Vertical Price Restraints

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Vertical Relations and Restraints Many transactions take place between two firms, rather than between a firm and consumers Key differences in these types.
Advertisements

Economics of Management Strategy BEE3027 Miguel Fonseca Lecture 8.
Competition Policy Vertical Restraints.
9 Import Tariffs and Quotas under Imperfect Competition 1
Departures from perfect competition
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Equilibrium and Efficiency
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Economics: Principles in Action
Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints1 Vertical Price Restraints.
Industrial Organization: Contemporary Theory & Practice Chapter 9: Vertical Relations.
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
Competition and Market Power
LIPSEY & CHRYSTAL ECONOMICS 12e
Chapter 13: Vertical Restraints1 Vertical Restraints.
Chapter 19: Nonprice Vertical Restraints1 Nonprice Vertical Restraints.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly 13 CHAPTER.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency. What Makes a Market Competitive? Buyers and sellers have absolutely no effect on price Three characteristics: Absence.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. What is a Pure Competition? Pure.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition Copyright © 2007 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Chapter: 14 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Monopoly.
Chapter 7SectionMain Menu Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Models of Competition Part I: Perfect Competition
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition
Chapter 15 Market Interventions McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Monopolistic Competition
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
CHAPTER 14 Monopoly.
Time Warner Rules Manhattan
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic Competition
23 Pure Competition.
Pure Monopoly Chapter 11 11/8/2018.
Lecture 14 Monopolistic competition
Factor Markets and Vertical Integration
CHAPTER 10 OUTLINE 10.1 Monopoly 10.2 Monopoly Power 10.3 Sources of Monopoly Power 10.4 The Social Costs of Monopoly Power 10.5 Monopsony 10.6 Monopsony.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Chapter 25 Price Planning.
Managerial Economics Eighth Edition Truett + Truett
Lecture ONE PRICE DISCRIMINATION.
Lecture 16 Vertical, Complementary, and Conglomerate Mergers
LIPSEY & CHRYSTAL ECONOMICS 12e
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS: PART 1
Monopoly and Pricing.
Chapter 7: Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Pure Competition Chapter 10 1/16/2019.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Monopoly and Pricing.
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior.
Economics: Principles in Action
6. Strategic Export Policy
Monopolistic Competition & Price Discrimination
Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the marketplace? What are prices.
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS
Price Strategy Considerations
Operations Management
CHAPTER 15 Pricing © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted.
Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the marketplace? What are prices.
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Presentation transcript:

Vertical Price Restraints Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints Introduction Many contractual arrangements between manufacturers Some restrict rights of retailer Can’t carry alternative brands Expected to provide services or to deliver product in a specific amount of time Some restrict rights of manufacturer Can’t supply other dealers Must buy back unsold goods Some involve restrictions/guidelines on pricing Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

Resale Price Maintenance Resale Price Maintenance is the most important type of vertical price restriction. Under RPM agreement Retailer agrees to sell at manufactured specified price RPM agreements have a long and checkered history In US, Dr. Miles case of 1911established per se illegality for any and all such agreements However, Colgate case of 1919 allowed some “wiggle room” Miller-Tydings (1937) and McGuire (1952) Acts even more supportive in allowing states to enforce RPM contracts Repeal of Miller-Tydings and McGuire Acts reverted legal status back to (mostly) per se illegal State Oil v. Khan decision in 1997 allowed rule of reason in RPM agreements setting maximum price Leegin case applies rule of reason to minimum price Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM Agreements & Double Marginalization Recall the Double Marginalization Problem Downstream Demand is P = A – BQ and Retailer has no cost other than wholesale purchase price Downstream Marginal Revenue = MRD = A – 2BQ MRD =Upstream Demand Upstream Marginal Revenue = MRU = A – 4BQ With Manufacturer’s marginal cost c, profit-maximizing output and upstream price are: and – Downstream price is: Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM & Double Marginalization 2 With a vertical chain of a monopoly manufacturer and a monopoly retailer, the downstream price is far too high There is a pricing externality The manufacturer profit is the wholesale price r – cost c times the volume of output Q [= (r – c)Q] Once r is set, manufacturer’s profit rises with Q In setting a markup over the wholesale price, the retailer limits Q and cuts into manufacturer profit But retailer ignores this external effect Retail (and wholesale) price maximizing joint profit < Independent retailer’s price Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM & Double Marginalization 3 An RPM restriction that prohibits the retailer from selling at any price higher than P* would permit the manufacturer to achieve the maximum profit There is though an alternative to the RPM, namely a Two-Part Tariff of the type discussed in Chapter 6 Set wholesale price at marginal cost c Retailer will then choose PD = P* = (A + c)/2 and earn profit = (A – c)2/4B Charge franchise fee of T = (A – c)2/4B Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM & Price Discrimination An RPM to prevent double marginalization suggests problem is that the retail price is too high Historical record suggests that perceived problem is often that retail price is too low Need to find reason(s) for RPM agreements aimed at keeping retail prices high Retail Price Discrimination may present case where RPM specifying minimum price can help manufacturer Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM & Price Discrimination (cont.) Suppose retailer operates in two markets One has less elastic demand (monopolized) One has elastic demand (due to potential entrant)—retail price P cannot rise above wholesale price r Manufacturer must use same contract for each Maximum profit in each market = (A – c)2/4B achieved at P* = (A + c)/2 No single price or single two-part tariff can maximize profit from both markets Unless r = (A + c)/2 in elastic demand market, P* cannot be achieved since in that market P = r But there is only one contract, so this implies r = (A + c)/2 in inelastic (monopolized) market and so to double marginalization Solution: write common contract that sets r = c, and imposes RPM minimum price of P=(A+c)/2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services So far the retailer has been a totally passive intermediary between manufacturer and consumer Retailers actually provide additional services: marketing, customer assistance, information, repairs. These services increase sales This benefits manufacturers But offering these services is costly, and also both services and costs are hard for manufacturer to measure Retailers interested in her profit not manufacturer’s How does the manufacturer provide incentives for retailer to offer services? Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 2 Think of retail services s and shifting out demand curve similar to the way that quality increases shifted out the demand curve in Chapter 7 $/unit Demand with retail services s = 1 Demand with retail services s = 2 Quantity But cost of providing retail services (s) rises as more services are provided $/unit (s) Service Level s Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 3 As a benchmark, see what happens if manufacturing and retailing are integrated in one firm suppose that consumer demand is Q = 100s(500 - P) Note how s shifts out demand assume that marginal costs are cm for manufacturing and for the cr for retailing the cost of providing retail services is an increasing function of the level of services, f(s) the integrated firm’s profit I is: I = [P-cm-cr-f(s)]100s(500 - P) Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 4 The integrated firm has two choices to make: What price P to charge (what Q to produce); and The level of retail services s to provide To maximize profit, take derivatives of integrated firm’s profit function both with respect to Q and with respect to s and set each equal to zero Cancel the 100s terms pI/P = 100s(500 - P) - 100s(P - cm - cr - f(s)) = 0  500 - 2P + cm + cr + f(s) = 0  P* = (500 + cm + cr + f(s))/2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 5 Cancel the 100(500 - P) terms RPM and Retail Services 5 Now take the derivative with respect to services s and set it equal to pI/s = 100s(500 - P)(P - cm - cr - f(s)) - 100s(500 - P)f’(s) = 0 Solving we obtain:  (P - cm - cr - f(s)) = sf’(s) Substituting the price equation into the service equation then yields:  (500 - cm - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf’(s) The s that satisfies the above equation gives the efficient (profit-maximizing) level of services Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 6 The left hand side is decreasing in cm and cr RPM and Retail Services 6 The right hand side is increasing in s We can use this equation to show how changes in the production and retailing marginal cost (cm and cr) affect the optimal level of services Suppose now that there is an increase in marginal costs, apart from services, at either the manufacturing or retail level Let cm and cr be initial marginal costs  (500 - cm - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf’(s) $/unit The rise in cost leads to a fall in the optimal choice of s from s* to s** f(s)/2 + sf’(s) (500-cm-cr)/2 Let c’m and c’r be new marginal costs (500-c’m-c’r )/2 Service Level s s** s* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 7 For example let cm = $20, cr = $30 and f(s) = 90s2 Then (500 - cm - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf(s) implies 225 = 45s2 + s180s ; OR 225 = 225s2  s = 1 Then, solving for P we obtain: (P - cm - cr - f(s)) = 180s2 = 180 P= $320 Implying an output level of: Q = 100s(500 - P) = 18,000 The integrated firm earns profit pI = $3.24 million. It chooses the socially efficient level of retail services but sets price above marginal cost. This is our benchmark case. Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 8 Now let manufacturer sell to monopoly dealer If we assume two-part pricing is not possible, then the only way that the manufacturer can earn profit is by charging a wholesale price r above cost cm Cancel the 100s terms – The profit of the retailer is now: pR = (P- r - cr - f(s))100s(500 - P) = (P- r - 30- 90s2 )100s(500 - P) Cancel the 100(500 - P) terms – Retailer sets P and s to maximize retail profit pR/P = 100s(500 - P) - 100s(P - r - 30 – 90s2) = 0 – P = (530 + r + 90s2)/2 pR/s = 100(500 - P)(P - r - 30 – 90s2) - 100s(500 - P)180s = 0 – P – r – 30 = 270s2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 9 Put the two profit-maximizing conditions together (500 – r – cr)/2 = (s)/2 + s’(s) OR 225s2 = 235 – r/2 – It is clear that unless r = cm = 20, s will be less than 1, i.e., less than the optimal level of services – Yet absent an alternative pricing arrangement, the manufacturer only earns a positive profit if r > 20. – From the retailer’s perspective, a value of r > 20 is equivalent to a rise in cm and as we saw previously, this reduces the retailer’s optimal service level Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 10 Two contracts that might solve the problem are: A royalty contract written on the retailer’s profit; A two-part tariff Under a profit-royalty contract, the manufacturer sells at cost cm to the retailer but claims a percentage x of the retailer’s profit This works because there is no difference between maximizing total retail profit or maximizing (1 – x) of total retail profit Given that the wholesale cost is cm, the profit-maximizing condition: 235 = 225s2 + r/2 leads to s = 1, the efficient level of services Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 11 Similarly, a two-part tariff could solve the problem: Again, sell at wholesale price cm = $20; As before, this leads to the efficient level of services, namely, s = 1. Now manufacturer can claim downstream profit (or some part of it) by use of an upfront franchise fee However, both royalty and two-part tariff requires that manufacturer know the retailer’s true profit level. This can be difficult if retailer has inside information on the nature of: Retailing cost, cr Retail consumer demand Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 12 Can an RPM solve the problem? It has the advantage that it is easily monitored It also addresses the double-marginalization problem However, it cannot solve the service problem in the present context Without a royalty or up-front franchise fee, manufacturer can only earn profit if r > cm. As we have seen, this in itself leads to a service reduction Imposing a maximum price via an RPM agreement intensifies this fall in service because it reduces the retailer’s margin, P – r, and it is that margin that funds the provision of services Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 13 However, use of an RPM becomes considerably more attractive if retail sector is competitive large number of identical retailers each buys from the manufacturer at r and incurs service costs per unit of f(s) plus marginal costs cr competition in retailing drives retail price to PC = r + cr + f(s) competition also drives retailers to provide the level of services most desired by consumers subject to retailers breaking even so each retailer sets price at marginal cost chooses the service level to maximize consumer surplus Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 14 With competition there is no retail markup and no retail profit P = r + cr + (s) Profit royalty and two-part tariff will not work because there is no profit to share or take up front Given wholesale price r, retailers compete by offering level of services s that maximizes consumer surplus Recall: Demand is: Q = 100s(500 - P) P = r + cr + f(s) Consumer Surplus is therefore: CS = (500 – P)xQ/2 = 50s(500 – P)2 CS = 50s[500 – r – cr – (s)]2 Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 15 By way of a diagram, we have: Triangle = Consumer Surplus. Given r, cr, and (s), competitive retailers will compete by offering services that maximize this triangle $/unit 500 P=r+cr+(s) Q 50s Quantity (000’s) Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 16 Cancel the common term 50(500 - r - cr - f(s)) We can determine the competitive service outcome for any value of r by maximizing CS = 50s[500 – r – cr – (s)]2 with respect to s . This yields  CS/s = 50(500-r-cr-f(s))2 -100s(500-r-cr-f(s))f(s) = 0 So: 500 - r - cr - f(s) = 2sf(s)  (500 - r - cr)/2 = f(s)/2 + sf(s) This equation gives the competitive level of retail services when the manufacturer simply chooses r and lets retailers choose P and s Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 17 Recall: the integrated firm wants to set a price=P* = $320. RPM lets manufacturer impose this price on retailers. With retail price = P* = $320, competitive retailers offer services until they just break even, i.e., until: f(s) = P* – cr – r = 90s2 = 320 – 30 – r By choosing, r = $200, the competitive service level satisfies: 90s2 = 90  s = 1 with P = $320 This is the optimal service level and price. The RPM has led to duplication of the integrated outcome Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Retail Services 18 Consideration of customer services with competitive retailing also gives another reason that RPM agreements may be useful—the free-riding problem. Many services are informational Features of high-tech equipment Quality, e.g., wine Providing these services are costly But no obligation of consumer to buy from retailer Discount stores can free-ride on retailer’s services Retailers cut back on services Manufacturers and consumers lose out RPM agreements prevent free-riding discounters Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand RPM agreements may also be helpful in dealing with variable retail demand Retailer facing uncertain demand has to balance how to meet demand if demand is strong how to avoid unwanted inventory if demand is weak monopoly retailer acts differently from competitive monopolist throws away inventory when demand is weak to avoid excessive price fall competitive retailer will sell it because he believes that he is small enough not to affect the price Intense retail competition if demand is weak reduces the profit of the manufacturer makes firms reluctant to hold inventory Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand 2 Suppose that demand is high, DH with probability 1/2 And that demand is low, DL with probability 1/2 Price – Marginal costs are assumed constant at c – Integrated firm has to choose in each period stage 1: how much to produce stage 2: demand known- how much to sell since costs are sunk: maximize revenue DH DL c MC Quantity Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand 3  An integrated firm will not produce more than QUpper Price  And will not produce less than QLower  the integrated firm will produce Q* DH How is Q* determined MC = MR with low demand MC = MR with high demand DL c MC MRL MRH Quantity QLower Q* QUpper Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand 4  If demand is high the firm sells Q* at price PMax: MR = MR*H  If demand is low selling Q* is excessive Price  the firm maximizes revenue by selling Q*L at price PMin: MR = 0 Revenue with low demand  Expected marginal revenue is: Revenue with high demand MR*H/2 + 0 = MR*H/2 DH  Q* is such that expected MR = MC . So, MR*H/2 = c PMax PMin DL  Expected profit is MR*H pI = PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 - cQ* MC c MRL MRH Quantity Q*L Q* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand 5 Suppose that retailing is competitive  Will competitive retailers stock the optimal amount Q*? What will happen if they do? Price  If demand is high the retail firms sell Q* at price PMax: MR = MR*H Revenue with high demand  If demand is low each firm will sell more so long as price is positive DH PMax  So, if demand is low competitive retailers keep selling until they sell the total quantity QL at which price is zero DL  Revenue is therefore zero in low demand periods if competitive firms stock Q* MC c MRL MRH Quantity QL Q* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and variable demand 6 If competitive retailers stock Q*, their expected net revenue is thus: PMaxQ*/2 + 0 = PMaxQ*/2 Competitive firms just break even. So, manufacturer can only charge a wholesale price PW such that: PWQ* = PMaxQ*/2 which gives PW = PMax/2 The manufacturer’s profit is then: pM = (PMax/2 - c)Q* This is well below the integrated profit. Competitive retailers sell too much in low demand periods An RPM agreement can fix this. How? Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand 7  Recall: The integrated firm never sells at a price below PMin Price  So, set a minimum RPM of PMin  In high demand periods Q* is sold at price PMax  In low demand periods the RPM agreement ensures that only Q*L is sold DH PMax  Expected revenue to the retailers is PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 PMin DL MR*H c MC MRL MRH Quantity Q*L Q* Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints

RPM and Variable Demand 8 With RPM, expected net revenues of retailers is PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 Manufacturer can now charge wholesale price PW such that: PWQ* = PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 which gives PW = PMax/2 + PMinQ*L/2Q* The manufacturer’s profit is pM = PMaxQ*/2 + PMinQ*L/2 - cQ* This is the same as the integrated profit – The RPM agreement has given the integrated outcome – Consumers can gain too because retailers now stock products with variable demand that would otherwise not be stocked. Chapter 18: Vertical Price Restraints