The Theory of Consumer Choice

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Thomson Learning 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
Advertisements

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
WHY DOES THE DEMAND CURVE SLOPE DOWNWARD?
The Theory of Consumer Choice
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Chapter 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Consumer Preferences and
Principles of Microeconomics: Ch. 21 First Canadian Edition Overview u The budget constraint u Indifference curves u The consumer’s optimal choice u Income.
Consumer Choice CHAPTER
Consumer Choice ETP Economics 101.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
PART 7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University The Theory of Consumer Choice 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Week 8 – Economics Theory Consumer Choice. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Principles of Microeconomics
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Economic Analysis for Business Session XV: Theory of Consumer Choice (Chapter 21) Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Review of the previous lecture A consumer’s budget constraint shows the possible combinations of different goods he can buy given his income and the prices.
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
Indifference Analysis Appendix to Chapter 5. 2 Indifference Curves Indifference analysis is an alternative way of explaining consumer choice that does.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University The Market Forces of Supply and Demand 1 © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Theory of Consumer Behaviour
Elasticity: Demand and Supply CHAPTER 6 © 2016 CENGAGE LEARNING. ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. MAY NOT BE COPIED, SCANNED, OR DUPLICATED, IN WHOLE OR IN PART, EXCEPT.
SARBJEET KAUR Lecturer in Economics Indifference Curve Analysis.
The Theory of Consumer Choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Review of the previous lecture
S PP 2 T OPIC 1 I SSUE 2: C HANGE IN PRICES AFFECT CONSUMER ’ S CHOICES T HE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE Xiaozhen Chen Hai Tran.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
Copyright © 2011 Cengage Learning 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 4 The Theory.
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 21
Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves
The Theory of Consumer Choice
ECN 201: Principles of Microeconomics
The Theory of Consumer Choice
21 The Theory of Consumer Choice CHAPTER
Consumer Choice.
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
Indifference Curves Indifference curve: a curve depicting alternative combinations of goods that yield equal satisfaction. This is a mechanism for illustrating.
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
21 The Theory of Consumer Choice CHAPTER
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 16 Labour supply.
Consumer Choice Indifference Curve Theory
Preferences and Utility
Consumer Behavior Ch. 7.
Demand, Supply, and Markets
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
Firms in Competitive Markets
Consumer Choice Indifference Curve Theory
Demand and Revenue Management
Firms in Competitive Markets
Presentation transcript:

The Theory of Consumer Choice © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Budget Constraint Budget constraint Slope of the budget constraint Limit on the consumption bundles that a consumer can afford It shows the trade-off between goods Slope of the budget constraint Rate at which the consumer can trade one good for the other Relative price of the two goods © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 1 The Consumer’s Budget Constraint The budget constraint shows the various bundles of goods that the consumer can buy for a given income. Here the consumer buys bundles of pizza and Pepsi. The table and graph show what the consumer can afford if her income is $1,000, the price of pizza is $10, and the price of Pepsi is $2. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 1 The Consumer’s Budget Constraint Quantity of Pepsi B 500 C 250 50 A Quantity of Pizza 100 The budget constraint shows the various bundles of goods that the consumer can buy for a given income. Here the consumer buys bundles of pizza and Pepsi. The table and graph show what the consumer can afford if her income is $1,000, the price of pizza is $10, and the price of Pepsi is $2. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Preferences Indifference curve Slope of indifference curve Shows consumption bundles that give the consumer the same level of satisfaction Combinations of goods on the same curve Same satisfaction Slope of indifference curve Marginal rate of substitution Rate at which a consumer is willing to trade one good for another Not the same at all points © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 2 The Consumer’s Preferences Quantity of Pepsi C B D MRS I2 A 1 Indifference curve, I1 C B D MRS A 1 Quantity of Pizza The consumer’s preferences are represented with indifference curves, which show the combinations of pizza and Pepsi that make the consumer equally satisfied. Because the consumer prefers more of a good, points on a higher indifference curve (I2 here) are preferred to points on a lower indifference curve (I1). The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) shows the rate at which the consumer is willing to trade Pepsi for pizza. It measures the quantity of Pepsi the consumer must be given in exchange for 1 pizza. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Preferences Four properties of indifference curves Higher indifference curves are preferred to lower ones Higher indifference curves – more goods Indifference curves are downward sloping Indifference curves do not cross Indifference curves are bowed inward © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 3 The Impossibility of Intersecting Indifference Curves Quantity of Pepsi C A B Quantity of Pizza A situation like this can never happen. According to these indifference curves, the consumer would be equally satisfied at points A, B, and C, even though point C has more of both goods than point A. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 4 Bowed Indifference Curves Indifference curves are usually bowed inward. This shape implies that the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) depends on the quantity of the two goods the consumer is consuming. At point A, the consumer has little pizza and much Pepsi, so she requires a lot of extra Pepsi to induce her to give up one of the pizzas: The marginal rate of substitution is 6 liters of Pepsi per pizza. At point B, the consumer has much pizza and little Pepsi, so she requires only a little extra Pepsi to induce her to give up one of the pizzas: The marginal rate of substitution is 1 liter of Pepsi per pizza. Quantity of Pepsi Indifference curve 14 MRS=6 2 A 8 1 3 4 B MRS=1 6 3 1 7 Quantity of Pizza © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Preferences Extreme examples of indifference curves Perfect substitutes Two goods with straight-line indifference curves Marginal rate of substitution – constant Perfect complements Two goods with right-angle indifference curves © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 5 Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements (a) Perfect Substitutes (b) Perfect Complements Nickels 6 2 4 Left shoes I2 I1 I3 7 I2 5 5 7 I1 Dimes 1 3 2 Right shoes When two goods are easily substitutable, such as nickels and dimes, the indifference curves are straight lines, as shown in panel (a). When two goods are strongly complementary, such as left shoes and right shoes, the indifference curves are right angles, as shown in panel (b). © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Optimization Optimum Marginal rate of substitution Point where indifference curve and budget constraint touch Best combination of goods available to the consumer Slope of indifference curve Equals slope of budget constraint Marginal rate of substitution = Relative price © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 6 The Consumer’s Optimum The consumer chooses the point on her budget constraint that lies on the highest indifference curve. At this point, called the optimum, the marginal rate of substitution equals the relative price of the two goods. Here the highest indifference curve the consumer can reach is I2. The consumer prefers point A, which lies on indifference curve I3, but she cannot afford this bundle of pizza and Pepsi. By contrast, point B is affordable, but because it lies on a lower indifference curve, the consumer does not prefer it. Quantity of Pepsi Budget constraint I3 Optimum I2 I1 A B Quantity of Pizza © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Optimization Higher income Normal good Consumer can afford more of both goods Shifts the budget constraint outward New optimum Normal good Good for which an increase in income raises the quantity demanded © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 7 An Increase in Income Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint 1. An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward . . . I2 3. . . . and Pepsi consumption I1 New optimum Initial budget constraint Initial optimum 2. . . . raising pizza consumption . . . Quantity of Pizza When the consumer’s income rises, the budget constraint shifts out. If both goods are normal goods, the consumer responds to the increase in income by buying more of both of them. Here the consumer buys more pizza and more Pepsi. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Optimization Inferior good Price of one good falls Good for which an increase in income reduces the quantity demanded Price of one good falls Rotates the budget constraint outward Steeper slope Change in relative price Income effect Substitution effect © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 8 An Inferior Good Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint 1. When an increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward . . . I2 3. . . . but Pepsi consumption falls, making Pepsi an inferior good I1 Initial budget constraint Initial optimum New optimum 2. . . . pizza consumption rises, making pizza a normal good. . . Quantity of Pizza A good is inferior if the consumer buys less of it when her income rises. Here Pepsi is an inferior good: When the consumer’s income increases and the budget constraint shifts outward, the consumer buys more pizza but less Pepsi. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 9 A Change in Price Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint D 1,000 I1 New optimum 1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward. . . 3. . . . and raising Pepsi consumption B 500 Initial budget constraint Initial optimum 2. . . . reducing pizza consumption A 100 Quantity of Pizza When the price of Pepsi falls, the consumer’s budget constraint shifts outward and changes slope. The consumer moves from the initial optimum to the new optimum, which changes her purchases of both pizza and Pepsi. In this case, the quantity of Pepsi consumed rises, and the quantity of pizza consumed falls. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Optimization Income effect Change in consumption When a price change moves the consumer To a higher or lower indifference curve © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Optimization Substitution effect Change in consumption When a price change moves the consumer Along a given indifference curve To a point with a new marginal rate of substitution © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Table 1 Income and Substitution Effects When the Price of Pepsi Falls © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 10 Income and Substitution Effects The effect of a change in price can be broken down into an income effect and a substitution effect. The substitution effect—the movement along an indifference curve to a point with a different marginal rate of substitution—is shown here as the change from point A to point B along indifference curve I1. The income effect—the shift to a higher indifference curve—is shown here as the change from point B on indifference curve I1 to point C on indifference curve I2. Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint I2 I1 New optimum C Income effect B Initial budget constraint Substitution effect Initial optimum A Quantity of Pizza Substitution effect Income effect © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Optimization Deriving the demand curve Quantity demanded of a good for any given price Initial optimum point Initial price of the good Initial quantity of the good A change in price of the good (new price) New optimum New optimum quantity © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.

Figure 11 Deriving the Demand Curve (a) The Consumer’s Optimum (b) The Demand Curve for Pepsi Quantity of Pepsi Price of Pepsi New budget constraint I2 B A $2 Demand 750 250 I1 B Initial budget constraint 1 A 750 250 Quantity of Pizza Quantity of Pepsi Panel (a) shows that when the price of Pepsi falls from $2 to $1, the consumer’s optimum moves from point A to point B, and the quantity of Pepsi consumed rises from 250 to 750 liters. The demand curve in panel (b) reflects this relationship between the price and the quantity demanded. © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use.