Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Social welfare and price changes Udayan Roy ECO61 Microeconomic Analysis Fall 2008.
Advertisements

Consumer’s and Producer’s Surpluses
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  Suppose you know you can buy as much gasoline as you choose at a given price.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Welfare measurement: individual CS, CV, EV and PS
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Welfare measures: CS, CV, EV and PS (Course Micro-economics) Ch 14 Varian Teachers: Jongeneel/Van Mouche.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
How much is a consumer hurt by an increase in price (like a tax)? Three Methods to measure this: Change Consumer Surplus. Compensating Variation –The amount.
Frank Cowell: Consumer Welfare CONSUMER: WELFARE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July Almost essential Consumer Optimisation.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Consumer: Welfare MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Firm: Optimisation Consumption: Basics.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Frank Cowell: EC202 Microeconomics Revision Lecture 2 EC202: Microeconomic Principles II Frank Cowell May 2008.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Exercise 4.12 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell November 2006.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus How to estimate preferences or utility from demand A discrete good with quasilinear utility u(x,y)=v(x)+y where y is money.
Chapter 5 The Theory Of Demand.
Consumer & producer surplusslide 1 Analysis of Competitive Markets In this section, we examine the social welfare implications of competitive markets.
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Chapter 13 – Taxation and Efficiency
Taxation and Efficiency
Introduction Are people unaffected by a tax increase if they pay zero in taxes afterwards? No, consumption may have changed in response to the tax increase.
Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus
Chapter 1 The Market Key Concept: Pareto Efficiency (如果能皆大歡喜那為什麼不做呢?)
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of markets
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 21
How much is a consumer hurt by an increase in price (like a tax)?
Chapter 6 Demand Key Concept: the demand function x1 (p1, p2, m)
Consumer Choice and Demand
L08 Buying and Selling.
Chapter 32 Exchange Key Concept: Pareto optimum and Market Equilibrium
Chapter 5 Choice Key Concept: Optimal choice means a consumer chooses the best he can afford. Tangency is neither necessary nor sufficient. The correct.
Measuring Welfare Changes of Individuals
Chapter 3 - Tools of Normative Analysis
Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be.
Systems Analysis Methods
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Consumer Choice and Demand
UNIVERSITY OF LUSAKA FACULTY OF ECONOMICS, BUSINESS AND MANAGEMENT
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
L08 Buying and Selling.
L08 Buying and Selling.
L08 Buying and Selling.
Indifference Analysis
L08 Buying and Selling.
14 Consumer’s Surplus.
L08 Buying and Selling.
Chapter Ten Intertemporal Choice.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
Microeconomics Corso E
ECONOMIC ROLES Unit 2, Part 1
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
L08 Buying and Selling.
Walter Nicholson Christopher Snyder
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods.
Chapter 8 Slutsky Equation
Chapter 37 Public Goods Key Concept: Free Riding.
Chapter 9 Buying and Selling.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter 2 Budget Constraint
The Market Mechanism – Supply and Demand
Chapter 34 Welfare Key Concept: Arrow’s impossibility theorem, social welfare functions Limited support of how market preserves fairness.
DEV 501: THE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE
EE/Econ 458 Introduction to Economics: Consumer’s Surplus
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus Key Concept: For quasilinear preferences, the area under the demand curve is the change in utility if the consumer can get the goods for free. Consumer’s surplus is the area that lies between the demand and the price. It represents the change in utility from not consuming to consuming.

Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus How to estimate preferences or utility from choice? We have learned the revealed preference approach. We now look at how to estimate utility from demand.

A discrete good with quasilinear utility u(x,y)=v(x)+y where y is money to be spent on other goods its price is normalized to be 1.

Have seen before that the consumer will start to buy the first unit at the r1 so that v(1)+m- r1 = v(0)+m r1 = v(1)-v(0)

Following this logic r1 = v(1)-v(0) r2 = v(2)-v(1) r3 = v(3)-v(2) and so on.

Therefore, if we sum the area under the demand curve say up to the third unit, then we get r1 + r2 + r3 =v(3)-v(0).

Fig. 14.1

r1 + r2 + r3 =v(3)-v(0). This is the change in utility due to the increase in consumption of x. If the consumer can get these three units for free, then his utility change, from consuming zero unit to consuming three units for free, will be v(3)+m-[v(0)+m] = v(3)-v(0) exactly the area under the demand.

Suppose the price of x is p, then the utility change when the consumer buys three units of x is v(3)+m-3p-[v(0)+m] =v(3)-v(0)-3p. This is the area that lies between the demand and the price up to three units. It is called the consumer’s surplus.

Fig. 14.1

Alternatively, can think in the following way. For the first unit, the consumer is willing to pay up to r1 but he only pays p, so there is this surplus r1 –p for the first unit. Similarly, there is a surplus of r2 –p for the second unit and r3 –p for the third unit.

So when he consumes 3 units, his consumer’s surplus is r1-p+r2-p+r3-p = v(3)-v(0)-3p.

For a continuous demand, we could use the discrete approximation. Or we solve max v(x)+y s.t. px+y=m.

Fig. 14.2

MRSxy = v’(x)/1 = p/1. so plotting the inverse demand (the price) is the same as plotting v’(x).

If the consumer consumes up to 3 units, then his change in utility is v(3)+m-3p-[v(0)+m] =v(3)-v(0)-3p =∫03v’(x)dx-3p. This is the area that lies between the demand curve and the price, up to three units, and is the consumer’s surplus.

Fig. 14.2

Interpret the change in consumer’s surplus the same way. CS(3) is her utility of buying 3 units minus her utility of not buying. CS(4) is her utility of buying 4 units minus her utility of not buying. So CS(4)-CS(3) is her utility of buying 4 units minus her utility of buying 3 units.

Suppose the price changes from p’ to p’’. Accordingly the consumer changes consumption from x’ to x’’. CS (x’) is the change of utility from not buying to buying x’ units. CS (x’’) is the change of utility from not buying to buying x’’ units.

Hence the difference CS(x’)-CS(x’’) is the change of utility from buying x’ units to buying x’’ units. It consists of a rectangular area and a roughly triangular area.

Fig. 14.3

Consumer’s surplus is tidy in quasilinear utility. Even if utility is not quasilinear, consumer’s surplus may still be a reasonable measure of consumer’s welfare in may applications.

But if an approximation is not good enough, we may want to measure utility changes without using consumer’s surplus. We will introduce two monetary measures of utility.

These two concepts lead to measurement of the welfare change expressed in dollar units.

 

Fig. 14.4 *

 

Alternatively, we can ask how much money would have to be taken away from the consumer before the price increase to leave him as well off as he would be after the price increase. This is called the equivalent variation (EV).

Fig. 14.4 *

This is measuring the two indifference curves by p This is measuring the two indifference curves by p*. (mention three lines)

One example. u(x,y)=x0.5y0.5 and price of y is 1. Suppose price of x changes from 1 to 2. Income is 100. CV:500.5500.5 = (0.5m/2) 0.5(0.5m/1) 0.5 m=141 You have to give the consumer additional 41 dollars to make him as well off as before.

One example. u(x,y)=x0.5y0.5 and price of y is 1. Suppose price of x changes from 1 to 2. Income is 100. EV: 250.5500.5 =(0.5m/1) 0.5(0.5m/1) 0.5 m=70 You have to take 30 dollars away from the consumer to make him as well off as after the price change.

Can you guess which utility function will make CV and EV the same?

For quasilinear preferences, the indifference curves are parallel. It does not matter which price vector we use to measure the distance between two indifference curves. CV and EV will be the same.

Fig. 14.5

Using the same example, suppose the consumer’s consumption changes from x to x’ (with some abuse of notation).

CV v(x)+m-px = v(x’)+m-p’x’+C C = [v(x)- px]-[v(x’)-p’x’] EV v(x)+m-px-E = v(x’)+m-p’x’ E = [v(x)- px]-[v(x’)-p’x’] =C =-ΔCS

Producer’s surplus can be approached the same way. Think of selling endowment. Suppose a consumer has n units of good x. When will he start selling the first unit of x? v(n)+m=v(n-1)+m+r1. So r1=v(n)-v(n-1).

Similarly, he will start selling the second unit at v(n-1)+m+r2 = v(n-2)+m+2r2 r2=v(n-1)-v(n-2).

Hence if for the first unit, he is selling at r1, then he is indifferent between selling or not selling. If the market price is p, then he gets a surplus of p-r1 for the first unit. Thus the area between the price and the supply curve measures the producer’s surplus from selling, compared to not selling.

Fig. 14.6

When moving from consumer’s surplus to consumers’ surplus, we can aggregate the consumer’s surplus across consumers.

Yet we may care about the distribution of the welfare change, i. e Yet we may care about the distribution of the welfare change, i.e., which consumer gets better off and which gets worse off. A tax change making the poor better off may be preferred by the society to that making the rich better off, for instance.

To evaluate policies, we may use the convenient measures of CV and EV. Suppose a policy change makes A worse off by 3 dollars and B better off by 4 dollars using the CV measure, then we may want to do it depending on who A and B are. (mention redistribution)

Some comments on CS. Budget constraint may kick in. Look at the case where u(x,y)=x1/2+y and m=1. r4 should be 41/2-31/2=0.2679, but 4r4>1. Look at some other utility function say u(x,y)=x0.5y0.5, the price of y is 1 and income 100. The demand curve is x=50/px. If px changes from 2 to 1, the increase of utility is 500.5500.5 - 250.5500.5=14.6447. Yet the change of CS is ∫5025(50/x)dx=34.6574.

Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus Key Concept: For quasilinear preferences, the area under the demand curve is the change in utility if the consumer can get the goods for free. Consumer’s surplus is the area that lies between the demand and the price. It represents the change in utility from not consuming to consuming.