Horizontal mergers with one capacity constrained firm increase prices

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Oligopoly.
Advertisements

1 Predatory Conduct. 2 Predatory conduct is the implementation of a strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. To.
OT Anticompetitive consequence of the nationalization of a public enterprise in a mixed duopoly.
Bertrand Model Matilde Machado. Matilde Machado - Industrial Economics3.4. Bertrand Model2 In Cournot, firms decide how much to produce and the.
Chapter 11 Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers.
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Strategic Pricing Techniques.
Chapter 9 – Profit maximization
Antitrust Analysis Using Calibrated Economic Models Gregory J. Werden Senior Economic Counsel Antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice The views expressed.
Perfect Competition and the
Bertrand Duopoly.
Decision-Making at the firm level - The Goal Of Profit Maximization
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 9-1 CHAPTER 9 Perfect Competition and the Supply Curve PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers,
Lecture 4 Strategic Interaction Game Theory Pricing in Imperfectly Competitive markets.
How to assess vertical mergers cast your vote! Miguel de la Mano* Member of the Chief Economist Team DG COMP, European Commission *The views expressed.
Merger Antitrust Law Fundamentals Dale Collins Shearman & Sterling LLP April 18, 2013.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
CHAPTER 15 Oligopoly PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
Competitors and Competition
Merger Simulation with Homogeneous Goods Gregory J. Werden Senior Economic Counsel Antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice The views expressed herein.
Pricing of Competing Products BI Solutions December
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the oligopoly model(II): competition in prices ………….1price competition: introduction.
From Market Concentration to Market Outcome: The evolution of US antitrust agency horizontal merger guidelines Russell Pittman Antitrust Division, U.S.
Perfect Competition and the Supply Curve Chapter 12.
Lecture 7 Price competition. Bertrand’s Model of Oligopoly Strategic variable price rather than output. Single good produced by n firms Cost to firm i.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Power of Rivalry: Economics of Competition and Profits MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Jeopardy Example A merger between firms in the same industry
Shane Murphy ECON 102 Tutorial: Week 9 Shane Murphy
Q 2.1 Nash Equilibrium Ben
Chapter: 16 >> Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers 1.
Perfectly Competitive Market
On privatization methods in Eastern Europe and their implications
Profit 3 lessons covering profit. We will look at: Calculation of:
Time Warner Rules Manhattan
ARE BUSINESSES EFFICIENT? 11a – Oligopoly
CHAPTER 15 Oligopoly.
African Competition Forum
Chapter 8 & 9 Pure Competition
News Review.
Perfect Competition: Short Run and Long Run
Horizontal Mergers: theory and practice
Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if . . .
Games Of Strategy Chapter 4 Dixit, Skeath, and Reiley
Economics September Lecture 14 Chapter 12
Today Oligopoly Theory Economic Experiment in Class.
14 Firms in Competitive Markets P R I N C I P L E S O F
Oligopoly Managerial Economics Kyle Anderson
OCR Cambridge nationals in Business R061
Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence
Chapter 25 Kaden Steele Section I.
Chapter 9 Corporate-Level Strategy: Horizontal Integration, Vertical Integration, and Strategic Outsourcing.
Analyzing Telecom Mergers*
Economics 101 The Basics.
Profit maximization.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Chapter 8 & 9 Pure Competition
Ind – Develop a foundational knowledge of pricing to understand its role in marketing. (Part II) Entrepreneurship I.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
The Market Forces of Supply and Demand
Chapter 9 Corporate-Level Strategy: Horizontal Integration, Vertical Integration, and Strategic Outsourcing.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers
Relations And Functions © 2002 by Shawna Haider.
Market Structures I: Monopoly
Relations And Functions.
Tariff Rate Quotas with endogenous mode of competition:
Pure Competition in the Short Run
Monopolistic Competition & Price Discrimination
Perfect Competition and the Supply Curve
Horizontal Mergers: theory and practice
Presentation transcript:

Horizontal mergers with one capacity constrained firm increase prices David J. Balan (FTC) Patrick DeGraba (FTC) Jason O’Connor (FTC) April 21, 2018 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Trade Commission.

UPP and Merger Effects Why do mergers of substitutes raise prices? Often explained in terms of Upward Pricing Pressure e.g., 2010 DOJ/FTC Horizontal Merger Guidelines UPP > 0 if and only if D12(P2 –C2) > EC1 This is fundamentally about recapture of lost sales Start with the pre-merger price Benefit to Firm 1 ↑ its price by a small amount equal to the loss After the merger, benefit is the same, loss is smaller This is because a fraction D12 of the lost sales go to Firm 2 Those sales, and the profit (P2 –C2) are “recaptured” If this effect exceeds the efficiencies EC1, then P1 ↑

UPP and Merger Effects This is a valuable way to think about mergers It is intuitive and it is useful as a pedagogical device It may also be useful for quantitative merger simulation Weyl & Jaffe (2013), Miller et al. (2016,2017) But recapture is not the only source of merger effects And applying the recapture intuition in the context of capacity constraints is positively misleading

UPP with a Capacity Constraint Pre-merger, Firm 1 faces binding capacity constraint K Let Firm 1 and Firm 2 merge For a given P2, Firm 1 will not want to change its price Price ↓ is unprofitable (lower price for same sales of K units) Price ↑ is ruled out by the assumption that the constraint binds Firm 2 should want to raise its price as long as D12 > 0 This is the logic of UPP But Firm 1 cannot accommodate any diverted sales So it might appear that Firm 2 will not ↑ its price That is, the logic of UPP appears to suggest no merger effect with even one constrained firm

UPP with a Capacity Constraint This has been claimed explicitly in defense of mergers Q. So that was a lot about Hershey. What about Pinnacle? A. Pinnacle is in a different situation because while there is some demand side substitutability as there is between Hershey and Pinnacle, but between Pinnacle and Hershey, as well, there's some overlap, it's just in the context of one being community and the other being academic, it is not all that substantial, but there's some, to be sure, without taking the capacity constraint into account. But once capacity is taken into account, there can't be substantial diversion of patients from anywhere, but, in particular, from Pinnacle to Hershey, say as a result of some imagined price increase or some competitive event that is being assessed, because Hershey just doesn't have the capacity to take on a major influx of patients from Pinnacle as a possible result of whatever, a natural disaster, we hope not, or a price rise. No, it just -- it won't happen. So that the practical diversion between Pinnacle and Hershey is insignificant due to Hershey's capacity constraint, as well as due to the differentiation of their services. But that means that the diversion ratio, in practical terms, because of the capacity constraint, is de minimis. And the conclusion is at the bottom of the slide. That means that upward pricing pressure in that direction, the upward pricing pressure from the merger on Pinnacle is negligible. (Expert testimony of Professor Robert Willig in Federal Trade Commission and Commonwealth of Pennsylvania vs. Penn State Hershey Medical Center and Pinnacle Health System, April 15, 2016.) Other examples exist as well

Non-UPP Merger Effects UPP is about internalizing recaptured sales With the constraint, there are no net recaptured sales But after the merger, Firm 2 DOES internalize the fact that an increase in P2 increases the price at which Firm 1 sells out its constraint K This is sufficient for an increase in both prices This is a simple point, but commonly misunderstood

Model Using Bertrand The natural way to model this would be Bertrand But there is a well-known problem with Bertrand Pure strategy equilibrium may not exist when MC ↑ Certain not to exist when MC is vertical at the constraint Could try to model a mixed-strategy equilibrium See Chen & Li (2018) But that is not what we do

Model Using Cournot In standard Cournot, mergers are not always profitable But when they are profitable, they ↑ prices Salant et al. (1983), Perry & Porter (1985) The intuition is that the each of the merged firms internalizes the effect of a reduction in its output on its merger partner, via the resulting price increase Having one merging firm be capacity constrained does not change this basic intuition The idea that merger effects come from recapture of lost sales following a price increase does not apply to Cournot, so the confusion discussed above does not arise

Model Using Stackelberg The claim that mergers have no effect in the presence of a capacity constraint is usually made in the context of price-setting games As discussed above, there are problems with Bertrand So instead we use Stackelberg Firm 2 (and other rivals) choose prices in Stage 1 Firm 1 (constrained firm) chooses its price in Stage 2 (Results for the opposite case, where Firm 1 chooses its price in Stage 1 and Firm 2 and rivals choose in Stage 2, are in process but we believe the answer to be the same)

Model Using Stackelberg Pre-merger, Firm 1 chooses price to sell exactly K Given this, effect for Firm 2 of small change in P2 is 0 But higher P2 ↑ the price at which Firm 1 sells K So the effect of a small change in P2 is positive for P1 Pre-merger Firm 2 does not care about this But after the merger this effect is internalized So following the merger both prices will ↑ Even though there was no recapture of lost sales At the post-merger equilibrium, Firm 1 may produce at the constraint K or may produce less (i.e., may cease to be constrained) But either way both prices ↑

Conclusion The logic of UPP is useful But it is not a complete account of where merger effects come from Usually this is not a serious problem, but it becomes one when UPP is used to analyze a merger with one capacity constrained firm The logic of UPP appears to indicate that such mergers have no effect This is simply incorrect: merged firms internalize price effects even when there are no net recaptured sales