Cost Minimization and Cost Curves

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
 fixed costs – costs that do not vary with the level of output. Fixed costs are the same at all levels of output (even when output equals zero).  variable.
Advertisements

Theory of the Firm in Perfect Competition Two Critical Decisions; Long Run vs Short Run; Widget Production.
Learning Objectives Delineate the nature of a firm’s cost – explicit as well as implicit. Outline how cost is likely to vary with output in the short run.
Cost and Production Chapters 6 and 7.
Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics, 9e Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice.
Chapter 9: Production and Cost in the Long Run
Production & Cost in the Long Run
Chapter 9 Costs.
Chapter 8 – Costs and production. Production The total amount of output produced by a firm is a function of the levels of input usage by the firm The.
Multiple Input Cost Relationships. Output is identical along an isoquant Output is identical along an isoquant Isoquant means “equal quantity” Two inputs.
10 OUTPUT AND COSTS CHAPTER.
Cost. Overview In this section we want to translate the production data into cost data. In other words, we will want to understand how the cost of producing.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics
1 Costs APEC 3001 Summer 2007 Readings: Chapter 10 & Appendix in Frank.
Applied Economics for Business Management
Chapter 10 McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Economic Applications of Functions and Derivatives
CHAPTER 11 Output and Costs
1 Cost Minimization and Cost Curves Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1.
AGEC 407 Economic Decision Making Marginal analysis –changes at the “margin” –examining the results of an additional unit.
Practice Questions Two goods are ________. A(n) _________ in the price of one good will _________ the demand for the other good: (A) substitutes; increase;
1 Review of General Economic Principles Review Notes from AGB 212.
Chapter 6 Production. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 62 Topics to be Discussed The Technology of Production Production with One Variable Input.
AAEC 2305 Fundamentals of Ag Economics Chapter 4 Costs, Returns, and Profit Maximization.
The Firm and Cost Overheads. Costs in the short run Total cost — everything they must give up in order to produce output A firm’s total cost of production.
AAEC 3315 Agricultural Price Theory CHAPTER 6 Cost Relationships The Case of One Variable Input in the Short-Run.
The Costs of Production Chapter 6. In This Chapter… 6.1. The Production Process 6.2. How Much to Produce? 6.3. The Right Size: Large or Small?
Theory of Production & Cost BEC Managerial Economics.
Copyright © 2005 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice eighth edition Chapter 9.
1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: , b.
Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1b-c, 3.2c, , 5.2a-d
1 Chapters 8: Costs of Production. 2 Cost Definitions Total cost (TC) = all costs of production –If r is the cost of capital (rental cost), and w is the.
A.P. Microeconomics Daily: Draw & label no the same axis set, TFC, AFC & TVC.
1 Unconstrained and Constrained Optimization. 2 Agenda General Ideas of Optimization Interpreting the First Derivative Interpreting the Second Derivative.
COST ANALYSIS CHAPTER # 5. Meaning of Cost  By cost we mean “The total sum of money required for the production of specific quantity of a good or service.
Production and Cost in the Long Run Nihal Hennayake.
9-1 Learning Objectives  Graph a typical production isoquant and discuss the properties of isoquants  Construct isocost curves  Use optimization theory.
1 Chapter 11 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION. 2 Profit Maximization A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the sole goal of achieving.
Understanding Production and Making Optimal Decisions
Chapter 11 Profit Maximization.
Production.
Production & Costs Continued…
Learning Objectives Define several key concepts and terminology related to marginal analysis Use marginal analysis to find optimal activity levels in unconstrained.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition
Chapter 9: Production and Cost in the Long Run
Costs in the Short Run.
Chapter 6 Production.
The Shape of the Marginal Cost Curve in the Short Run
Intermediate Microeconomics WESS16
Modelling the producer: Costs and supply decisions
Pure Competition in the Short-Run
Costs.
AP Microeconomics Review #3 (part 1)
Chapter 9 Production and Cost in the Long Run
Lecture 9 The Costs of Production
ECN 201: Principles of Microeconomics
Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: , b
Thinking About Costs A firm’s total cost of producing a given level of output is ______________ Everything they must give up in order to produce that amount.
Review of General Economic Principles
Module 55: Firm Costs.
Review of the previous lecture
Unconstrained and Constrained Optimization
Production & Cost in the Long Run
CHAPTER 5 THEORY OF PRODUCTION. CHAPTER 5 THEORY OF PRODUCTION.
Costs.
Chapter 9 Costs.
Sides Game.
Chapter 3 Marginal Analysis for Optimal Decisions
AP Microeconomics Review Unit 3 (part 1)
Introduction to Production and Resource Use
Presentation transcript:

Cost Minimization and Cost Curves Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 3.1a, 3.2a-b, 4.1

Agenda The Cost Function and General Cost Minimization Cost Minimization with One Variable Input Deriving the Average Cost and Marginal Cost for One Input and One Output Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs

Cost Function A cost function is a function that maps a set of inputs into a cost. In the short-run, the cost function incorporates both fixed and variable costs. In the long-run, all costs are considered variable.

Cost Function Cont. The cost function can be represented as the following: C = c(x1, x2, …,xn)= w1*x1 + w2*x2 + … + wn*xn Where wi is the price of input i, xi, for i = 1, 2, …, n Where C is some level of cost and c(•) is a function

Cost Function Cont. When there are fixed costs, the cost function can be represented as the following: C = c(x1, x2| x3, …,xn)= w1*x1 + w2*x2 + TFC Where wi is the price of the variable input i, xi, for i = 1 and 2 Where wi is the price of the fixed input i, xi, for i = 3, 4, …, n Where TFC = w3*x3 + … + wn*xn When inputs are fixed, they can be lumped into one value which we usually denote as TFC Where C is some level of cost and c(•) is a function

Cost Function Cont. Suppose we have the following cost function: C = c(x1, x2, x3)= 5*x1 + 9*x2 + 14*x3 If x3 was held constant at 4, then the cost function can be written as: C = c(x1, x2| 4)= 5*x1 + 9*x2 + 56 Where TFC in this case is 56

Cost Function Cont. The cost function is usually meaningless unless you have some constraint that bounds it, i.e., minimum costs occur when all the inputs are equal to zero.

Standard Cost Minimization Model Assume that the general production function can be represented as y = f(x1, x2, …, xn).

Cost Minimization with One Variable Input Assume that we have one variable input (x) which costs w. Let TFC be the total fixed costs. Assume that the general production function can be represented as y = f(x).

Cost Minimization with One Variable Input Cont. In the one input, one output world, the solution to the minimization problem is trivial. By selecting a particular output y, you are dictating the level of input x. The key is to choose the most efficient input to obtain the output.

Example of Cost Minimization Suppose that you have the following production function: y = f(x) = 6x - x2 You also know that the price of the input is $10 and the total fixed cost is 45.

Example of Cost Minimization Cont. Since there is only one input and one output, the problem can be solved by finding the most efficient input level to obtain the output.

Example of Cost Minimization Cont. Given the previous, we must decide whether to use the positive or negative sign. This is where economic intuition comes in. The one that makes economic sense is the following:

Cost Function and Cost Curves There are many tools that can be used to understand the cost function: Average Variable Cost (AVC) Average Fixed Cost (AFC) Average Cost (ATC) Marginal Cost (MC)

Average Variable Cost Average variable cost is defined as the cost function without the fixed costs divided by the output function.

Average Fixed Cost Average fixed cost is defined as the cost function without the variable costs divided by the output function.

Average Total Cost Average total cost is defined as the cost function divided by the output function. It is also the summation of the average fixed cost and average variable cost.

Marginal Cost Marginal cost is defined as the derivative of the cost function with respect to the output. To obtain MC, you must substitute the production function into the cost function and differentiate with respect to output.

Example of Finding Marginal Cost Using the production function y = f(x) = 6x - x2, and a price of 10, find the MC by differentiating with respect to y. To solve this problem, you need to solve the production function for x and plug it into the cost function. This gives you a cost function that is a function of y.

Example of Finding Marginal Cost Cont.

Notes on Costs MC will meet AVC and ATC from below at the corresponding minimum point of each. Why? As output increases AFC goes to zero. As output increases, AVC and ATC get closer to each other.

Production and Cost Relationships Summary Cost curves are derived from the physical production process. The two major relationships between the cost curves and the production curves: AVC = w/APP MC = w/MPP

Product Curve Relationships When MPP>APP, APP is increasing. This implies that when MC<AVC, then AVC is decreasing. When MPP=APP, APP is at a maximum. This implies that when MC=AVC, then AVC is at a minimum. When MPP<APP, APP is decreasing. This implies that when MC>AVC, then AVC is increasing.

Product Curve Relationships Cont.

Product Curve Relationships Cont.

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Given that the production function y = f(x) = 6x - x2, and a price of 10, find the input(s) where AVC is greater than, equal to, and less than MC. To solve this, examine the following situations: AVC = MC AVC > MC AVC < MC

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Cont.

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Cont.

Example of Examining the Relationship Between MC and AVC Cont.

Review of the Iso-Cost Line The iso-cost line is a graphical representation of the cost function with two inputs where the total cost C is held to some fixed level. C = c(x1,x2)=w1x1 + w2x2

Finding the Slope of the Iso-Cost Line

Example of Iso-Cost Line Suppose you had $1000 to spend on the production of lettuce. To produce lettuce, you need two inputs labor and machinery. Labor costs you $10 per unit, while machinery costs $100 per unit.

Example of Iso-Cost Line Cont. Given the information above we have the following cost function: C = c(labor, machinery) = $10*labor + $100*machinery 1000 = 10*x1 + 100*x2 Where C = 1000, x1 = labor, x2 = machinery

Example of Iso-Cost Line Graphically X2 = 10 – (1/10)*x1 10 x1 100

Finding the Slope of the Iso-Cost Line

Notes on Iso-Cost Line As you increase C, you shift the iso-cost line parallel out. As you change one of the costs of an input, the iso-cost line rotates.

Input Use Selection There are two ways of examining how to select the amount of each input used in production. Maximize output given a certain cost constraint Minimize cost given a fixed level of output Both give the same input selection rule.

Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Assume that we have two variable inputs (x1 and x2) which cost respectively w1 and w2. We have a total fixed cost of TFC. Assume that the general production function can be represented as y = f(x1,x2).

First Order Conditions for the Cost Minimization Problem with Two Inputs

Implication of MRTS = Slope of Iso-Cost Line Slope of iso-cost line = -w1/w2, where w2 is the cost of input 2 and w1 is cost of input 1. MRTS = -MPPx1/MPPx2 This implies MPPx1/MPPx2 = w1/w2 Which implies MPPx1 /w1 = MPPx2/w2 This means that the MPP of input 1 per dollar spent on input 1 should equal MPP of input 2 per dollar spent on input 2.

Example 1 of Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Suppose you have the following production function: y = f(x1,x2) = 10x1½ x2½ Suppose the price of input 1 is $1 and the price of input 2 is $4. Also suppose that TFC = 100. What is the optimal amount of input 1 and 2 if you want to produce 20 units.

Example 1 of Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Cont. Summary of what is known: w1 = 1, w2 = 4, TFC = 100 y = 10x1½ x2½ y = 20

Example 1 of Cost Minimization with Two Variable Inputs Cont.

Solving Example 1 Using Ratio of MPP’s Equals Absolute Value of the Slope of the Cost Function

Solving Example 1 Using MRTS from the Isoquant and Setting it Equal to the Slope of the Cost Function

Final Note on Input Selection It does not matter whether you are trying to maximize output given a fixed cost level or minimizing a cost given a fixed output level, you want to have the iso-cost line tangent to the isoquant. This implies that you will set the absolute value of MRTS equal to the absolute value of the slope of the iso-cost line.