Francesco Zucchini Università di Milano Paper prepared for SISP Venezia 2010 Recent studies of the legislative process contain a number of plausible hypotheses.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
The Prime Minister & Cabinet System 1.Introduction 2. Membership (a) The Prime Minister (b) Selection of other Ministers 3.The PM and Organisation of.
Advertisements

Institutions Want stable democracy? Get the institutions right!
A Comparative Theory of Legislation, Discretion, and Policy making Process (Huber&Shipan) Two crucial elements in the politicians- bureaucrats interaction.
NOTE: To change the image on this slide, select the picture and delete it. Then click the Pictures icon in the placeholder to insert your own image. CHOOSING.
Regulatory Regimes, Agency Actions, and the Conditional Nature of Congressional Influence Charles Shipan, 2004 Stefano Alessandro Rognoni EPS.
Reforming Legislative Process in Poland: What, How and Why? Dr Radoslaw Zubek Potsdam University, Germany October 2006.
Veto Players.
McGraw-Hill Ryerson Copyright © 2011 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Adapted by Peter Au, George Brown College.
Government turnover: Concepts, measures and applications Shale Horowitz, Karla Hoff & Branko Milanovic.
Office and policy payoffs in coalition governments Marc Debus Presentation by: Jacopo Gandin.
Institutions: The rules of the game POLI 352A.
Making and breaking government The Veto Player perspective Camilla Mariotto5th November 2009 Positive Political Theory Prof. Francesco Zucchini.
Veto Players, Political Institutions a. Institutional Constraints- 3rd dec. Data-set 1, Veto Players In: „Comparative Politics“/ Prof. Giuliani/ 1st trim./
Coalition agreements and Cabinet Governance (Muller and Strom) Coalition agreements are one of the aspect of the governance structure of multiparty coalition.
The Government Agenda in Parliamentary Democracies 4 th November 2009 Camilla Mariotto Comparative PoliticsProf. Marco Giuliani AY
Configurations of politico- administrative roles in organisation of public administration reforms. (Inductive approach ) Georg Sootla Professor of Public.
McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. Chapter 9 Hypothesis Testing.
Chapter 9: Executives. This Week… What is the executive branch? How is the Executive Organized? ▫Parliaments, Presidents and Mixed Systems Formal and.
Comparative Extension Projects: Denmark About the project The starting point for this project is the argument that the development of the agenda of different.
Chapter VI, Veto Player, George Tsebelis, 2002 Luca Vezzoli, EPS 2013.
Policy Influencing strategies & Tactics. What is Public policy? Public policy: It is a guideline to the actions of the governments in addressing societal.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2012 Chapter 3: Decision making Nothing is more difficult, and therefore more precious, than to be able to decide. Napoleon.
Francesco Zucchini Università di Milano Paper prepared for SISP Venezia 2010 Recent studies of the legislative process contain a number of plausible hypotheses.
Copyright ©2013 Pearson Education, Inc. publishing as Prentice Hall 9-1 σ σ.
. The Conditional Nature of Administrative Responsiveness to Public Opinion Julia Rabinovich Abstract Theoretical Model Statistical Model for “Representation.
Elections, Representation and Parliament Weekend 2 : Session 1.
Meeting the Challenges of Representation and Accountability in Multi-party Governments Wolfgang C. Müller and Thomas M. Meyer Anna Marta Zaremba.
MAURIZIO COTTA - LUCA VERZICHELLI IL SISTEMA POLITICO ITALIANO CHAPTER 5 The cabinet. From weak and unstable to stronger and long-lasting governments.
Relations Between the Executive and Bureaucracy in Turkey Konuralp Ercilasun Kwangwoon University – Seoul Maltepe University – Istanbul.
Lesson 5.1 Evaluation of the measurement instrument: reliability I.
Gender quotas and political representation. Two concepts of equality The classic liberal notion of equality was a notion of "equal opportunity" or "competitive.
INSTITUTIONS OF THE STATE 3 PUB 101 (WEEK 14). Forms of Executive-Legislative Relations.
Political Parties Chapter 8 Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Longman. Edwards, Wattenberg, and Lineberry Government in America:
OVERVIEW OF PUBLIC ACCOUNTS COMMITTEES
The U.S. Constitution.
Sampling.
Pearson Education, Inc., Longman © 2008
Unit 5: Hypothesis Testing
EcoMod2009 Ottawa, Canada, June 25, 2009
Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals (Part 2): Cohen’s d, Logic of Testing, and Confidence Intervals Lecture 9 Justin Kern October 17 and 19, 2017.
Distribution of the Sample Means
Key Features of FPTP.
Chapter 3: Decision making Nothing is more difficult, and therefore more precious, than to be able to decide. Napoleon Bonaparte.
Overview and Basics of Hypothesis Testing
Hypothesis Tests for a Population Mean,
Political Parties.
Chapter 9 Hypothesis Testing.
DECISION MAKING.
Patterns of Involuntary Technology Adoption
Review: What influences confidence intervals?
Chapter 5 Political Parties.
Statistical Analysis Error Bars
POL 201 GENIUS innovative education /pol201genius.com
Significance Tests: The Basics
INTRODUCTION TO HYPOTHESIS TESTING
Influencing Court Decisions
One-Way Analysis of Variance
Policing the Bargain: Coalition Government and Parliamentary Scrutiny L. Martin and G. Vanberg (2004)
Significance Tests: The Basics
CS 594: Empirical Methods in HCC Experimental Research in HCI (Part 2)
Sampling and Power Slides by Jishnu Das.
Chapter 7: The Normality Assumption and Inference with OLS
Political Parties Chapter 7.
Comparative Analysis of Democratization prof. Fulvio Venturino
STABILITY OF ELECTION LAW EFFECTIVE PROCEDURAL GUARANTEES
American Politics October 23.
Over the next several periods we will…
Chapter 24: Governing the States Section 2
STA 291 Spring 2008 Lecture 17 Dustin Lueker.
Over the next several periods we will…
Presentation transcript:

Francesco Zucchini Università di Milano Paper prepared for SISP Venezia 2010 Recent studies of the legislative process contain a number of plausible hypotheses regarding the distribution of agenda-setting powers, and these hypotheses lead scholars to identify which conflicts (and consequently which actors) are of fundamental importance in explaining legislative change and the wording of legislation (Tsebelis 2002, Huber and Shipan 2003, Cox & McCubbins 2005.) The unchallenged opinion about the crucial importance of the agenda setting power in explaining the lawmaking has not yet induced to deepen the origins of the specific agenda setting power configuration in the different countries.==> Government alternation and legislative agenda setting.*

Research Question Why in some parliamentary democracy the Cabinet has an undisputed leading role in the law making whilst in others the Parliament still plays effectively the role of co- protagonist? General hypothesis In pivotal party systems with rare and limited government alternation it is much more difficult any strengthening of the government vis-vis the Parliament. One factor prevents the procedural and institutional predominance of the Cabinet in these circumstances: lack of opportunities of and expectations for a large and controversial policy change.

More precisely H1) a high level of government alternation strengthens de facto the agenda-setting power of the government. Government alternation is a necessary and sufficient condition for a less frequent use of the amendment power from the parliament (the “closed rule”). H2) Government alternation is a necessary but not sufficient condition for the creation of new rules that increase formally and permanently the agenda setting power of the government. An increase of the government ideological homogeneity is the other necessary condition.

The model (1) Parliament whose median voter is M Government composed at least of two political players who are disposed at the opposite sides of the left-right ideological spectrum (VPL and VPR), in a one-dimensional space. The government decides to promote the policy change and the Parliament decides the procedure. Inside the government we can assume without lack of generality that the closest actor to the present status quo, q, is also the first promoter of the change, while the farthest one is only a veto player.

The model (2)‏ The options of the Parliament are grouped into three categories: a) Adopting a rule granting amendment powers to the parliamentary floor: procedure r = o. The government chooses a policy and a parliamentary majority adopts it under open rule. The final policy outcome coincides with the ideal point of M, the parliamentary median voter position m. b) Adopting a rule preventing a government agreement from being amended by the floor: procedure r = c. Once the bill is proposed, the majority of the parliament decides to give up the right to amend. The government chooses a policy and a parliamentary majority adopts it under “closed rule. The final outcome is g. As the government is supposed to know the preferences of the parliament, the closed rule allows the government to select and propose the policy that it prefers the most and that will be accepted by the parliament. c) Changing the rules: procedure r=n. Parliament before dealing with the bill proposed by the Government creates a new rule that allows the government to propose the bill by a take-it-or leave-it option at the onset of the legislative process. This new rule deprives quasi- permanently the Parliament of its power to amend the government proposal.

The model (4) The three moves at M’s disposal imply different decision costs cr. The procedures that leave more scope to debate, like open rule (o), are by far more vulnerable to a parliamentary conflict sparked off by opposition parties. They can be more costly for government parties and for the median voter in Parliament than the closed rule (c) is. Changing the rules can be very costly as well. However this price is overwhelmingly compensated by the long run of benefits of the reform: once the new rule is approved the parliament does not have to examine anymore every single government bill in order to decide which procedure to adopt. Therefore, the decision costs vary according to the procedure r, the actors, the position of the status quo q and the length of the time horizon. The open rule is very costly for the median voter M in the Parliament (and the government actors) when the status quo is very controversial, that is, when the opposition strongly disapproves of the change. The change of the rules is costly regardless of where the status quo policy is located, but when the new rules are in force they can be extremely convenient for the parliamentary majority. According to a cautious evaluation I can consider the decision cost of changing the rules equal to the decision cost of the closed rule. Therefore, for M, we assume that in the long run: cc (cost of closed rule) = cn (cost of new rule)= 0 ; co (cost of open rule) = f (q, Op, VPL, VPR)

The model (4)‏ An informal introduction to the implications of this simple game can be illustrated by a spatial representation of the legislative change in case of an oversized government. The cost of the procedure o (co) can be represented spatially as an additional distance c from the final policy outcome m. The distance is “added” on the left of m if I consider a leftist status quo q when the crucial VP is VPL. Without any loose of generality I will consider the outcomes only when q VPR. When VPL  q  VPR the solution of the game is trivially q.

Oversized government ( in bold the final outcome)‏

Oversized government ( in bold the final outcome)‏ In Fig. 2a, the status quo q is outside the government's Pareto set, namely the line connecting VPL and VPR. Both the government actors could easily agree to change it. However, VPL will not propose any bill, lest the parliament (m) should choose an open rule leading to m+co as the final policy outcome. This result would be much worse for VPL than the initial status quo q.

Oversized government ( in bold the final outcome)‏ The policy change and the adoption of a closed rule becomes possible in the scenario of Fig. 2b. In this case, the status quo q is far from VPL and near enough to Op to make it convenient for VPL to propose g. Given the cost co of the open rule, the parliament will find it marginally better to adopt such a proposal with a closed rule rather than allow amendments by adopting an open rule.

Oversized government ( in bold the final outcome)‏ Figure 2c presents a similar scenario to that of Fig. 2b, but here VPL is much closer to M. In this case the Parliament is indifferent between the adoption of a closed rule and the introduction of a new rule that allows the government to propose a bill under a take-it-or leave-it option from the onset. When a government party has been enjoying a closed rule since the beginning of the legislative process, it can take advantage of its position as agenda setter independently from the decision costs of the open rule. In other words, it can obtain more than what the parliament can offer if the latter could still choose between a closed rule and an open rule.

Which are the concrete political circumstances that drive to the scenarios b ? (1)‏ Government alternation is the most promising candidate among the concrete political circumstances driving towards the scenario b. The status quo must be not only far but also controversial. The most systematic source of these shifts comes from government alternation in two ways: 1.The decisions of the previous government are likely to be a status quo far from those of the present government and controversial if the previous opposition wins office. 2.The perspective of the alternation can move the “reversion point” in case of no decision farther than the present status quo and in a controversial area. In other words, the real status quo that the government parties take in consideration can be the potential legislative outcome if the present opposition becomes the next government. Such a crucial change in the political calculus of the government parties takes place when the government alternation has already become a real and experienced possibility.

( in bold the final outcome)‏

( in bold the final outcome)‏ In the Figure 2d the status quo is no longer controversial as the opposition and the government agree on the direction of change. The change is still blocked by VPL. However, when a shift of the status quo makes the change possible (Fig. 2e), though not certainly by the government alternation as in Fig. 2b or Fig 2c., the procedure adopted will be always open rule and the final outcome will be m. As the opposition Op agrees with the government in changing the status quo, open rule will be always the most convenient procedure for M.

Government alternation crucially affects the position of the status quo and the perception of its stability. When alternation is rare, the status quo in different policy areas is less likely to be between the government and the opposition. It is likely to be in the present government’s range or, at the most, marginally on its left or right. In this case, the status quo is mostly the outcome of decisions taken by the previous government that is ideologically very similar to the present one. In many policy sectors, no real change is possible. In others, the change of status quo is so uncontroversial (as in Fig. 2e) that open rule does not imply higher decision costs and the whole parliament prefers the parliamentary median party position to the status quo. When the alternation is a stable feature of the party system, a decrease of the government’s ideological heterogeneity (or the closeness of one VP to the parliamentary median voter as in the case of minority governments) increases the probability of a change of the formal rules in favor of the government (fig. 2c). Therefore the empirical implication of the model can be summarized in the following two hypotheses: H1) a high level of government alternation strengthens the agenda-setting power of the government. Government alternation is a necessary and sufficient condition for a less frequent use of the amendment power from the parliament (the “closed rule”). H2) Government alternation is a necessary but not sufficient condition for the creation of new rules that increase formally and permanently the agenda setting power of the government. An increase of the government ideological homogeneity is the other necessary condition. Summary of model’s implications and hypotheses

Operationalization independent variables:direct I consider a)the party positions identified by the expert surveys (Laver and Hunt 1989) regarding the issue of “raising taxes to increase public services” (score 1) versus “ cutting public services to cut taxes” (score 20). b)Party positions on left-right dimension identified by Huber&Gabel using Party Manifestos with the so called Vanilla tecnique Knowing these party positions I can calculate for each data source (LH and PM)‏ Spatial hetereogeneity of the government-parliament system (Parliament median party-Government distance): Government range when the median party is in the government ; distance between median party and farthest VP when the median party position is not in the government range. 2. Different measures of alternations (see below).

Operationalization independent variables:indirect Government heterogenity: The number of government parties (Vpnum) Alternation: The proportion of days spent by the government party (government party predominance) that has been longer in office as an estimation of the level of alternation. The smaller the proportion is, the larger the alternation is. The probability that two cabinets taken randomly in time include the party that has been longer in office (government party concentration).

Gallagher index of disproportionality: an electoral system very disproportional amplifies in the parliament the changes that took place among voters: more disproportionality more expectation of alternation. Operationalization independent variables: expectation of alternation

Operationalization dependent variable (Government legislative agenda setting) The government agenda setting power scores identified by Doering (1995) and re- elaborated by Tsebelis (2002) (Doering- Tsebelis Agenda Setting index). Doering identifies seven variables that contribute to the agenda setting powers of governments when producing ordinary legislation. Tsebelis used principal components and the first factor loadings to weigh each one of these variables and normalized the weighted sum.

Operationalization (direct) of alternation Tsebelis Alternation: is the difference between the mid range position of the left-right dimension of two successive “merged” governments. Successive governments with the same ideological range are considered to constitute one single government. Median party alternation:is the difference between two parliamentary median parties positions in correspondence “of” two successive “merged”governments. Corrected Tsebelis alternation and Corrected median party alternation, allow for the previous differences only when the midrange measure of the previous government or the parliamentary median party position during the previous government, are not included in the present government Pareto set.

The logic of the corrected measures:

General statistics

Correlations

Mod.1Mod.2Mod.3Mod.4Mod. 5Mod.6Mod.7Mod.8Mod.9Mod.10 Constant 1.035*** [.3494] (0.010).6318*** [.2104] (0.010).0194 [.1856] (0.918).0501 [.1975] (0.803).0606 [ ] (0.739).0289 [.1891] (0.881) [.1587] (0.282) [.1812] (0.315) [.1670] (0.589) [.1639] (0.359) Vpnum [.0912] 0.377 (0.356) Government Party Predominance * [.0053] 0.067) Government Party concentration * [.3220] (0.060) Parliament median party- Government distance * [.0286] (0.086) [.0316] (0.137) [.0271] (0.122) [.0328] (0.325) Tsebelis alternation (LH).0475** [.0208] (0.039) Corrected Tsebelis alternation(LH).0418* [.0238] (0.100) Median Party alternation(LH).0453* [.0213] (0.052) Corrected median party alternation(LH).0510** [.0229] (0.043) Parliament median party- Government distance (PM) * [.1020] (0.100) [.1295] (0.445) * [.1199] (0.093) [.1208] (0.387) Tsebelis Alternation (PM).4235*** [.1142] (0.002) Corrected Tsebelis alternation (PM).4252*** [.1326] (0.006) Median party alternation (PM).4657** [.1852] (0.025) Corrected median party alternation (PM).5748*** [.1640] (0.004) N. 17 R2R * p<0.1 level; **p<0.05 ;***p<0.01 ;****p<0.001 Legislative Agenda Setting (Doering-Tsebelis scores) OLS models with robust standard errors

Legislativa agenda setting power and index of disproportionality Mod.1Mod.2Mod.3 Constant [ ] (0.568) [ ] (0.237) [ ] (0.112) Vpnum [ ] 0.159 Disproportionality *** [ ] (0.002) ** [.02298] (0.012) *** [ ] (0.001) Parliament median party- Government distance (LH) [.02216] (0.292) Parliament median party-Government distance (PM) [ ] (0.150) N.17 R2R

Discussion (1) All measures of alternation are linked significantly with the legislative agenda setting power of the government. The models with the indirect measures of both the alternation and the government heterogeneity perform worse than the others. The measures of ideological heterogeneity (VPnum, Parliament median party –government distance) have always the right sign but they are non significant or marginally significant.. The “best” models are the models where : 1)Alternation is measured as difference between the ideological position of two parliamentary median parties in succession. 2)Alternation is in fact “possibility of alternation” operationalized by Gallagher disproportionality index.

Discussion (2) The measures of ideological heterogeneity (VPnum, parliament median party–government distance) have always a negative sign, as expected in the hypothesis 2, but they are non significant or marginally significant. It is not surprising... The proximity of the agenda setter in the government with the parliamentary median voter allows the change in the formal rules. However it does not have to be constant to keep the new rules stable. In other terms while a certain level of homogeneity in the government is necessary for the institutional change in favour of the government, a possible subsequent increase of heterogeneity does not allow the government parties to come back to the original situation. The parties that mostly play an agenda setter role would not have any advantage to reinstate the previous conditions.

Alternation and agenda setting power: which comes first ? The Italian case. Causal sequence in this paper: the lack of alternation and the associated centrism of government ==> the weak degree of governmental agenda-setting power Causal sequence in Tsebelis paper (2008): weak government agenda-setting power ==> the existence of centrist governments and the lack of government alternation associated therewith. The analysis of the recent development of de facto legislative agenda-setting powers in Italy lends some support to the causal sequence

Italian example (change in party system dynamics and...increase of government agenda setting power)

Italian example (change in party system dynamics and...increase of de facto government agenda setting power)

Informal changes and Italian government heterogeneity The Italian recent changes in the legislative practices is a perfect illustration of an increase of the government agenda setting power that does not imply any new rule (in terms of the model a “closed rule” is adopted). According to the model such a circumstance takes place more likely when the government alternation is not coupled with a decrease of the government heterogeneity. The study of recent Italian politics seems to confirm this implication. The presidents of the chambers are crucial actors in the procedure for changing parliamentary standing orders. They chair the rules committees that have the exclusive right to propose amendments to the existing standing orders on the floor. The present standing orders give to the presidents many prerogatives and it is unlikely that they have a strong interest in increasing the power of the executive to the detriment of their power. Moreover the presidencies of the chambers are part of the post-electoral bargaining process among winning coalition parties for the allocation of the relevant offices. In the last four legislatures the president of one chamber has never been a member of the prime minister’s party. The president of a chamber can increase the legislative bargaining power of his/her party, balancing the role played by the Prime Minister’s party. Therefore the political heterogeneity of the Italian government coalition seems to have prevented the creation of new rules, without affecting the strengthening of the government in practice

Conclusions The central hypothesis of this paper is the following: by affecting the relative position of the status quo, both real and expected government alternation affects the legislative agenda-setting power of the government in parliamentary democracies. In a competitive party system characterized by a large alternation, government parties and the majority in parliament are better off relying on those procedures that limit the debate and preclude the legislative assembly from amending government proposals. The causal mechanism behind this hypothesis follows the argument recently proposed by Cox (2006) to explain the evolution of rules and procedures in the legislatures: “All busy legislatures will evolve rules that create inequalities in member’s access to plenary time and diminish ordinary members’ ability to delay”. However, the parliaments are not all equally busy and the cabinets are not always the beneficiary in the agenda-setting power distribution. Opportunities for policy change make parliaments busier, but only their controversial nature makes the government stronger. The study of the Italian case supports also the causal direction implicitly hypothesized in model: Level of alternation and level of “centrism” of government ==> degree of governmental agenda-setting power

Table 1 Summary of the outcomes with q<VPL