Tutorial 4: Asymmetric Information

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
3 CHAPTER Demand and Supply.
Advertisements

© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. Markets and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with.
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
CHAPTER 6: SECTION 1 Supply and Demand Together
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection. What does it mean Adverse Selection (AS)? There is an AS problem when: before the signing of the contract,
BEE3049 Financial Markets and Decisions II Lecture 2.
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY © 2012 Pearson Education What makes the prices of oil and gasoline double in just one year? Will the price of gasoline keep on rising?
Correcting Market Distortions: Shadow Prices, Shadow Wages and Discount Rates Chapter 6.
Chapter 6 McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
SUPPLY AND DEMAND I: HOW MARKETS WORK. Copyright © 2004 South-Western The Market Forces of Supply and Demand.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
Economics of Management Strategy BEE3027 Lecture 7.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. Demand and Supply Supply and demand are the two words that economists use most often. Supply and demand are the forces.
3 Demand and Supply Notes and teaching tips: 4, 6, 41, and 46.
Supply, Demand and Equilibrium. In competitive markets the interaction of supply and demand tends to move toward what economists call equilibrium ▫Ex:
Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium Let’s put together all of the pieces.
AQA Econ 1: Markets and market failure
Industrial Economics Fall INFORMATION Basic economic theories: Full (perfect) information In reality, information is limited. Consumers do not know.
ECON 101: Introduction to Economics - I Lecture 3 – Demand and Supply.
Asymmetric Information
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism George A. Akerlof,
Chapter 21.1 What is Supply?. An Introduction to Supply  Supply refers to the various quantities of a good or service that producers are willing to sell.
Chapter 3: Individual Markets: Demand & Supply
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Markets and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with.
3 Demand and Supply © 2013 Pearson Australia After studying this chapter, you will be able to ■Describe a competitive market and think about a price.
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY © 2014 Pearson Addison-Wesley After studying this chapter, you will be able to:  Describe a competitive market and think about a.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Asymmetric Information The seller of the good knows more about its quality than the buyer.. Perhaps the market does not exist.
THE MODEL OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY Lesson 3 1. LET’S BUILD THE MODEL… 2.
3 CHAPTER Demand and Supply © Pearson Education 2012 After studying this chapter you will be able to:  Describe a competitive market and think about.
MICROECONOMICS Chapter 3 Demand and Supply
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada. What makes the prices of oil and gasoline double in just one year? Will the price of gasoline keep on rising?
Main Definitions Market: –All situations that link potential buyers and potential sellers are markets. Demand: –A demand schedule shows price and quantity.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at the same price.
Perfect Competition. insignificant Price taker homogeneous complete information costless no costs equal access barriers to entry/exit competition externalities.
Intro To Microeconomics.  Cost is the money spent for the inputs used (e.g., labor, raw materials, transportation, energy) in producing a good or service.
Intro to Business Supply, Demand and Price Target: I can describe how costs and revenues affect profit and supply.
What is the Law of Supply? MODULE 6 SUPPLY AND EQUILIBRIUM.
Chapter 4: Demand and Supply
Macroeconomic Equilibrium
Q 2.1 Nash Equilibrium Ben
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of markets
Surplus (a.k.a. excess supply):
Competition: Perfect and Otherwise
SUPPLY AND DEMAND I: HOW MARKETS WORK
Microeconomics I Perfect Competition
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
Econ Unit One Day 8.
Chapter 24 Perfect Competition.
Supply and Demand: Theory (Part II)
Section 2 Module 7.
Factor Markets and Vertical Integration
THE ECONOMY: THE CORE PROJECT
SUPPLY AND DEMAND THEORY (Part 2)
Supply and Demand: Theory (Part II)
Chapter 6: Estimating demand and revenue relationships
Lecture ONE PRICE DISCRIMINATION.
Chapter 6 Section 1.
Supply Supply Quantity Supplied Law of Supply
Bellwork- fill in the blank
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior.
Chapter 6 Demand, Supply, & Price.
Equilibrium in the Market
Combining Supply and Demand
Equilibrium Equilibrium price and quantity are found where the AD and AS curves intersect. At any price level above equilibrium sellers are faced with.
SUPPLY AND DEMAND: HOW MARKETS WORK
Chapter 3 Lecture DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
Equilibrium Equilibrium price and quantity are found where the AD and AS curves intersect. At any price level above equilibrium sellers are faced with.
Presentation transcript:

Tutorial 4: Asymmetric Information Matthew Robson

4.1 Asymmetric Information A particular good is either high quality (type A) or low quality (type B). Sellers know which type they are selling. Buyers cannot distinguish type at the time of purchase. So there can be only a single price p, and in effect a single market. Suppliers are price-takers, with market supply functions for Types A and B respectively: 𝑠 𝐴 =𝑚𝑎𝑥 5𝑝−30 , 0 𝑠 𝐵 =20 Relative to supply, there is a large number of potential buyers, each of whom would be willing to pay up to £16 (per unit) for known Type A, and £4 for known Type B. Buyers are risk-neutral.   1

4.1 Let 𝜑 denote the probability, as estimated/perceived by buyers, that any given unit of the good is Type A rather than Type B. Define an equilibrium in this market as a situation in which supply equals demand, and also 𝜑 is correct, i.e.: 𝜑= 𝑠 𝐴 𝑠 𝐴 + 𝑠 𝐵 Market for Lemons, George Akerlof -Second Hand Car Sales: Good Cars and Bad Cars (lemons) -Asymmetry of Information between buyers and sellers. -Up to a price of £6 the only cars in market are lemons 2

4.1 (a) Explain why, for a unit of unknown type, buyers are willing to pay up to 𝑣=4+12𝜑 . We know buyers are risk neutral. Willing to pay £16 for Type A and £4 for Type B. The probability that the good is Type A is: 𝜑= 𝑠 𝐴 𝑠 𝐴 + 𝑠 𝐵 Therefore, buyers willingness to pay for an unknown type is: 𝑣=φ16+ 1−φ 4 𝑣=4+12𝜑 3

4.1 (b) By calculating in each case the correct 𝜑, and the corresponding v, explain why the market would not be in equilibrium at any of the following prices: 𝑝= 3 𝑝= 6 𝑝= 9 𝑝= 12 If 𝑣<𝑝 then there is zero demand, and so excess supply. If 𝑣>𝑝 then there is excess demand, given the assumption of a large number of buyers relative to supply. 4

4.1 (b) If 𝑝=3 𝑠 𝐴 =𝑚𝑎𝑥 5𝑝−30 , 0 𝑠 𝐵 =20 𝑠 𝐴 =0 𝑠 𝐵 =20 𝑠 𝐴 =𝑚𝑎𝑥 5𝑝−30 , 0 𝑠 𝐵 =20 𝑠 𝐴 =0 𝑠 𝐵 =20 𝜑= 𝑠 𝐴 𝑠 𝐴 + 𝑠 𝐵 𝜑=0 𝑣=4+12𝜑 𝑣=4 𝑝=3, 𝜑=0, 𝑣=4, 𝑠𝑜 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑 5

So what are the 𝜑’s and 𝑣’s for each of the following prices: 𝑝= 3 𝑝= 6 𝑝= 9 𝑝= 12 𝑝=3, 𝜑=0, 𝑣=4, 𝑠𝑜 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑝=6, 𝜑=0, 𝑣=4, 𝑠𝑜 𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑝=9, 𝜑=3/7, 𝑣≈9.14, 𝑠𝑜 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑝=12, 𝜑=3/5, 𝑣=11.2, 𝑠𝑜 𝑧𝑒𝑟𝑜 𝑑𝑒𝑚𝑎𝑛𝑑 6

4.1 (c) Similarly, explain why the market would be in equilibrium at any of the following prices: 𝑝= 4 𝑝= 8 𝑝= 10  𝑝=4, 𝜑=0, 𝑣=4, 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑏𝑟𝑖𝑢𝑚 𝑝=8, 𝜑=1/3, 𝑣=8, 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑏𝑟𝑖𝑢𝑚 𝑝=10, 𝜑=1/2, 𝑣=10, 𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑏𝑟𝑖𝑢𝑚 7

Supply: -There is a single market as buyers cannot distinguish between Type A and Type B -So for any given p the ‘correct’ 𝜑 can be found Demand: -A function of p and 𝜑, so different curves for different 𝜑 -For the ‘correct’ 𝜑 from the supply curve, the demand curve can be traced out 8

Equilibria: -Here the intersection of the demand and supply shows the three equilibria -Each has a different value of 𝝋 p = 10 p = 8 p = 4 9

4.1 (c) Do your calculations in (b) suggest anything about the stability of any of these equilibria? What is distinctive about the equilibrium at 𝑝= 4 Answers from (b) suggest that 𝒑=𝟖 is unstable, in that for p slightly higher than 8 there is excess demand (presumably causing p to rise), while for p slightly lower than 8 there is excess supply (presumably causing p to fall). The equilibrium at 𝑝=4 is a separating equilibrium, in that only Type B sell at that price. So if we don’t just want lemons in the market the higher price of 𝑝=10 may have to be the price to pay. 10

4.2 The Labour Market In a particular field of employment there are two types of applicants: high quality (Type A) and low quality (Type B). An applicant (seller) knows what type they are. Employers (buyers) cannot distinguish type at the time of offering employment contracts, although they know that a fixed proportion 𝝋 of applicants are of Type A.   Relative to the number of applicants, there is a large number of potential employers. Each would be willing to pay a wage of up to 70 to a known Type A, and 30 to a known Type B, and each is risk neutral in their valuation of an unknown type. 11

4.2 (a) In each case identifying the crucial assumption(s), explain why on the assumptions so far: the equilibrium wage cannot be more than 30+40𝜑 (ii) the equilibrium wage cannot be less than 30+40𝜑 (iii) hence, the equilibrium wage must be 30+40𝜑 Why is the equilibrium here unique, in contrast to exercise 4.1? 12

4.2 (a) Employers are assumed to be risk-neutral, which implies that they will offer no more than 𝜑70+ 1−𝜑 30=30+40𝜑 to an applicant of unknown type. Employers are risk-neutral, and also numerous relative to applicants. So competition between them pushes the wage up to the maximum they will offer, i.e. 30+40𝜑 follows from (i) and (ii). The equilibrium is unique because 𝜑 is assumed fixed. In 4.1, by contrast, 𝜑 varies with price. 13

4.2 (b) (b) Now assume that there is a qualification that only Type A applicants are capable of obtaining, at a cost to them of 𝑐 𝐴 . Employers can offer a wage w either unconditionally (w,0), or conditional (w,1) on the applicant having obtained that qualification. In a pooling equilibrium there is a uniform offer made by all employers, and accepted by both types of applicant. Explain why, on the assumptions so far, in a pooling equilibrium: the offer must be unconditional the wage offered must be 30+40𝜑 14

4.2 (b) (i) By assumption Type B are unable to obtain the qualification. So, if the equilibrium offer was conditional on obtaining the qualification then only Type A could accept, in which case it would not be a pooling equilibrium.   (ii) Given that both types accept the offer, the explanation is exactly as in (a). 15

4.2 (b) In a separating equilibrium employers make two distinct offers: a conditional offer ( 𝑤 𝐴 ,1) accepted only by Type A applicants, and an unconditional offer ( 𝑤 𝐵 ,0) accepted only by Type B. Explain why, on the assumptions so far, in a separating equilibrium: (iii) 𝑤 𝐵 =30 (iv) 𝑤 𝐴 =70 Hence, explain why there can be no separating equilibrium if 𝑐 𝐴 >40 16

4.2 (b) (iii) Given that only Type B accept the ( 𝑤 𝐵 ,0) offer, competition between employers pushes 𝑤 𝐵 up to the maximum they will pay for known Type B. 𝑤 𝐵 =30. (iv) Given that only Type A accept the ( 𝑤 𝐴 ,1) offer, competition between employers pushes 𝑤 𝐴 up to the maximum they will pay for known Type A. 𝑤 𝐴 =70. If 𝑐 𝐴 >40 then Type A applicants prefer to accept (30,0) rather than (70,1). 17

4.2 (c) Assume from now on that 𝑐 𝐴 =18. Assume that 𝜑=0.5. If all other employers were offering only (50,0), find a profitable alternative offer that would attract only Type A applicants. Hence explain why a pooling equilibrium does not exist here. Explain why a pooling equilibrium would exist if instead 𝜑=0.6. 18

4.2 (c) From (b), if 𝜑=0.5 then a pooling equilibrium would be when: 𝑤=30+40𝜑=50 So: (50,0). But an alternative offer of (69,1) would be accepted by Type A applicants, in preference to (50,0), and at a wage less than the maximum the employer is willing to offer a known Type A. So (50,0) is not an equilibrium. If instead 𝜑=0.6 then a pooling equilibrium would when: 𝑤=30+40𝜑=54 at (54,0). For an alternative offer (𝑤,1) to be accepted by Type A would now require 𝑤>72 (as 𝑐 𝐴 =18), which is more than an employer is willing to offer a known Type A. So (54,0) is an equilibrium. 19

4.2 (c) Assume that 𝜑=0.6. If all other employers were offering only (30,0) and (70,1), find a profitable alternative offer that would attract both types. Hence explain why a separating equilibrium does not exist here. Explain why a separating equilibrium would exist if instead 𝜑=0.5. So, in equilibrium, what proportion of applicants obtain the qualification if 𝜑=0.5.? And what proportion if 𝜑=0.6.? 20

4.2 (c) From (b), a separating equilibrium would be at (30,0) and (70,1). If 𝜑=0.6 then an employer is willing to offer up to 54 to an unknown type. An alternative offer of (53,0) would be accepted by both types. So (30,0) and (70,1) is not an equilibrium. If instead 𝜑=0.5 then an employer is willing to offer no more than 50 to a unknown type. For an alternative offer (w,0) to attract both types would require 𝑤> 52 . So (30,0) and (70,1) is an equilibrium. So, if 𝜑=0.5 then in equilibrium 50% of applicants (i.e. all Type A) obtain the qualification. But if 𝜑=0.6 then in equilibrium 0% of applicants obtain the qualification. 21

4.2 (d)  (d) Now assume that Type B applicants are also capable of obtaining the same qualification, but at a higher cost of 𝑐 𝐵 =34 . Explain why, in a separating equilibrium: (i) 𝑤 𝐵 =30 (ii) 𝑤 𝐴 =64 Hence explain why there is no equilibrium at all if 𝜑=0.5. Given the assumed values of 𝑐 𝐴 and 𝑐 𝐵 , what is the largest 𝜑 at which there would be a separating equilibrium? And what is the smallest value of 𝜑 at which there would be a pooling equilibrium? 22

4.2 (d) (i) Same as (b)(iii). Given that only Type B accepts the ( 𝑤 𝐵 ,0) offer, competition between employers pushes 𝑤 𝐵 up to the maximum they will pay for known Type B. 𝑤 𝐵 =30. (ii) As in (b)(iv), competition between risk neutral employers pushes 𝑤 𝐴 up to the maximum they will pay for known Type A, so long as 𝑤 𝐴 ,1 is accepted only by Type A. But if 𝑤 𝐴 >64 then Type B applicants will also prefer to accept ( 𝑤 𝐴 ,1) rather than (30,0). 23

4.2 (d) A separating equilibrium would be at (30,0) and (64,1). If 𝜑=0.5 then an employer is willing to offer up to 50 to an unknown type. An alternative offer of (47,0) would attract both types. So (30,0) and (64,1) is not an equilibrium. We already know from (c) that if 𝜑=0.5 then there is no pooling equilibrium. So there is no equilibrium at all, if 𝜑=0.5.   (30,0) and (64,1) is an equilibrium iff: 30+40𝜑≤46 =64−18 𝑖.𝑒. 𝜑≤0.4 (30+40𝜑, 0) is an equilibrium iff: 30+40𝜑≥52 =70−18 𝑖.𝑒. 𝜑≥0.55 24

Signalling One important assumption that was changed was related to signalling. In (a) we assume that the individuals type in unknown. But in (b) we assume that due to their qualification they can signal their type. A good signal must be costly-to-fake and ensure full-disclosure occurs. Toad’s Croak -Male toads croak at night to attract mates. The female toads prefer the larger toads, and so need to have some signal in the dark as to which toads are the largest. -So the toads have a signal, their croak. The larger the toads are the deeper their croak will be, while smaller toads can only emit higher pitched croaks. -The signal is costly-to-fake, the smaller toads cannot croak deeply, and ensures full-disclosure occurs, as individual toads must disclose even unfavourable information about themselves (a high pitched croak) as silence would mean they had more to hide (they were even smaller). 25