Module Inflation: An Overview

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Measurement of Economic Performance: Inflation AP Economics Mr. Bordelon.
Advertisements

AP Economics Mr. Bernstein Module 14: Inflation: An Overview February 2, 2015.
Issues in monetary and fiscal policy In this lecture we will use our economic models to study some important issues in the use of monetary and fiscal policy.
Module Inflation: An Overview
Back to the Future GDP, Unemployment, etc..
Unit 2-3: Macro Measures 1.
1 of 35 chapter: 8 >> Krugman/Wells ©2009  Worth Publishers Inflation.
Unit 2: Macro Measures 1 Copyright ACDC Leadership 2015.
Section 3. What You Will Learn in this Module Explain the three different types of unemployment and their causes Identify the factors that determine the.
Pump Primer : Draw the long-run equilibrium in the AD/AS framework. Show what happens in the short run when AD increases Explain what happens in the long.
Inflation: An Overview How to Calculate Inflation.
Inflation Module 14.
ECO Global Macroeconomics TAGGERT J. BROOKS.
ECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells with Margaret Ray and David Anderson SECOND EDITION in MODULES.
Module Inflation: An Overview KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* 14 Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Goal #3 LIMIT INFLATION Country and Time- Zimbabwe, 2008 Annual Inflation Rate- 79,600,000,000% Time for Prices to Double hours Copyright ACDC Leadership.
Part 1: An Overview Part 2: Measures and Calculations
Introduction to Macroeconomics Chapter 17
Money Growth and Inflation
Measuring the Cost of Living
Calculating Nominal GDP, Real GDP, and Inflation
Three Causes of Inflation
Section 4 Lecture November 2016 Mr. Gammie
Inflation Who wins & loses from inflation.
Money Growth and Inflation
AP Macroeconomics Fall 2013
Unemployment Practice
Inflation.
20 Module Economic Policy and the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Model odel KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
20 Module Economic Policy and the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Model odel KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Module Inflation and Unemployment: The Phillips Curve
Module Inflation and Unemployment: The Phillips Curve
Module 28 The Money Market KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP*
Module 28 The Money Market KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP*
Tuesday, September 26 Please get out a piece of paper and number it You need your Outside Work ready for today! We will be taking notes on Inflation.
Inflation.
Please read the following License Agreement before proceeding.
Inflation: An Overview
Module Inflation: An Overview
Money, Interest, and Inflation
Section 3 Module 14.
Module Inflation and Unemployment: The Phillips Curve
Module 29 The Market for Loanable Funds KRUGMAN'S
Module 28 The Money Market KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP*
Inflation and Unemployment: The Phillips Curve
20 Module Economic Policy and the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Model odel KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Module Aggregate Demand: Introduction and Determinants
Unit 2: Macro Measures 1.
Inflation Module 14.
Module Inflation and Unemployment: The Phillips Curve
Module Aggregate Demand: Introduction and Determinants
20 Module Economic Policy and the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Model odel KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Module Types of Inflation, Disinflation, and Deflation
20 Module Economic Policy and the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Model odel KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Module 29 The Market for Loanable Funds KRUGMAN'S
Pump Primer: 29 Draw a Loanable Funds Market graph in Equilibrium.
Money Growth and Inflation
Inflation: Measuring the Cost of Living
INFLATION SSEMA1-You will illustrate the means by
The Market for Loanable Funds AP Macro Mr. Warner.
Money Growth and Inflation
Module Types of Inflation, Disinflation, and Deflation
20 Module Economic Policy and the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Model odel KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
Module 24 The Time Value of Money KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP*
Inflation Module 14.
Module Aggregate Supply: Introduction and Determinants
Module Aggregate Supply: Introduction and Determinants
Module 29 The Market for Loanable Funds KRUGMAN'S
Module Aggregate Demand: Introduction and Determinants
Presentation transcript:

Module Inflation: An Overview 14 Module Inflation: An Overview KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* Margaret Ray and David Anderson

What you will learn in this Module: The economic costs of inflation How inflation creates winners and losers Why policy makers try to maintain a stable rate of inflation The difference between real and nominal values of income, wages, and interest rates The problems of deflation and disinflation

The Level of Prices Doesn’t Matter... Misconception It’s all relative Real Wage Real Income NOTE: Economists often toss around little phrases like “there’s no such thing as a free lunch”. Another phrase that is pertinent to this material is “only relative prices matter”. Create an example to illustrate this point.   Example: A student in the class has income of $20 per week to spend on gasoline ($2 per gallon) or venti  mochachino café lattes (at $4 per cup). We can see her purchasing possibilities in a table below. The most gas she could buy: The most lattes she could buy: To buy one more latte, she must give up: 10 gallons of gas 5 cups 2 gallons of gas One gallon of gas uses up 10% of her income. One cup of mochachino uses up 20% of her income. What would happen if her income doubled and so did the price of gasoline and the price of a café latte? Absolutely nothing! The prices of gas and café lattes, relative to her income is unchanged. The price of a cup of latte, relative to the price of a gallon of gas is unchanged. Nothing REAL has changed.

...But the Rate of Change of Prices Does Inflation Rate Inflation rate = Shoe-Leather Costs Hyperinflation Menu Costs Unit-of-Account Costs Price level in year 2 - Price level in year 1 Price level in year 1 X 100 Note: refer back to the previous example.   But what if the price of gas and café lattes doubles, while the student’s income stays the same? The most gas she could buy: The most lattes she could buy: To buy one more latte, she must give up: 5 gallons of gas 2.5 cups 2 gallons of gas One gallon of gas uses up 20% of her income. One cup of mochachino uses up 40% of her income. The price of a cup of latte, relative to the price of a gallon of gas is unchanged. But! Relative to her income, these items are now twice as costly. Obviously, this price inflation has radically decreased her purchasing power because her income did not rise to keep pace. In a very REAL sense, she is worse off. What would she do? What would the sellers of gas and café lattes do? Inflation creates costs for both groups of people. 1. Shoe leather costs We might expect the student in the example above to be pretty upset about the doubling prices of two goods she really enjoys consuming. What would she do? She might spend a lot of time looking for less expensive substitutes. She might drive around town looking for a coffee shop with prices that haven’t doubled. She might decide that she needs to get her $20 of income out of her wallet (where it is quickly become worthless) and into something else that might hold value better. All of this extra time and effort comes at a cost to the consumer. Shoe leather cost is an allusion to the wear and tear caused by the extra running around that takes place when people are trying to avoid holding money. Or increased costs of transactions caused by inflation. 2. Menu Costs What would the sellers of gas and café lattes need to do? Change their menus or signs. This might not be very expensive for the gas station, they would just need to have a paid employee go outside and change the sign. But a restaurant or coffee shop might need to literally print new menus and this is pretty costly. And what if this price inflation persists? Maybe prices are rising 10% every few months and menus neeed to be constantly changed as a result. These are costs incurred by the sellers just to update the posted prices. 3. Unit-of-Account Costs The costs arising from the way inflation makes money a less reliable unit of measurement. These costs can emerge from the way in which we tax certain assets. Suppose you owned a house that was worth $100,000 and your state levied a property tax of 1% on that house. Each year you expected to pay $1000 in property taxes. Over the course of a short period of time, maybe two years, real estate prices go way, WAY up. Now your house, on paper, is worth $200,000 but it’s the very same house. It’s not a better house. Your state reassesses property taxes and now claims that you owe $2000 every year! Assuming your income didn’t double as your house was doubling in value, you are worse off because the property tax system didn’t take into account that it was inflation that caused your house to increase in value.

Winners and Losers from Inflation Nominal contracts Nominal interest rate v. real interest rate Note: Stress to students that inflation can often just redistribute money from one person to another. A good example of this can be seen when we look at borrowers and lenders.   Suppose you lend a buddy $100 and he promises you pay you back in a year. There are two reasons why it makes sense to charge him interest. 1. By providing this service to your friend, you won’t have that $100 over the next year to buy things that you enjoy. Your service, and delayed consumption, should entitle you to compensation. 2. When he pays you back, inflation will have eroded the purchasing power of the original $100. Knowing this, you should be entitled to enough interest so that inflation doesn’t hurt your purchasing power. So the interest rate should have two parts: the part to compensate you for the service you are providing, and the part that offsets the inflation that is expected to occur. Economists call the sum of these two parts the nominal interest rate: Nominal interest rate = real interest rate + expected inflation Suppose you and your friend agree that inflation next year will be 5% and you agree that your lending services are worth another 3%. You charge your friend: 8% = 3% + 5% After a year’s time, three scenarios could have happened. Scenario 1: you expected 5% inflation and you experienced exactly 5% inflation. The purchasing power of the $100 you lent was unchanged when your friend paid you back exactly enough to compensate for the inflation. Scenario 2: you expected 5% inflation and you experienced only 1% inflation. Your purchasing power has actually increased because your friend paid you back more than enough to compensate for the inflation. Note: When actual inflation is below expected inflation, the lender (in this case you) gains and the borrower loses. Scenario 3: you expected 5% inflation and you experienced 8% inflation. Your purchasing power has actually decreased because your friend paid you back less than enough to compensate for the inflation. Note: When actual inflation is above expected inflation, the lender (in this case you) loses and the borrower gains.

Inflation is Easy; Disinflation is Hard The cost of disinflation Policy response to inflation Note: the instructor can use this section to briefly preview future discussions on monetary and fiscal policy, or can skip over it for now.   A quick review of terms: Inflation is the overall rise in prices. Deflation is the overall decline in prices. Disinflation is the process of reducing rapid inflation to a smaller, less damaging, amount of inflation. Disinflation would be necessary if inflation was 10% and policy makers acted to bring it down to 3%. What is problematic about disinflation? Often a high rate of inflation is caused by “too much” money being circulated and spent in the economy. The obvious way to reduce the inflation is to act in ways to reduce the amount of money being circulated and spent. This can be painful because this will often reduce demand for goods and services and put some workers out of work. Policymakers in the US have, since the 1980s, tried to maintain a very low and stable amount of inflation so that painful corrections like this are unnecessary.