A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 Interest Rate Determination Here we start with an example and end with a theory of changes in the interest rate.
Advertisements

Chapter 4 Lecture - Consumption, Saving, and Investment
Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account Part 2.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
Unit 1: Trade Theory Standard Trade Model 2/6/2012.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Consumption, Saving, and Investment
Changes in Income An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel manner An increase in income will cause the budget constraint.
Consumption, Saving, and Investment
Review of the Previous Lecture
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER SIXTEEN.
MACROECONOMICS © 2010 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved S E V E N T H E D I T I O N PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw C H A P.
CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 0 Class Slides for EC 204 To Accompany Chapter 16.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 13: Consumption.
Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 8 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption– Savings Decision and Credit Markets.
Consumption Prof Mike Kennedy. Where we are going? Here we will be looking at two major components of aggregate demand: – Aggregate consumption or what.
Consumer Choice ETP Economics 101.
7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright©2004 South-Western 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
PART 7 TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY. Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
The Theory of Consumer Choice
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
This chapter presents:
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
The Theory of Individual Behavior. Overview I. Consumer Behavior n Indifference Curve Analysis n Consumer Preference Ordering II. Constraints n The Budget.
Chapter 16: Consumption.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Theory of Consumer Behaviour
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
Chapter 19 Appendix: Indifference Curves McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 13e.
Chapter 8 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption- Savings Decision and Ricardian Equivalence.
Lecture 3 Consumption. John M. Keynes: Absolute Income Hypothesis Consumption is a linear function of disposable personal income, C = C + cY C = consumption.
S PP 2 T OPIC 1 I SSUE 2: C HANGE IN PRICES AFFECT CONSUMER ’ S CHOICES T HE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE Xiaozhen Chen Hai Tran.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
Chapter overview This chapter surveys the most prominent work on consumption: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher and Intertemporal.
The Standard Trade Model
Consumption Topic 13: (chapter 16)
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 21
Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Indifference Curves Indifference curve: a curve depicting alternative combinations of goods that yield equal satisfaction. This is a mechanism for illustrating.
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice
Chapter 9 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption-Savings Decision and Credit Markets Macroeconomics 6th Edition Stephen D. Williamson Copyright © 2018, 2015,
CH6:Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Asst. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Asst. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN
Consumer Behavior Ch. 7.
Utility Functions, Budget Lines and Consumer Demand
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Indifference Curve Analysis
Abel & Bernake: Macro Ch3 Varian: Micro Ch10
Consumer Preferences, Utility Functions
Irving Fisher and Intertemporal Choice
Presentation transcript:

A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving

How Much Can the Consumer Afford? The Budget Constraint Current income y; future income yf; initial wealth a Choice variables: af = wealth at beginning of future period; c = current consumption; cf = future consumption af = (y + a – c)(1 + r), so cf = (y + a – c)(1 + r) + yf (4.A.1) This is the budget constraint

How Much Can the Consumer Afford? The Budget Constraint The budget line Graph budget line in (c, cf) space (Fig. 4.A.1) Slope of line = – (1 + r)

Figure 4.A.1 The budget Line

Present Values Present value is the value of payments to be made in the future in terms of today’s dollars or goods Example: At an interest rate of 10%, $12,000 today invested for one year is worth $13,200 ($12,000  1.10); so the present value of $13,200 in one year is $12,000 General formula: Present value = future value/(1 + i), where amounts are in dollar terms and i is the nominal interest rate Alternatively, if amounts are in real terms, use the real interest rate r instead of the nominal interest rate i

Present Value and the Budget Constraint Present value of lifetime resources: PVLR = y + yf/(1+r) + a (4.A.2) Present value of lifetime consumption: PVLC = c + cf/(1+r) The budget constraint means PVLC = PVLR c + cf/(1+r) = y + yf/(1+r) + a (4.A.3) Horizontal intercept of budget line is c = PVLR, cf = 0

What Does the Consumer Want? Consumer Preferences Utility = a person’s satisfaction or well-being Graph a person’s preference for current versus future consumption using indifference curves An indifference curve shows combinations of c and cf that give the same utility (Fig. 4.A.2)

Figure 4.A.2 Indifference curves

What Does the Consumer Want? Consumer Preferences A person is equally happy at any point on an indifference curve Three important properties of indifference curves Slope downward from left to right: Less consumption in one period requires more consumption in the other period to keep utility unchanged Indifference curves that are farther up and to the right represent higher levels of utility, because more consumption is preferred to less Indifference curves are bowed toward the origin, because people have a consumption-smoothing motive, they prefer consuming equal amounts in each period rather than consuming a lot one period and little the other period

The Optimal Level of Consumption Optimal consumption point is where the budget line is tangent to an indifference curve (Fig. 4.A.3) That’s the highest indifference curve that it’s possible to reach All other points on the budget line are on lower indifference curves

Figure 4.A.3 The optimal consumption combination

The Effects of Changes in Income and Wealth on Consumption and Saving The effect on consumption of a change in income (current or future) or wealth depends only on how the change affects the PVLR An increase in current income (Fig. 4.A.4) Increases PVLR, so shifts budget line out parallel to old budget line If there is a consumption-smoothing motive, both current and future consumption will increase Then both consumption and saving rise because of the rise in current income

Figure 4.A.4 An increase in income or wealth

The Effects of Changes in Income and Wealth on Consumption and Saving The effect on consumption of a change in income (current or future) or wealth depends only on how the change affects the PVLR An increase in future income Same outward shift in budget line as an increase in current income Again, with consumption smoothing, both current and future consumption increase Now saving declines, since current income is unchanged and current consumption increases An increase in wealth Same parallel shift in budget line, so both current and future consumption rise Again, saving declines, since c rises and y is unchanged

The Effects of Changes in Income and Wealth on Consumption and Saving The permanent income theory Different types of changes in income Temporary increase in income: y rises and yf is unchanged Permanent increase in income: Both y and yf rise

The Effects of Changes in Income and Wealth on Consumption and Saving The permanent income theory Permanent income increase causes bigger increase in PVLR than a temporary income increase So current consumption will rise more with a permanent income increase So saving from a permanent increase in income is less than from a temporary increase in income

The Effects of Changes in Income and Wealth on Consumption and Saving The permanent income theory This distinction between permanent and temporary income changes was made by Milton Friedman in the 1950s and is known as the permanent income theory Permanent changes in income lead to much larger changes in consumption Thus permanent income changes are mostly consumed, while temporary income changes are mostly saved

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Life-cycle model was developed by Franco Modigliani and associates in the 1950s Looks at patterns of income, consumption, and saving over an individual’s lifetime Typical consumer’s income and saving pattern shown in Fig. 4.A.5

Figure 4.A.5 Life-cycle consumption, income, and saving

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Real income steadily rises over time until near retirement; at retirement, income drops sharply Lifetime pattern of consumption is much smoother than the income pattern In reality, consumption varies somewhat by age For example, when raising children, household consumption is higher than average The model can easily be modified to handle this and other variations

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Saving has the following lifetime pattern Saving is low or negative early in working life Maximum saving occurs when income is highest (ages 50 to 60) Dissaving occurs in retirement

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Bequests and saving What effect does a bequest motive (a desire to leave an inheritance) have on saving? Simply consume less and save more than without a bequest motive

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Ricardian equivalence We can use the two-period model to examine Ricardian equivalence The two-period model shows that consumption is changed only if the PVLR changes Suppose the government reduces taxes by 100 in the current period, the interest rate is 10%, and taxes will be increased by 110 in the future period Then the PVLR is unchanged, and thus there is no change in consumption

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Excess sensitivity and borrowing constraints Generally, theories about consumption, including the permanent income theory, have been supported by looking at real-world data But some researchers have found that the data show that the impact of an income or wealth change is different than that implied by a change in the PVLR There seems to be excess sensitivity of consumption to changes in current income This could be due to short-sighted behavior Or it could be due to borrowing constraints

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Excess sensitivity and borrowing constraints Borrowing constraints mean people can’t borrow as much as they want Lenders may worry that a consumer won’t pay back the loan, so they won’t lend If a person wouldn’t borrow anyway, the borrowing constraint is said to be nonbinding But if a person wants to borrow and can’t, the borrowing constraint is binding

Consumption and Saving Over Many Periods: The Life-Cycle Model Excess sensitivity and borrowing constraints A consumer with a binding borrowing constraint spends all income and wealth on consumption So an increase in income or wealth will be entirely spent on consumption as well This causes consumption to be excessively sensitive to current income changes How prevalent are borrowing constraints? Perhaps 20% to 50% of the U.S. population faces binding borrowing constraints

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The real interest rate and the budget line (Fig. 4.A.6) When the real interest rate rises, one point on the old budget line is also on the new budget line: the no-borrowing, no-lending point Slope of new budget line is steeper

Figure 4.A.6 The effect of an increase in the real interest rate on the budget line

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The substitution effect A higher real interest rate makes future consumption cheaper relative to current consumption Increasing future consumption and reducing current consumption increases saving Suppose a person is at the no-borrowing, no-lending point when the real interest rate rises (Fig. 4.A.7) An increase in the real interest rate unambiguously leads the person to increase future consumption and decrease current consumption The increase in saving, equal to the decrease in current consumption, represents the substitution effect

Figure 4.A.7 The substitution effect of an increase in the real interest rate

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The income effect If a person is planning to consume at the no-borrowing, no-lending point, then a rise in the real interest rate leads just to a substitution effect But if a person is planning to consume at a different point than the no-borrowing, no-lending point, there is also an income effect

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The income effect The intuition of the income effect If the person originally planned to be a lender, the rise in the real interest rate gives the person more income in the future period; the income effect works in the opposite direction of the substitution effect, since more future income increases current consumption If the person originally planned to be a borrower, the rise in the real interest rate gives the person less income in the future period; the income effect works in the same direction as the substitution effect, since less future income reduces current consumption further

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The income and substitution effects together Split the change in the budget line into two parts (Fig. 4.A.8) A budget line with the same slope as the new budget line, but going through the original consumption point (BLint) The substitution effect is shown by the change from budget line BL1 to budget line BLint, with the consumption point changing from point D to point P The income effect is shown by the change from budget line BLint to budget line BL2, with consumption point changing from point P to point Q

Figure 4.A.8 An increase in the real interest rate with both an income effect and a substitution effect

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The income and substitution effects together The substitution effect decreases current consumption, but the income effect increases current consumption; so saving may increase or decrease Both effects increase future consumption For a borrower, both effects decrease current consumption, so saving definitely increases but the effect on future consumption is ambiguous

The Real Interest Rate and the Consumption-Saving Decision The income and substitution effects together The effect on aggregate saving of a rise in the real interest rate is ambiguous theoretically Empirical research suggests that saving increases But the effect is small