The Uncommon Insight of Elinor Ostrom

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Public Goods and Common Resources Chapter 11 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part.
Advertisements

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
PROPERTY RIGHTS. PROPERTY RIGHTS AND MARKET FAILURE.
AGEC 640 – Nov. 6, 2014 Policy: How well can market failures be remedied?
Lecture 5.
Sabina L. Shaikh University of Chicago Economic Valuation of Ecosystems Conference May 29, 2009 Ecosystems and Economics: Progress and Optimism for the.
Game Theoretical Models of Effort and Lobbying in a Heterogeneous CPR Setting Matthew Freeman Louisiana State University/LA Sea Grant Chris Anderson University.
An Introduction to... Evolutionary Game Theory
Public Goods and Common Resources Chapter 11 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part.
Public Goods and Common Resources Chapter 11 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning...
16 CHAPTER Public Goods and Common Resources.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
BEE3049 Behaviour, Decisions and Markets Miguel A. Fonseca.
Introduction to the Theory of HES Collective Action in Human-Environment Systems Prof. Stefanie Engel Chair of Environmental Policy and Economics Universitätstr.
Some Problems from Chapt 13. Problem 1: A crowded fishery.
 “Picture a pasture that is open to all. Each herdsman will try to keep as many cattle as possible on the commons…the inherent logic of the commons remorselessly.
1 Externalities. 2 Externalities  Externalities are a market failure (so Government intervention may be advisable).  Externalities imply that there.
P2P Interaction in Socially Intelligent ICT David Hales Delft University of Technology (Currently visiting University of Szeged, Hungary)
Lecture 13 Externalities, public goods, common-property resources.
CHAPTER 1.2 The Environment and Society. “THE TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS” When talking about environmental problems it is important to consider human societies.
2008/01/30Lecture 11 Game Theory. 2008/01/30Lecture 12 What is Game Theory? Game theory is a field of Mathematics, analyzing strategically inter-dependent.
Chapter 12 Game Theory Presented by Nahakpam PhD Student 1Game Theory.
Game Theory By Ben Cutting & Rohit Venkat.
NMA course Marko Lindroos
Markets with Only a Few Sellers
Ecolog 2.
Chapter 11 Public Goods and Common Resources
Sustainability Science Seminar
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Session 2 Managing the global commons:
Market Failure: Oligopolies
Algorithmic Game Theory and Internet Computing
How To Govern Shared Natural Resources?
AGEC 640 – Nov. 2, Policy: How well can market failures be remedied?
Laddered auction Ashish Goel tanford University
Common-pool resources
Institutions and Sustainability
Game Theory Developed to explain the optimal strategy in two-person interactions. Initially, von Neumann and Morganstern Zero-sum games John Nash Nonzero-sum.
Unit 4 SOCIAL INTERACTIONS.
Ecolog 2.
Objectives Describe “The Tragedy of the Commons”.
Spatio-temporal information in society: evolution of cooperation
Why Study the Commons?.
Presented By Aaron Roth
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Learning 6.2 Game Theory.
Ecolog 2.
What is Environmental Science?
“The Tragedy of the Commons”
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS: PART 2
AGEC 640 – Nov. 6, Policy: How well can market failures be remedied?
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.
NATURAL RESOURCES Classification Economic characteristics
Ecolog 2.
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Section 2: The Environment and Society
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Ecolog 2.
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Section 2: The Environment and Society
Ecology 2.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory
Warm Up:.
Environmental Economics
Ecolog 2.
Ecolog 2.
Ecolog 2.
Environmental Science Ch1 Sec 2 The Environment and Society
Presentation transcript:

The Uncommon Insight of Elinor Ostrom

Tragedy of the Commons “Picture a pasture that is open to all. Each herdsman will try to keep as many cattle as possible on the commons…the inherent logic of the commons remorselessly generates tragedy.” ---Garrett Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons 1968

Global and Local Commons A key characteristic of “local” commons is that there are typically several participants (but a relatively small “several”.) Hardin applied the commons metaphor to “global” commons problems such as large-scale air and water pollution and overpopulation. Ostrom has concentrated her attention on local commons.

Local Commons Pastures Woodlands Fishing grounds Hunting Grounds Watersheds Ground Water Basins Oil Fields Parking spaces

Appropriation Games Instinctive economists’ approach: Model common commons problem as an “appropriation game”. Common resource shared by N players, intensity of use by i is xi. number of cows pastured, amount of water extracted, etc Payoff to player i is Pi(xi,Σxj).

Assumed payoffs Given actions of others, Pi(xi,Σxj) is increasing in xi over some range and then decreasing. Pi xi Pi(xi,Σxj) is a decreasing function of Σx

Nash equilibrium Under plausible assumptions, this game will have a unique Nash equilibrium. In Nash equilibrium each user imposes a “negative externality” on all other users, but does not take this into account when choosing his intensity of use. This equilibrium will not be Pareto efficient. The resource will be overused.

Traditional Economists’ Remedies Centrally enforced solutions: “Pigovian solution”: Price the externality. Find the optimal solution, charge an access fee equal to the total externality caused by an extra use. Legal limits on quantities extracted by each individual “Enclosure” Privatize the commons by assigning property rights to exclusive use

Difficulties with economists’ remedies Centrally imposed solutions require central knowledge of payoff functions and public observability of activities of each individual. They require a non-corrupt central authority. They require intelligent political decision-making by central authority.

Problems with Privatization Requires enforcement of property rights and monitoring of action of users. Fencing the range land. Patrolling the berry patches. How does one assign property rights to flowing water, swimming fish, or game in the forest? Transferring property rights to a single owner introduces the holdout problem. Similar to land assembly problems

Ostrom Observes Ostrom proposed that we learn from case studies of successful and unsuccessful real world common property institutions. She conducted field studies and studied the field studies of others. She found that enduring institutions achieved more efficient outcomes than Nash equilibrium for simple game, but were not the predicted first-best efficient outcomes.

Case studies Mountain meadow and forests in Swiss Alps and in mountains of Japan. Irrigation systems in Spain, the Philippines, Sri Lanka, and Nepal Fisheries in Turkey, Sri Lanka, and Nova Scotia

Often the one-shot model applies Ostrom documents overexploitation and rent dissipation Fisheries in Turkey, Sri Lanka Water basins in the U.S Enclosure often replaces commons.

Getting the game right Ostrom noted that many commons problems are not one-shot games, but repeated games, played year after year. The Swiss canton of Törbel has maintained communal management of forests and meadows for more than 500 years. Irrigation institutions in Spain are also more than 500 years old.

Repeated games What does game theory predict for repeated games? Folk theorem: In a repeated game without a fixed end point, if players are well-informed about each others actions, almost any behavior can be sustained as a Nash equilibrium (by strategies that punish deviations.) Some of these equilibria will be efficient. Some will not be. Neither Nash equilibrium of one-shot game, nor Pareto optimal outcome is a reliable predictor of outcome.

What to do? Ostrom suggests a fruitful path. Outcomes are not well predicted by simple models that incorporate few facts. Study a large number of durable and less durable institutions. Look for regularities. Try to understand what happens and why. This requires detailed observation, guided by sophisticated theory.

Ostrom’s List: Characteristics of durable commons institutions Clear boundaries of resource and of the group who share it. Congruence of benefit shares and cost shares. Constitutional rules for changing operating rules. Monitoring. Graduated sanctions. Conflict resolution mechanism.

Symmetry and asymmetry Finding and enforcing a nearly efficient allocation is relatively easy in a symmetric game where it is efficient for everyone to be treated equally. More challenging where there are important differences in the interests and bargaining positions of players.

Irrigation examples Landholders near headwaters have advantage over those downstream. Some land is more suitable for water-intensive crops. Elaborate rules for allocating water under different scarcity conditons. Philippines-symmetrization by allocating some land near head and some near bottom to each landholder.

Stability and Efficiency Durable institutions must be internally stable. They need not be efficient. Ostrom’s case studies document this. Group selection may impose some efficiency.

Evolution and Design of Mechanisms Analogy to medicine. Observe what has evolved, try to understand how it works. Where outcome is inefficient, seek alternative designs that are internally consistent and likely to work. Mechanism designers need to observe and understand existing institutions before tinkering. Example: Medical intern matching algorithm.

Norms and Human Evolution Successful commons operations are enforced by norms. Norms are monitored by entire population. Humans seem to have an evolved ability to generate and follow norms. Like potential for language, can take many forms Experimental evidence.

Family networks and altruism Where does altruism enter? Helps when information is incomplete Limits variety of solutions in repeated games. Kin selection theory and the family as a commons.

Is technology making commons obsolete? Agriculture displaces hunter gathering. Fixed, appropriable resources. Cheaper fencing makes enclosure of pastures possible. Manufacturing allows clear ownership rights. But the information economy is a commons.

The information economy as a commons An idea is no easier to appropriate than wild game or running water.

Anti-commons Information economy has been described as an “anti-commons”. Instead of a game in which substitute goods are depleted, complement goods are added by individual contributors. Nash equilibrium has undersupply. Privatizing ideas with patents does not help.

Institutions in the information economy Success Stories The internet Open access publishing Open source software Patent pools Google Wikipedia Tales of Woe Patent morasses Monopolies

Hybrid Vigor in Social Science Nobel ceremonies, a week of celebration of science. Work of Ostrom dramatizes the potential of social science as a multidisciplinary, multi-method commons. Theory, case studies, experiments Political Science, Economics, Game theory, History, Anthropology, Ecology Antidote for inbreeding--Hybridization