Diego Prior Dpt. of Business

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Efficiency and Productivity Measurement: Index Numbers
Advertisements

Efficiency and Productivity Measurement: Index Numbers
1 Index Numbers Summary measures of change over time or differences in levels in set of related variables –Price index numbers – output and input price.
University of Queensland. Australia
Index Numbers.
1 1 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Chapter 17 Index Numbers n Price Relatives n Aggregate Price Indexes n Computing an Aggregate.
Chapter 10 Index analysis. The concept and classification of index A statistical indicator providing a representation of the value of the securities which.
The Reconciliation of Industry Productivity Measures with National Measures: An Exact Translog Approach EMG Workshop 2006 December 13, 2006 Erwin Diewert.
Systems of Index Numbers for International Price Comparisons Based on the Stochastic Approach Gholamreza Hajargasht D.S. Prasada Rao Centre for Efficiency.
1 Economics 122a Fall 2010 Agenda for this week: 1. The classical macro model (Chap 3) 2. How economists measure output/income (Chap 2)
Module 15 The Measurement & Calculation of Inflation
United Nations Statistics Division/DESA International Recommendations for the Index of Industrial Production (IIP)
1 Now Playing: The Biggest Hit in Economics: The Gross Domestic Product Starring Irving Fisher (Yale) Simon Kuznets (Harvard) Steve Landefeld (U.S. Bureau.
Lecture 15 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini Main Macroeconomic Aggregates (II)
Economic Indexes Indexes in statistics Indexes are indicators of size comparison of any socio-economic process. Index number measures how much a variable.
Index Numbers Chapter 15 McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Linier Programming By Agustina Shinta. What is it? LP is essentially a mathematical technique for solving a problem that has certain characteristics.
Nobel Prize - Economics Three Amigos Eugene Fama - U. Chicago Lars Peter Hansen - U. Chicago Robert Shiller - Yale Financial Economics American.
1 Now Playing: The Biggest Hit in Economics: The Gross Domestic Product.
Constant Price Estimates Expert Group Meeting on National Accounts Cairo May 12-14, 2009 Presentation points.
CHAPTER 17: Index Numbers to accompany Introduction to Business Statistics third edition, by Ronald M. Weiers Presentation by Priscilla Chaffe-Stengel.
Composite Price Index  Unweighted Aggregative method  Unweighted Average of Relatives method  Weighted Aggregative Method  Paasche Index  Laspeyres.
1 1 Slide Slides Prepared by JOHN S. LOUCKS St. Edward’s University © 2002 South-Western/Thomson Learning 
18- 1 Chapter Eighteen McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 6 Index numbers. Index Numbers Index numbers allow relative comparisons over time It measures the percentage change in the value of some economic.
INDEX NUMBERS Definition of Index Number l A summary measure that states a relative comparison between groups of related items l Price Relative or Percentage.
Ka-fu Wong © 2003 Chap Dr. Ka-fu Wong ECON1003 Analysis of Economic Data.
Measuring and Decomposing the Productivity Growth of Beef and Sheep Farms in New Zealand using the Malmquist Productivity Index ( ) Allan Rae and.
Capital Input in OECD Agriculture: A Multilateral Comparison V. Eldon Ball, W. A. Lindamood, and Richard Nehring Economic Research Service U.S. Department.
United Nations Economic Commission for Europe Statistical Division Producer Price Indices - Recommendations of international manuals Joint EFTA/UNECE/SSCU.
Gregory Mankiw. Three Macroeconomic Variables 1. Real GDP- A. It grows overtime. B. It is not steady 2. Inflation Rate- 3. Unemployment rate A. Varies.
Lecture 9 – academic year 2013/14 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini Main Macroeconomic Aggregates (II)
The Measurement of Nonmarket Sector Outputs and Inputs Using Cost Weights 2008 World Congress on National Accounts and Economic Performance Measures for.
Index numbers Value-, price-, quantity indices. Measuring changes in time Indices: relative change in price, quantity and value of products or services.
 Definition  Unweighted and Weighted Index Numbers ( Simple Index Numbers, Laspeyre’s, Paasche’s Index, Fisher’s “Ideal” Index)  CPI ( Consumer Price.
2015/2016 Introduction to Economics Augusto Ninni Main Macroeconomic Aggregates (II)
Two major points to discuss today: 1. Equilibrium v. identity 2. Solving the index number problem 1.
Workshop on Price Index Compilation Issues February 23-27, 2015
INDEX NUMBERS An index number measures the relative change in price, quantity, value, or some other items of interest from one time period to another.
Slide 0 Chapter 2: The Data of Macroeconomics. slide 1 Gross Domestic Product (GDP) the Consumer Price Index (CPI Unemployment rate.
Copyright © 2004 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
1 ICP PPP Methods Regional Course on Price Statistics and ICP Male, Maldives September 2005 TIMOTHY LO Statistician, International Comparison Program.
Comparison of Estimation Methods for Agricultural Productivity Yu Sheng ABARES the Superlative vs. the Quantity- based Index Approach August 2015.
INDEX NUMBERS. Index Number 2  An index number is a statistical measure designed to show changes in variables or a group of related variables with respect.
The Measurement and Calculation of Inflation Market Baskets and Price Indices.
1 D. S. Prasada Rao, Alicia N. Rambaldi and Bert M. Balk Fourth World KLEMS Conference Madrid, May 2016 On Measuring Regional or Global Growth and.
Index of Industrial Production: Methods of Compilation
Definition According to Morris Hamburg defined, an index number is nothing more than a relative number, which expresses are relationship between two.
Forecasting Methods Dr. T. T. Kachwala.
MICROECONOMICS.
ECON 201 Indices Week
John Loucks St. Edward’s University . SLIDES . BY.
Value-, price-, quantity indices
Index Numbers Chapter 15.
Jan de Haan Bert M. Balk Carsten Boldsen Hansen
Index Numbers Chapter 15.
Chapter Eighteen McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Index Numbers Chapter 15.
Module The Measurement and Calculation of Inflation
The Measurement and Calculation of Inflation
Price and Volume Measures
Index Numbers Chapter 15.
Index Numbers Chapter 15.
Chapter Eighteen McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Price and Volume Measures
Derivatives and Differentiation
Chapter 3 INDEX NUMBERS Dr. A. PHILIP AROKIADOSS Assistant Professor
INDEX NUMBERS.
Rebasing and Linking of National Accounts
Price and Volume Measures
Presentation transcript:

Diego Prior Dpt. of Business Productive efficiency and innovation Lesson 2. Output and input measurement: Partial productivity measures and aggregation Diego Prior Dpt. of Business

Outline for today 2.1. Measuring outputs and inputs. 2.2. Partial productivity indicators. 2.3 TFP indices. 2.4. Applications. Fare et al 1994, OECD and MPI (regional concept) Coelli and Rao (2005) Ag Economics 95 countries Ag productivity using MPI technical efficiency, which reflects the ability of a firm to obtain maximal output from a given set of inputs.

2.1. Measuring outputs and inputs. What is Production? Transformation of resources (inputs) into products and services (outputs).   Examples: Agriculture: Grain farming Inputs: land; labour; biochemical input (fertiliser, pesticides, seeds); capital (equipment, power and buildings). Output: corn, soybeans, wheat. Industry: Cement production Inputs: energy in calories; blue and white-collar workers (man hours/year); book value of machinery and equipment; raw materials (especially: limestone). Output: cement production per year (tonnes). Services: Urban transport with busses Inputs: staff; fuel; vehicles. Output: vehicle kilometres.

Problems: Sometimes there are positive or negative external effects in production. Example: Electricity generation using fossil fuels creates pollutants like sulphur dioxide and nitrogen oxide. The internal organisation of production processes (including decision-making across different hierarchical levels, intermediate production stages, etc.) is ignored (black box models). Problem of accurate measurement of inputs and outputs. Example: Labour in agriculture should include farm family members.

Richard Murray (1992), Measuring Public-Sector Output:   Throughput Measures workloads and may even come close to input (number of cases) Output Goods or services delivered (number of cases handled) Outcome The result from the point of view of the principal or the customers Bradford, Malt and Oates (1969): Intermediate outputs : hours of service delivered D-output : direct output consumed C-output : outcome indicator reflecting the degree to which the direct outputs translate into welfare improvements as perceived by consumers

Measuring the inputs:  

2.2. Partial productivity indicators. Source: Prior, D. Vergés, J. and Vilardell, I. (1993), La evaluación de la eficiencia en el sector privado y en el sector público, Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Madrid

2.3. TFP indices (American Productivity Center proposal):

2.3. TFP indices. When we have just one input and output the TFP change between period 1 and 2 is: When we have more inputs and outputs we must aggregate using index numbers A basic property of any TFP index is that when q2=aq1 and x2=bx1, then TFP12=a/b Also, productivity = using less inputs to produce a particular level of output. Productivity is a relative concept - between two time periods or two firms, etc. The TFP change between period 1 and 2 is equal to the TFP index in year 2 over the TFP index in year 1 - or the ratio of the output change index over the input change index. See the example on the next slide.

Index number formulae When we have more than one input or output we need to find an aggregation method Four most popular indices are: Laspeyres (prices dependent) Paasche (prices dependent) Fisher (prices dependent) Divisia/Tornqvist (good property: connected with production theory) PIN can be used for TFP measurement - and also for constructing aggregate input and output variables for use in SFA and DEA. Laspeyres, Paasche, Fisher, Tornqvist are the most commonly used index number formula (eg. CPI, etc.). Selection of best index number formula often based on economic theory or axiomatic arguments (or practical issues). Tornqvist is most often used for TFP measurement. Simple numerical example from the railways data in Coelli, Estache, Perelman and Trujillo (2000). Indirect quantity indices = value / price index. Chaining used to accumulate changes over time. Transitivity (consistency) required in spatial comparisons. Computer example uses TFPIP program - can also use Excel, Shazam, etc.

Price Index Numbers Measure changes (or levels) in prices of a set of commodities. Let pmj and qmj represent prices and quantities (m-th commodity; m = 1,2,...,M and j-th period or firm j = s, t). The index number poblem is to decompose value change into price and quantity change components. Fare et al 1994, OECD and MPI (regional concept) Coelli and Rao (2005) Ag Economics 95 countries Ag productivity using MPI technical efficiency, which reflects the ability of a firm to obtain maximal output from a given set of inputs.

Laspeyres price index numbers Price change index for N goods from period s to period t pit = price of i-th good in t-th period, qit = quantity Uses base-period (period s) quantity weights Share-weighted sum of individual price indices Very popular in CPI calculations Best to start with price indices because we are familiar with them - eg. the consumer price index (CPI). Price change from period s to period t. Note: p=price, q=quantity, =value share. An unweighted index will not be independent of units of measurement and may not be representative - see bread and beef example on next slide. Laspeyres uses base quantities as weights, while Paasche uses comparison period quantities. These indices can be interpreted as the change in the cost of a particular basket of goods. Many countries use a fixed-base Laspeyres index to measure the CPI because it is expensive to re-estimate the shares every period - this is usually done every 5 years or so - but quantity weights can quickly change (eg. computers, travel) When price changes induce demand changes the Laspeyres will overstate the price change while the Pasche will understate it - the true index lies between the two extremes. Fisher is geometric average- and hence may be a good approximation. The Tornqvist uses share weights from both periods - often expressed in log-change form for calculation. Tornqvist is geometric weighted average, while Laspeyres and Paasche are arithmetic and harmonic averages, respectively.

Paasche price index numbers Uses current-period (period t) quantity weights Share-weighted harmonic mean of individual price indices Paasche  Laspeyres - when people respond to relative price changes by adjusting mix of goods purchased (in periods of inflation) Best to start with price indices because we are familiar with them - eg. the consumer price index (CPI). Price change from period s to period t. Note: p=price, q=quantity, =value share. An unweighted index will not be independent of units of measurement and may not be representative - see bread and beef example on next slide. Laspeyres uses base quantities as weights, while Paasche uses comparison period quantities. These indices can be interpreted as the change in the cost of a particular basket of goods. Many countries use a fixed-base Laspeyres index to measure the CPI because it is expensive to re-estimate the shares every period - this is usually done every 5 years or so - but quantity weights can quickly change (eg. computers, travel) When price changes induce demand changes the Laspeyres will overstate the price change while the Pasche will understate it - the true index lies between the two extremes. Fisher is geometric average- and hence may be a good approximation. The Tornqvist uses share weights from both periods - often expressed in log-change form for calculation. Tornqvist is geometric weighted average, while Laspeyres and Paasche are arithmetic and harmonic averages, respectively.

Fisher price index numbers Fisher index is the geometric mean of the Laspeyres and Paasche index numbers Paasche  Fisher  Laspeyres - when consumers respond to relative price changes by adjusting mix of goods purchased (in periods of inflation) Best to start with price indices because we are familiar with them - eg. the consumer price index (CPI). Price change from period s to period t. Note: p=price, q=quantity, =value share. An unweighted index will not be independent of units of measurement and may not be representative - see bread and beef example on next slide. Laspeyres uses base quantities as weights, while Paasche uses comparison period quantities. These indices can be interpreted as the change in the cost of a particular basket of goods. Many countries use a fixed-base Laspeyres index to measure the CPI because it is expensive to re-estimate the shares every period - this is usually done every 5 years or so - but quantity weights can quickly change (eg. computers, travel) When price changes induce demand changes the Laspeyres will overstate the price change while the Pasche will understate it - the true index lies between the two extremes. Fisher is geometric average- and hence may be a good approximation. The Tornqvist uses share weights from both periods - often expressed in log-change form for calculation. Tornqvist is geometric weighted average, while Laspeyres and Paasche are arithmetic and harmonic averages, respectively.

Tornqvist price index numbers Share-weighted geometric mean of individual price indices Uses average of value share from period t and period s Log form is commonly used in calculations - has an approximate percentage change interpretation Best to start with price indices because we are familiar with them - eg. the consumer price index (CPI). Price change from period s to period t. Note: p=price, q=quantity, =value share. An unweighted index will not be independent of units of measurement and may not be representative - see bread and beef example on next slide. Laspeyres uses base quantities as weights, while Paasche uses comparison period quantities. These indices can be interpreted as the change in the cost of a particular basket of goods. Many countries use a fixed-base Laspeyres index to measure the CPI because it is expensive to re-estimate the shares every period - this is usually done every 5 years or so - but quantity weights can quickly change (eg. computers, travel) When price changes induce demand changes the Laspeyres will overstate the price change while the Pasche will understate it - the true index lies between the two extremes. Fisher is geometric average- and hence may be a good approximation. The Tornqvist uses share weights from both periods - often expressed in log-change form for calculation. Tornqvist is geometric weighted average, while Laspeyres and Paasche are arithmetic and harmonic averages, respectively.

Quantity Index Numbers Approaches to the compilation of quantity index numbers. 1. Simply use the same formulae as in the case of price index numbers – simply interchange prices and quantities. 2. Use the index number identity: Fare et al 1994, OECD and MPI (regional concept) Coelli and Rao (2005) Ag Economics 95 countries Ag productivity using MPI technical efficiency, which reflects the ability of a firm to obtain maximal output from a given set of inputs.

Four quantity index numbers To obtain the corresponding quantity index numbers we interchange prices and quantities: For quantity indices we simply interchange prices and quantities. Best index for TFP measurement? - Diewert and others argue for Tornqvist and Fisher on the basis of economic theory and axiomatic arguments - we now discuss these...

Which index is best for use in TFP studies? Two methods are used to assess the suitability of index number formulae: economic theory or functional approach Exact and superlative index numbers axiomatic or test approach Index numbers that satisfy a number of desirable properties Both approaches suggest that the Fisher and Tornqvist are best (Diewert) Linear production functions imply infinite elasticities of substitution. Most published work by Diewert. Diewert argues for more emphasis on axiomatic arguments because above assumptions often do not apply - especially in regulated industries

Tornqvist TFP index The Tornqvist has been the most popular TFP index The Tornqvist has been most commonly used for TFP calculations in the past 2 decades. Usually expressed in log-change form for ease of calculation and interpretation. Notation: M outputs and K inputs, y=output quantity, x=input quantity, =output revenue share, =input cost share. This approach is also know as the Hicks-Moorsteen Approach – defines productivity index simply as the ratio of output and input index numbers.

Properties of index numbers Used to evaluate index numbers Economic theory Axioms Both suggest Tornqvist and Fisher best for TFP calculations

Economic theory arguments Laspeyres and Paasche imply simplistic linear production structures Fisher is exact for quadratic - Tornqvist is exact for translog - both are 2nd-order flexible forms - thus “superlative” indices If we assume technical efficiency, allocative efficiency and CRS, then Tornqvist and Fisher indices can be interpreted as production function shift (technical change) Linear production functions imply infinite elasticities of substitution. Most published work by Diewert. Diewert argues for more emphasis on axiomatic arguments because above assumptions often do not apply - especially in regulated industries