Competition and Concentration

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
Advertisements

11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
Perfect Competition 12.
Change in S vs. Change in Qs
Demand And Supply Demand
1 Chapter 3 Practice Quiz Tutorial Market Demand / Supply ©2004 South-Western.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Airlines and automobile producers are facing tough times: Prices are being slashed to drive sales and profits are turning.
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
Chapter Nine The Rise and Fall of Industries. 9 | 2 Copyright © Houghton Mifflin Company. All rights reserved. Markets and Industries Industry – A group.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition
Equilibrium and Efficiency
Chapter 28: The Labor Market: Demand, Supply and Outsourcing
slide 1Competition in the long-run In the short-run the number of firms in a competitive industry is fixed. In the long-run new firms can enter or existing.
REVENUE THEORY IB Business & Management A Course Companion 2009 THE THEORY OF THE FIRM: COSTS, REVENUES AND PROFITS.
Modern Principles: Microeconomics Tyler Cowen and Alex Tabarrok Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers Modern Principles: Microeconomics Cowen/Tabarrok Chapter.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Lecture 10: The Theory of Competitive Supply
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly ECO 2023 Chapter 11 Fall 2007.
Chapter 6 The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly.
Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and International Trade
Chapter 6.  Why does the market tend towards equilibrium?  Excess demand leads firms to raise prices, higher prices induce the quantity supplied to.
1 of 37 PART II The Market System: Choices Made by Households and Firms © 2012 Pearson Education CHAPTER OUTLINE 9 Long-Run Costs and Output Decisions.
Next page Chapter 5: The Demand for Labor. Jump to first page 1. Derived Demand for Labor.
Chapter 21.1 What is Supply?. An Introduction to Supply  Supply refers to the various quantities of a good or service that producers are willing to sell.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly 13 CHAPTER.
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
12 PERFECT COMPETITION © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
Economics Chapter 5 Supply
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 13A. After studying this chapter you will be able to Define and identify monopolistic competition Explain how output.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly 14 & 15 CHAPTER.
CHANGES IN SUPPLY Brianna Coachman. INPUT COSTS  Effects of rising costs: A supplier sets output at the most profitable level, where price is equal to.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Competition Perfect competition is an industry in which:  Many firms sell identical products to many buyers.  There.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economies of Scale, Imperfect Competition, and.
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
IB Business & Management A Course Companion 2009
3.14 Operational Strategies: location
Long Run Costs and Output Decisions Ch-9
PERFECT COMPETITION McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Economists versus accountants
Chapter 5 The Demand for Labor McGraw-Hill/Irwin
IB Economics A Course Companion 2009
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Price Takers and the Competitive Process
Perfect Competition in the Long-run
Definition of Supply Supply represents how much the market can offer. It indicates how many product producers are willing and able to produce and offer.
Capitalism as an Economic System
Aggregate Demand, Employment, and Unemployment
Government and the Economy
The Dilemmas of Macroeconomic Policy
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
THE ECONOMY: THE CORE PROJECT
CHAPTER 10 OUTLINE 10.1 Monopoly 10.2 Monopoly Power 10.3 Sources of Monopoly Power 10.4 The Social Costs of Monopoly Power 10.5 Monopsony 10.6 Monopsony.
Supply and Demand: How Markets Work
Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee
Capitalist Production and Profits
The Surplus Product: Conflict and Change
Chapter 7: Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Aim: How is price determined in the market place?
Competition and Coordination: The Invisible Hand
Firms in Competitive Markets
Market Structures I: Monopoly
Chapter 5: Pure Competition
A Three-Dimensional Approach to Economics
Chapter 4 SUPPLY AND DEMAND.
Presentation transcript:

Competition and Concentration Chapter 11 Competition and Concentration Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press

Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Figures and Tables Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press

FIGURE 11.1 Finding the selling price at which profit is highest. A business faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its output if when it raises its price it loses some, but not all, of its customers. This figure shows (a) the quantity of output (brownies) a bakery can sell per day at each price, as well as (b) the total profit, measured along the horizontal axis, that the bakery expects to make at each price level it could set for its brownies. The demand curve facing the firm may change constantly, though, as rivals offer new products, set new prices, or open new stores. In practice, setting prices often involves trial and error. Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press

Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee FIGURE 11.2 Average cost curve for an auto plant with marginal cost $10,000 per car and fixed cost $60 million per year. There are large economies of scale in the auto industry, which result in decreasing average cost as the number of cars produced (Z) increases, as panel (a) shows. Panel (b) shows a close-up of the exact same average cost curve, highlighting the fact that if the plant produces 30,000 cars a year its average cost will be $12,000 per car, but if it produces 60,000 cars, its average cost will be only $11,000. With 100,000 cars produced per year or more, the average cost falls to $10,600 or less. This allows a large-scale producer either to charge the same price as its competitors producing in smaller plants, but make more profit per car sold, or else to charge a lower price, sell more cars, and gain larger market share. Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press

FIGURE 11.3 Dynamic cost advantage. Panel (a) of this figure shows what happens when firms do not reinvest their profits. Assuming that the prices of inputs (including the wage) remain unchanged, such firms will see their unit costs remain constant from one period to the next. Panel (b) shows that when firms successfully reinvest their profits (in better equipment, for example) their unit costs fall from one period to the next—again assuming no changes in input prices. Lower unit costs will allow firms to achieve higher unit profits or reduce their prices and gain market share. Higher unit profits or lower prices (or both) will give the reinvesting firms competitive advantage over firms that do not reinvest. Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press

Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee FIGURE 11.4 Exit and entry of firms from and into markets tend to equalize profits. Low profits will drive some firms out of an initially low-profit industry. This will cause the supply of output in that industry to contract, shown in the left-hand diagram by the leftward shift of the supply curve from S1 to S2. This shift will allow the remaining firms to raise their price from P1 to P2, thus increasing their profits. Exactly the opposite happens in an initially high-profit industry (the right-hand diagram). High profits will induce new firms to enter this industry, increasing total output, so the industry supply curve will shift to the right, showing that there is more supply at each price. The higher output from entry of new firms forces all the firms in the industry to sell their output at a lower price (P2), driving their profit rates down. Thus, exit causes the profit rate to rise in low-profit industries and entry causes the profit rate to fall in high-profit industries, so the profit rates in the two industries will tend to converge. Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press

FIGURE 11.5 Diverse trends in industry concentration, 1997-2012 The degree of concentration, as measured by the four-firm concentration ratio, grew in some sectors and fell in others over the period 1997–2012. The four-firm concentration ratio shown here is the share of the top four firms in the total value of goods shipped over the year by U.S. producers in the sector. Trends vary: sectors whose concentration rose are near the top; sectors whose concentration fell are near the bottom. Sectors were selected, among those for which data were reported in the same narrow (6-digit NAICS) category of manufacturing for both 1997 and 2012, to indicate a variety of products and trends. Many sectors have lower four-firm concentration ratios (e.g., apparel industry sectors), but are not shown. Narrowly defined sectors (“Beet sugar manufacturing” but not “Food manufacturing”) tend to have higher concentration ratios. Source: U.S. Census Bureau, American Factfinder: Download the file “EC1231SR2 - Manufacturing: Subject Series: Concentration Ratios: Share of Value of Shipments Accounted for by the 4, 8, 20, and 50 Largest Companies for Industries: 2012” from https://factfinder.census.gov/faces/nav/jsf/pages/download_center.xhtml; and U.S. Census Bureau, Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing, 1997 Census, Manufacturing, Subject Series, EC97M31S-CR, Issued June 2001, available at https://www.census.gov/prod/ec97/m31s-cr.pdf. Samuel Bowles, Frank Roosevelt, Richard Edwards, Mehrene Larudee Understanding Capitalism, Fourth Edition, Copyright © 2018 Oxford University Press