – Wealth of Nations 1776 http://www.adamsmith.org/smith/won-intro.htm It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family, never attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy. The tailor does not attempt to make his own shoes, but buys them from the shoemaker What is prudence in the conduct of every private family, can scarce be folly in that of a great kingdom. If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it from them with some part of the product of our own industry, employed in a way in which we have some advantage Trade is not a zero sum game – everyone can win International Economics

Adam Smith – theory of absolute advantage A country should produce and export a good if it can produce the good in a more efficient manner than other countries Production process very simple – labour is the only factor input, and prices depend on labour hours only International Economics

Absolute Advantage Production per labour hour (marginal product) In the US In the U.K. Wheat (W) 6 1 Cloth (C) 4 5 International Economics

International Economics Absolute Advantage In this example, the U.S. has an absolute advantage in wheat and the U.K. in cloth. The US should export wheat and import cloth. It will be in everyone's interest that countries specialise Obviously correct, and probably some trade is happening along these lines However, the theory does not go very far – what will happen if a country does not possess an absolute advantage in the production of any good? Enter David Ricardo and the theory of comparative advantage International Economics

International Economics David Ricardo International Economics

International Economics David Ricardo International Economics

David Ricardo: Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817) Two men can both make shoes and hats, and one is superior to the other in both employments; but in making hats he can only exceed his competitor by one-fifth, or 20 %, and in making shoes he can excel him by one-third or 33-1/3%. Will it not be in the interest of both that the superior man should employ himself exclusively in making shoes, and the inferior in making hats? International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model To develop a Ricardian model of trade, we will use a so called 2 x 2 model, i.e. two countries, home and foreign, each capable of producing 2 goods, wheat and cloth The model can easily be extended, but our simplification still allows for major insights to be derived International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model The Home Country We will assume that labor is the only resource used to produce both goods. One worker can produce 4 bushels of wheat or 2 yards of cloth. The Marginal Product of Labor is the extra output obtained by using one more unit of labor. MPLW = 4 and MPLC = 2. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Showing these calculations we can see: Labor = 25, MPLW = 4, MPLC = 2 QW = MPLW(L) = 25(4) = 100 QC = MPLC(L) = 25(2) = 50 This gives us a straight line PPF which is a unique feature of the Ricardian model. It assumes the marginal products of labor are constant. There are no diminishing returns because the model ignores the use of other resources. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model The slope of the PPF can be calculated as the ratio of marginal products of the two goods. The slope also equals the opportunity cost of wheat—the amount of cloth that must be given up to obtain one more unit of wheat. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Figure 2.1 Figure 2.1 Home Production Possibilities Frontier The Home PPF is a straight line between 50 yards of cloth and 100 bushels of wheat. The slope of the PPF equals the negative of the opportunity cost of wheat, that is, the amount of cloth that must be given up (yard) to obtain 1 more bushel of wheat. Equivalently, the magnitude of the slope can be expressed as the ratio of the marginal products of labor for the two goods. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Home Indifference Curve Given Home’s PPF, how much wheat and cloth will home actually produce. The answer depends on demand. Demand can be represented with indifference curve. An indifference curve shows the combinations of two goods that the country can consume and be equally satisfied. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Figure 2.2 The country is indifferent between A and B The country is better off on U2 but cannot produce that much U0<U1<U2 Figure 2.2 Home Equilibrium with No Trade Points A and B lie on the same indifference curve and give the Home consumers the level of utility U1. The highest level of Home utility on the PPF is obtained at point A, which is the no-trade equilibrium. Point D is also on the PPF but would give lower utility. Point C represents a higher utility level but is off of the PPF, so it is not attainable in the absence of international trade. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Opportunity Cost and Prices The slope of the PPF reflects the opportunity cost of producing one more bushel of wheat. Under perfect competition the opportunity cost of wheat should equal the price of wheat. Price reflects the opportunity cost of a good. If a good A takes twice as long to produce as a good B, one unit of A will cost the same as two units of B, or PA/PB = 2. The price ratio, PA/PB, always denotes the relative price of the good in the numerator, measured in terms of how much of the good in the denominator must be given up. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Wages Determination of wages In competitive markets firms hire workers up to the point at which the hourly wage equals the value of one more hour of production. The value of one more hour of labor equals the amount of goods produced in that hour (MPL) times the price of the good. Labor hired up to the point where wage equals P*MPL for each industry. Labor will move to the higher paid industry and this will continue until there is equalization of wages between industries. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model The equalization of wages will give us the following: The right hand side is the slope of the PPF and the opportunity cost of obtaining one more bushel of wheat. The left hand side is the relative price of wheat. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model The Foreign Country Assume Foreign’s technology is inferior to Home’s. Foreign has an absolute disadvantage in producing both wheat and cloth as compared to Home. Foreign Production Possibilities Frontier Assume a Foreign worker can produce one bushel of wheat or one yard of cloth. MPL*W = 1, MPL*C = 1 Assume there are 100 workers available in Foreign. If all workers were employed in wheat they could produce 100 bushels. If all workers were employed in cloth they could produce 100 yards. International Economics

International Economics Ricardian Model Figure 2.3 Figure 2.3 Foreign Production Possibilities Frontier The Foreign PPF is a straight line between 100 yards of cloth and 100 bushels of wheat. The slope of the PPF equals the negative of the opportunity cost of wheat, that is, the amount of cloth that must be given up (1 yard) to obtain 1 more bushel of wheat. International Economics

Ricardian Model Opportunity Costs for Goods in Home and Foreign Cloth (1 Yard) Wheat (1 Bushel) Home 2 Bushels of Wheat ½ Yard of Cloth Foreign 1 Bushel 1 Yard International Economics

Can Comparative Advantage be Created? The Case of “Icewine” In general we think of a country having a comparative advantage in a good. Certain countries have a comparative advantage in the production of wine. Can a country create a comparative advantage? Areas that get very cold are not good wine producers because the vines get too cold. International Economics

Can Comparative Advantage be Created? The Case of “Icewine” The Niagara Falls region of Canada began producing a product called “icewine” in 1983; it’s now made in British Columbia, too. The grapes are allowed to freeze on the vine before they are picked. The unique flavor of the wine has led to a relatively high demand. This has created a comparative advantage in a certain type of wine, even though Canada does not have the advantage in traditional wine production. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade What happens now when goods are traded between Home and Foreign? We will see the country’s no-trade relative price determines which product it will export and which it will import. The no-trade relative price equals its opportunity cost of production. Therefore, the pattern of exports and imports will be determined by the opportunity costs of production in each country—their comparative advantage. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade International Trade Equilibrium Relative price of cloth in Foreign is PC/PW = 1. Relative price of cloth in Home is PC/PW = 2, or conversely relative price of wheat in Home is Pw/Pc = 1/2 Therefore Foreign would want to export their cloth to Home—they can make it for $1 and export it for more than $1. The opposite is true for wheat. Home will export wheat and Foreign will export cloth. Both countries export the good for which they have the comparative advantage. What happens to relative prices? International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade International Trade Equilibrium The relative price of wheat in the trade equilibrium will be between the no-trade price in the two countries. For now we will assume the free-trade price of Pw/Pc is 2/3. This is between the price of 1/2 in Home and 1 in Foreign. We can now take this price and see how trade changes production and consumption in each country. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Change in Production and Consumption Home producers of wheat can earn more than the opportunity cost of wheat by selling it to Foreign. Home will therefore shift labor resources toward the production of wheat and increase its production. Remember wages are calculated by the price of the good times its marginal product. Given the information from before, we can calculate the ratio of wages in the two industries. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Home’s workers will want to work in wheat and no cloth will be produced. With trade, Home will be fully specialized in wheat production. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Home can export wheat at the international relative price of 2/3. For each bushel of wheat it exports, it gets 2/3 yards of cloth in return. In figure 2.5 we trace this out to get a new price line showing the world price. The world price line shows the range of consumption possibilities that a country can achieve by specializing in one good and trading. Remember: this is only a consumption possibility because production is still constrained by the PPF. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Home produces 100 bushels but consumes only 40, so exports equal 60 World price line, Slope = –2/3 U2 U1 50 100 Wheat, QW (bushels) Cloth, QC (yards) 50 100 Home produces 0 yards of cloth but consumes 40, so imports equal 40. Home consumption 40 C Home imports 40 yards of cloth 25 A Home production B 40 50 Home exports 60 bushels of wheat International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Figure 2.6 Figure 2.6 Foreign Equilibrium with Trade With a world relative price of wheat of 2/3, Foreign production will occur at point B*. Through international trade, Foreign is able to export 2/3 yard of cloth in exchange for 1 bushel of wheat, moving down the world price line B*C*. Foreign consumption occurs at point C*, and total exports are 40 yards of cloth in exchange for imports of 60 bushels of wheat. Relative to its pretrade wheat and cloth consumption (point A*), Foreign consumes 10 more bushels of wheat and 10 more yards of cloth. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Pattern of Trade and Gains from Trade Each country is exporting the good for which it has the comparative advantage. This confirms that the pattern of trade is determined by comparative advantage. This is the first lesson of the Ricardian model. There are gains from trade for both countries. This is the second lesson of the Ricardian model. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Pattern of Trade and Gains from Trade However, we have not yet determined the level of wages across countries. Relative prices converge. Do wages? Wages do rise in each country, but they do not converge. They are determined by absolute advantage, not comparative advantage. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Solving for Wages Across Countries As stated before, in competitive labor markets, firms will pay workers the value of their marginal product. Since Home produces and exports wheat, they will be paid in terms of that good—the real wage is MPLW = 4 bushels of wheat. The workers sell the wheat on the world market at a relative price of PW/PC = 2/3. We can use this to calculate the real wage in terms of cloth: (PW/PC)MPLW = (2/3)4 = 8/3 yards. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Solving for Wages Across Countries We can do this for Foreign as well and summarize: Home real wage is 4 bushels of wheat 8/3 yards of cloth Foreign real wage is 3/2 bushels of wheat 1 yard of cloth Foreign workers earn less than Home workers as measured by their ability to purchase either good. This fact reflects Home’s absolute advantage in the production of both goods. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade Wages are determined by absolute advantage and trade is determined by comparative advantage. This should make sense. The only way a country with poor technology can export at a price others are willing to pay is by having low wages. As a country develops better technology, its wages will rise. Workers become better off through receiving higher wages. As countries engage in trade, the Ricardian model predicts that their real wages will rise. International Economics

Determining the Pattern of International Trade We can see this in the real world Per capita income in China in 1978 was estimated at $925. In 2000, per capita income in China had risen to $3750. Per capita income in India more than doubled from $1180 in 1978 to $2480 in 2000. It is strongly believed that the opportunity for these countries to engage in international trade has been crucial in raising their standard of living. International Economics

Solving for International Prices Home Export Supply Curve We can use the information we gathered from before to derive an export supply curve. The export supply curve will have the relative price of wheat on the Y-axis and the amount of wheat on the X-axis. We saw before a relative price of 2/3 related to exports of 60 bushels. The first point on the export supply curve: the horizontal distance from point B to C in figure 2-9(a) and point C’ in figure 2-9(b). International Economics

Solving for International Prices To derive other points on the export supply curve we look at the no-trade equilibrium. When the relative price of wheat is ½, Home exports of wheat are zero (no-trade equilibrium). Point A and A’ in figure 2.9 For the 3rd point, we keep the relative price of wheat at ½. At this price, Home could export some wheat in exchange for cloth. Production could shift from A to any other place on the PPF. Workers are willing to shift between industries as the wages are the same. International Economics

Solving for International Prices If we assume that all workers have moved into wheat production. With the relative price of ½, consumption is still at point A and the difference between A and B is the amount of wheat that Home is exporting. At the relative price of ½, with wheat exports of 50, gives another point on the Home export supply curve: B’. International Economics

Solving for International Prices Figure 2.9 Home Export Supply Panel (a) repeats Figure 2-5 showing the trade equilibrium for Home with production at point B and consumption at point C. Panel (b) shows the Home export supply of wheat. When the relative price of wheat is ½, Home will export any amount of wheat between 0 and 50 bushels, along the segment A′B′ of the Home export supply curve. For relative prices above ½ Home exports more than 50 bushels, along the segment B′C′. For example, at the relative price of 2/3, Home exports 60 bushels of wheat. Figure 2.9 International Economics

Solving for International Prices The flat portion of the export supply curve is a special feature of the Ricardian model. The PPF is a straight line. Production can occur anywhere along the PPF as workers shift between industries. This leads to all the export levels between A’ and B’. At prices above ½, production is the same but consumption changes, rising above point A. International Economics

Solving for International Prices Foreign Import Demand We can use a similar analysis to construct the import demand for wheat in figure 2.10. At the world relative price of 2/3, Foreign imports 60 bushels of wheat, C* and C*’. The no-trade equilibrium in Foreign, with a relative price of 1, is zero imports, A* and A*’. Production can shift from point A, at a price of 1, as workers move between industries: If workers all shift to cloth. Foreign imports 50 bushels of wheat, B* and B*’. This gives us the import demand curve. International Economics

Solving for International Prices Figure 2.10 Foreign Import Demand Panel (a) repeats Figure 2-6, showing the Foreign trade equilibrium with production at point B* and consumption at point C*. Panel (b) shows Foreign import demand for wheat. When the relative price of wheat is 1, Foreign will import any amount of wheat between 0 and 50 bushels, along the segment A*’B*’ of the Foreign import demand curve. For relative prices below 1, Foreign imports more than 50 bushels, along the segment B*’C*’. For example, at the relative price of 2/3, Foreign imports 60 bushels of wheat. Figure 2.10 International Economics

Solving for International Prices Figure 2.11 Figure 2.11: World Market for Wheat Putting together the Home export supply curve and the Foreign import demand curve for wheat, the world equilibrium is established at point C ’, where the relative price of wheat is . At this price, Home exports of 60 bushels just equal Foreign imports of wheat. International Economics

Solving for International Prices The Terms of Trade The price of a country’s exports divided by the price of its imports. For Home, PW/PC is their terms of trade. An increase in PW or a fall in PC will raise Home’s terms of trade. An increase in the terms of trade is good for a country: it makes it better off. A country will earn more for its exports. A country will pay less for its imports. For Foreign, PC/PW is the terms of trade and a higher relative price for cloth makes it better off. International Economics