FIN 377: Investments Topic 4: An Introduction to Portfolio Management

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 11 Optimal Portfolio Choice
Advertisements

Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management by Frank K
Copyright © 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Return and Risk: The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Chapter.
An Introduction to Asset Pricing Models
FIN352 Vicentiu Covrig 1 Asset Pricing Models (chapter 9)
Chapter 8 Portfolio Selection.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
Efficient Diversification
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
Chapter 6 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
Return and Risk: The Capital Asset Pricing Model Chapter 11 Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
AN INTRODUCTION TO ASSET PRICING MODELS
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
FIN638 Vicentiu Covrig 1 Portfolio management. FIN638 Vicentiu Covrig 2 How Finance is organized Corporate finance Investments International Finance Financial.
Diversification and Portfolio Analysis Investments and Portfolio Management MB 72.
FIN 614: Financial Management Larry Schrenk, Instructor.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part. Chapter.
Portfolio Management Lecture: 26 Course Code: MBF702.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Eighth Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
Version 1.2 Copyright © 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to:
Portfolio Management-Learning Objective
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Chapter 7.
Chapter 13 CAPM and APT Investments
6 Analysis of Risk and Return ©2006 Thomson/South-Western.
Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to: Thomson/South-Western 5191 Natorp Blvd. Mason, OH Chapter 11.
Risk and Capital Budgeting Chapter 13. Chapter 13 - Outline What is Risk? Risk Related Measurements Coefficient of Correlation The Efficient Frontier.
Return and Risk: The Capital-Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Expected Returns (Single assets & Portfolios), Variance, Diversification, Efficient Set, Market.
Lecture 10 The Capital Asset Pricing Model Expectation, variance, standard error (deviation), covariance, and correlation of returns may be based on.
Chapter 06 Risk and Return. Value = FCF 1 FCF 2 FCF ∞ (1 + WACC) 1 (1 + WACC) ∞ (1 + WACC) 2 Free cash flow (FCF) Market interest rates Firm’s business.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 6.
Risk and Return: Portfolio Theory and Assets Pricing Models
Asset Pricing Models Chapter 9
1 Estimating Return and Risk Chapter 7 Jones, Investments: Analysis and Management.
Asset Pricing Models CHAPTER 8. What are we going to learn in this chaper?
Chapter 7 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
Chapter 6 Efficient Diversification Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
FIN437 Vicentiu Covrig 1 Portfolio management Optimum asset allocation Optimum asset allocation (see chapter 8 RN)
1 INVESTMENT ANALYSIS & PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Lecture # 35 Shahid A. Zia Dr. Shahid A. Zia.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part. Chapter.
Chapter 15 Portfolio Theory
Return and Risk Lecture 2 Calculation of Covariance
Capital Market Theory: An Overview
Asset Pricing Models Chapter 9
Key Concepts and Skills
Return and Risk The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
Topic 4: Portfolio Concepts
Markowitz Risk - Return Optimization
Decisions Under Risk and Uncertainty
INVESTMENTS: Analysis and Management Second Canadian Edition
Risk and Rates of Return
Investments: Analysis and Management
Risk and Return.
Asset Pricing Models Chapter 9
Chapter 19 Jones, Investments: Analysis and Management
Principles of Investing FIN 330
Risk and Return Fundamentals
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
Portfolio Selection 8/28/2018 Dr.P.S DoMS, SAPM V unit.
TOPIC 3.1 CAPITAL MARKET THEORY
Saif Ullah Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and.
Asset Pricing Models Chapter 9
Chapter 6 Risk and Rates of Return.
Chapter 8: An Introduction to Asset Pricing Models
FIN 360: Corporate Finance
Copyright © 2010 by Nelson Education Ltd. 7-1 Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 2.
Global Equity Markets.
Presentation transcript:

FIN 377: Investments Topic 4: An Introduction to Portfolio Management Larry Schrenk, Instructor

Overview 6.1 Some Background Assumptions 6.2 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 6.3 The Efficient Frontier 6.4 Capital Market Theory

Learning Objectives @

Readings Reilley, et al., Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management, Chap. 6

6.1 Some Background Assumptions

6.1 Some Background Assumptions Investors want to maximize return from the total set of investments for a given level of risk Portfolio includes all assets and liabilities Relationship between the returns for assets in the portfolio is important A good portfolio is not simply a collection of individually good investments

6.1.1 Risk Aversion Given a choice between two assets with equal rates of return, risk-averse investors will select the asset with the lower level of risk Evidence Many investors purchase insurance purchase various types of insurance, including life insurance, car insurance, and health insurance Yield on bonds increases with risk classifications, which indicates that investors require a higher rate of return to accept higher risk Not all investors are risk averse It may depend on the amount of money involved Risking small amounts, but insuring large losses

6.1.2 Definition of Risk For most investors, risk means the uncertainty of future outcomes An alternative definition may be the probability of an adverse outcome

Diversification: An Example We bounce a rubber ball and record the height of each bounce. The average bounce height is very volatile As we add more balls… Average bounce height less volatile. Greater heights ‘cancels’ smaller heights

Average Bounce

Average Bounce

Average Bounce

Average Bounce

Bouncing Ball Standard Deviation

Diversification: An Analogy ‘Cancellation’ effect = diversification Hold one stock and record daily return The return is very volatile. As we add more stock… Average return less volatile Larger returns ‘cancels’ smaller returns

Diversification: The Dis-Analogy Stocks are not identical to balls. Drop more balls, volatility will Eventually go to zero. Add more stocks, volatility will Decrease, but Level out at a point well above zero.

Stock Diversification Key Idea: No matter how many stocks in my portfolio, the volatility will not get to zero!

What Different about Stocks? As I start adding stocks The non-market risks of some stocks cancel the non-market risks of other stocks. The volatility begins to go down.

What Different about Stocks? At some point, all non-market risks cancel each other. But there is still market risk! But volatility can never reach zero. Diversification cannot reduce market risk.

Diversification and Market Risk Impact on all firms in the market No cancellation effect Example: Government doubles the corporate tax All firms worse off Holding many different stocks would not help. Diversification can eliminate my portfolio’s exposure to non-markets risks, but not the exposure to market risk.

What Happens in Stock Diversification?▪ Non-Market Risk Volatility of Portfolio Market Risk Number of Stocks

Empirical Diversification Example Five Companies Ford (F) Walt Disney (DIS) IBM Marriott International (MAR) Wal-Mart (WMT)

Diversification Example (cont’d) Five Equally Weighted Portfolios Portfolio Equal Value in… F Ford F,D Ford, Disney F,D,I, Ford, Disney, IBM F,D,I,M Ford, Disney, IBM, Marriott F,D,I,M,W Ford, Disney, IBM, Marriott, Wal-Mart Minimum Variance Portfolio (MVP)

Individual Returns

F Portfolio

F,D Portfolio

F,D,I Portfolio

F,D,I,M Portfolio

F,D,I,M,W Portfolio

F,D,I,M,W versus F Portfolio

Equally Weighted versus MVP

MVP versus F Portfolio

Decreasing Risk

A Well-Diversified Portfolio Non-market risks eliminated by diversification Assumption: All investors hold well-diversified portfolios. Index funds S&P 500 Russell 2000 Wilshire 5000

Implications If investors hold well-diversified portfolios… Ignore non-market risk No compensation for non-market risk Only concern is market risk Risk Identification. If you hold a well diversified portfolio, then your only exposure is to market risk. Risk Analysis, Step 1 Revised

6.2 Markowitz Portfolio Theory

6.2 Markowitz Portfolio Theory The Markowitz model is based on several assumptions regarding investor behavior: Investors consider each investment alternative as being represented by a probability distribution of potential returns over some holding period Investors maximize one-period expected utility, and their utility curves demonstrate diminishing marginal utility of wealth Investors estimate the risk of the portfolio on the basis of the variability of potential returns Investors base decisions solely on expected return and risk, so their utility curves are a function of expected return and the variance (or standard deviation) of returns only For a given risk level, investors prefer higher returns to lower returns. Similarly, for a given level of expected return, investors prefer less risk to more risk

6.2 Markowitz Portfolio Theory Using these assumptions, a single asset or portfolio of assets is considered to be efficient if no other asset or portfolio of assets offers higher expected return with the same (or lower) risk or lower risk with the same (or higher) expected return

6.2.1 Alternative Measures of Risk Variance or standard deviation of expected return Range of returns Returns below expectations Semi-variance – a measure that only considers deviations below the mean These measures of risk implicitly assume that investors want to minimize the damage from returns less than some target rate

6.2.1 Alternative Measures of Risk Advantages of using variance or standard deviation of returns: Measure is somewhat intuitive Widely recognized risk measure Has been used in most of the theoretical asset pricing models

6.2.2 Expected Rates of Return Expected rate of return For an individual investment Equal to the sum of the potential returns multiplied with the corresponding probability of the returns For a portfolio of investments Equal to the weighted average of the expected rates of return for the individual investments in the portfolio

6.2.2 Expected Rates of Return

6.2.2 Expected Rates of Return

6.2.3 Variance of Returns for an Individual Investment The variance is a measure of the variation of possible rates of return:

6.2.3 Variance of Returns for an Individual Investment The standard deviation is also a measure of the variation of possible rates of return:

6.2.3 Variance (Standard Deviation) of Returns for an Individual Investment

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio Covariance of Returns A measure of the degree to which two variables “move together” relative to their individual mean values over time For two assets, x and y, the covariance of rates of return is defined as:

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio Covariance and Correlation The correlation coefficient (r) is obtained by standardizing (dividing) the covariance by the product of the individual standard deviations

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio The coefficient can vary only in the range +1 to -1 A value of +1 would indicate perfect positive correlation. This means that returns for the two assets move together in a positively and completely linear manner A value of –1 would indicate perfect negative correlation. This means that the returns for two assets move together in a completely linear manner, but in opposite directions

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio Portfolio Variance Formula

6.2.4 Variance of Returns for a Portfolio Two-Asset Portfolio Variance Formula

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of Returns for a Portfolio Portfolio Standard Deviation Formula

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of Returns for a Portfolio Two-Asset Standard Deviation Variance Formula

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio Impact of a New Security in a Portfolio Two effects to the portfolio’s standard deviation when we add a new security to such a portfolio: The asset’s own variance of returns The covariance between the returns of this new asset and the returns of every other asset that is already in the portfolio The relative weight of these numerous covariances is substantially greater than the asset’s unique variance; the more assets in the portfolio, the more this is true The important factor to consider when adding an investment to a portfolio that contains a number of other investments is not the new security’s own variance but the average covariance of this asset with all other investments in the portfolio

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio Portfolio Standard Deviation Calculation Any asset or portfolio of assets can be described by two characteristics: The expected rate of return The standard deviation of returns

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio Equal Risk and Return—Changing Correlations The expected return of the portfolio does not change because it is simply the weighted average of the individual expected returns Demonstrates the concept of diversification, whereby the risk of the portfolio is lower than the risk of either of the assets held in the portfolio Risk reduction benefit occurs to some degree any time the assets combined in a portfolio are not perfectly positively correlated (that is, whenever ri,j < +1) Diversification works because there will be investment periods when a negative return to one asset will be offset by a positive return to the other, thereby reducing the variability of the overall portfolio return

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio The negative covariance term exactly offsets the individual variance terms, leaving an overall standard deviation of the portfolio of zero This would be a risk-free portfolio, meaning that the average combined return for the two securities over time would be a constant value (that is, have no variability) Thus, a pair of completely negatively correlated assets provides the maximum benefits of diversification by completely eliminating variability from the portfolio

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio Combining Stocks with Different Returns and Risk Consider two assets (or portfolios) with different expected rates of return and individual standard deviations With perfect negative correlation, the portfolio standard deviation is not zero This is because the different examples have equal weights, but the asset standard deviations are not equal

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio Constant Correlation with Changing Weights If the weights of the two assets are changed while holding the correlation coefficient constant, a set of combinations is derived that trace an ellipse The benefits of diversification are critically dependent on the correlation between assets

6.2.5 Standard Deviation of a Portfolio

Two Asset Portfolio: Example Return s Weight r A 7% 19% 80% 0.8 B 11% 22% 20% NOTE: sp < sA and sp < sB

Example If I hold a stock with a standard deviation of 20%, would I get more diversification by adding a stock with a standard deviation of 10% or 30%? If I added two stocks each with a standard deviation of 25%, the standard deviation of the portfolio could be anywhere from 25% to 0%–depending on the correlation. If r = 1, s = 25% If r = -1, s = 0% (with the optimal weights)

Standard Deviation and Stock Risk Standard deviation tells nothing about… Stock’s diversification effect on a portfolio; or Whether including that stock will increase or decrease the exposure to market risk. Thus, standard deviation (and variance) Not a correct measure of market risk, and Cannot be used as our measure of risk in the analysis of stocks.

6.2.6 A Three-Asset Portfolio The results presented earlier for the two-asset portfolio can be extended to a portfolio of n assets As more assets are added to the portfolio, more risk will be reduced (everything else being the same) The general computing procedure is still the same, but the amount of computation has increase rapidly For the three-asset portfolio, the computation has doubled in comparison with the two-asset portfolio

6.2.7 Estimation Issues Results of portfolio allocation depend on accurate statistical inputs Estimates of Expected returns Standard deviation Correlation coefficient Among entire set of assets With 100 assets, 4,950 correlation estimates Estimation risk refers to potential errors

6.2.7 Estimation Issues With the assumption that stock returns can be described by a single market model, the number of correlations required reduces to the number of assets Single index market model: Ri = ai + biRm + ei

6.2.7 Estimation Issues If all the securities are similarly related to the market and a bi derived for each one, it can be shown that the correlation coefficient between two securities i and j is given as:

6.3 The Efficient Frontier

6.3 The Efficient Frontier The efficient frontier represents that set of portfolios with the maximum rate of return for every given level of risk or the minimum risk for every level of return Every portfolio that lies on the efficient frontier has either a higher rate of return for the same risk level or lower risk for an equal rate of return than some portfolio falling below the frontier See Exhibit 6.13 Portfolio A in Exhibit 6.13 dominates Portfolio C because it has an equal rate of return but substantially less risk Portfolio B dominates Portfolio C because it has equal risk but a higher expected rate of return

6.3 The Efficient Frontier

6.3 The Efficient Frontier Markowitz defined the basic problem that the investor needs to solve as: Select {wi} so as to: subject to the following conditions: i) E(Rport) = Swi E(Ri) = R* ii) Swi = 1.0

6.3 The Efficient Frontier The general method for solving the formula is called a constrained optimization procedure because the task the investor faces is to select the investment weights that will “optimize” the objective (minimize portfolio risk) while also satisfying two restrictions (constraints) on the investment process: The portfolio must produce an expected return at least as large as the return goal, R; and All of the investment weights must sum to 1.0 The approach to forming portfolios according to this equation is often referred to as mean-variance optimization because it requires the investor to minimize portfolio risk for a given expected (mean) return goal

6.3.1 The Efficient Frontier: An Example What would be the optimal asset allocation strategy using these five asset classes?

6.3.1 The Efficient Frontier: An Example

6.3.1 The Efficient Frontier: An Example

6.3.2 The Efficient Frontier and Investor Utility An individual investor’s utility curve specifies the trade-offs he is willing to make between expected return and risk The slope of the efficient frontier curve decreases steadily as you move upward The interactions of these two curves will determine the particular portfolio selected by an individual investor The optimal portfolio has the highest utility for a given investor

6.3.2 The Efficient Frontier and Investor Utility The optimal lies at the point of tangency between the efficient frontier and the utility curve with the highest possible utility See Exhibit 6.16 Investor X with the set of utility curves will achieve the highest utility by investing the portfolio at X With a different set of utility curves, Investor Y will achieve the highest utility by investing the portfolio at Y Which investor is more risk averse?

6.3.2 The Efficient Frontier and Investor Utility

6.4 Capital Market Theory

6.4 Capital Market Theory: An Overview Capital market theory builds directly on the portfolio theory we have just developed by extending the Markowitz efficient frontier into a model for valuing all risky assets Capital market theory also has important implications for how portfolios are managed in practice The development of this approach depends on the existence of a risk-free asset, which in turn will lead to the designation of the market portfolio

6.4.1 Background for Capital Market Theory Assumptions: All investors are Markowitz efficient investors who want to target points on the efficient frontier Investors can borrow or lend any amount of money at the risk-free rate of return (RFR) All investors have homogeneous expectations; that is, they estimate identical probability distributions for future rates of return All investors have the same one-period time horizon such as one month, six months, or one year

6.4.1 Background for Capital Market Theory Assumptions (Continued) All investments are infinitely divisible, which means that it is possible to buy or sell fractional shares of any asset or portfolio There are no taxes or transaction costs involved in buying or selling assets There is no inflation or any change in interest rates, or inflation is fully anticipated Capital markets are in equilibrium, which implies that all investments are properly priced in line with their risk levels

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line A risky asset is one for which future returns are uncertain Uncertainty is measured by the standard deviation of expected returns Because the expected return on a risk-free asset is entirely certain, the standard deviation of its expected return is zero The rate of return earned on such an asset should be the risk-free

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line Covariance with a Risk-Free Asset Covariance between two sets of returns is Because the returns for the risk free asset are certain, the covariance between the risk-free asset and any risky asset or portfolio will always be zero Similarly, the correlation between any risky asset and the risk-free asset would be zero

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line Combining Risk-Free Asset with a Risky Portfolio Expected Return Is the weighted average of the two returns: E(Rport) = wrf rf + (1 - wrf)E(Rm) Standard Deviation Is the linear proportion of the standard deviation of the risky asset portfolio

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line The Risk–Return Combination Investors who allocate their money between a riskless security and the risky Portfolio M can expect a return equal to the risk-free rate plus compensation for the number of risk units (σport) they accept

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line The risk–return relationship holds for every combination of the risk-free asset with any collection of risky assets This relationship holds for every combination of the risk-free asset with any collection of risky assets However, when the risky portfolio, M, is the market portfolio containing all risky assets held anywhere in the marketplace, this linear relationship is called the Capital Market Line (CML)

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line Risk–Return Possibilities with Leverage One can attain a higher expected return than is available at point M One can invest along the efficient frontier beyond point M, such as point D With the risk-free asset, one can add leverage to the portfolio by borrowing money at the risk-free rate and investing in the risky portfolio at point M to achieve a point like E Clearly, point E dominates point D Similarly, one can reduce the investment risk by lending money at the risk-free asset to reach points like C

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line

6.4.2 Developing the Capital Market Line

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio Because portfolio M lies at the point of tangency, it has the highest portfolio possibility line Everybody will want to invest in Portfolio M and borrow or lend to be somewhere on the CML It must include all risky assets Because the market is in equilibrium, all assets in this portfolio are in proportion to their market values Because it contains all risky assets, it is a completely diversified portfolio, which means that all the unique risk of individual assets (unsystematic risk) is diversified away

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio Systematic risk Only systematic risk remains in the market portfolio Systematic risk can be measured by the standard deviation of returns of the market portfolio and can change over time Systematic risk is the variability in all risky assets caused by macroeconomic variables: Variability in growth of money supply Interest rate volatility Variability in factors like industrial production, corporate earnings, cash flow

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio Diversification and the Elimination of Unsystematic Risk The purpose of diversification is to reduce the standard deviation of the total portfolio This assumes that imperfect correlations exist among securities As you add securities, you expect the average covariance for the portfolio to decline How many securities must you add to obtain a completely diversified portfolio?

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio The CML and the Separation Theorem The CML leads all investors to invest in the M portfolio Individual investors should differ in position on the CML depending on risk preferences How an investor gets to a point on the CML is based on financing decisions Risk averse investors will lend at the risk-free rate, while investors preferring more risk might borrow funds at the RFR and invest in the market portfolio The investment decision of choosing the point on CML is separate from the financing decision of reaching there through either lending or borrowing

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio A Risk Measure for the CML Capital market theory now shows that the only relevant portfolio is the market Portfolio M. Together, this means that the only important consideration for any individual risky asset is its average covariance with all the risky assets in Portfolio M or the asset’s covariance with the market portfolio This covariance, then, is the relevant risk measure for an individual risky asset

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio Because all individual risky assets are a part of the market portfolio, one can describe their rates of return in relation to the returns to Portfolio M using a linear model: Rit = ai +biRMt + e The variance of returns for a risky asset can similarly be described as: Var(Rit) = Var(ai +biRMt + e) = Var(ai) + Var(biRMt) + Var(e) = 0+ Var(biRMt) + Var(e)

6.4.3 Risk, Diversification, and the Market Portfolio Note that Var(biRMt) is the variance of return for an asset related to the variance of the market return, or the asset’s systematic variance or risk Also, Var(ε) is the residual variance of return for the individual asset that is not related to the market portfolio This residual variance is what we have referred to as the unsystematic or unique risk because it arises from the unique features of the asset Therefore: Var(Rit) = Systematic Variance + Unsystematic Variance

6.4.4 Investing with the CML: An Example Suppose you have a riskless security at 4% and a market portfolio with a return of 9% and a standard deviation of 10%. How should you go about investing your money so that your investment will have a risk level of 15%? Portfolio Return E(Rport) = rf+σport[(E(RM) - rf)/σM) = 4%+15%[(9%-4%)/10%] = 11.5% Money invested in riskless security, wRF 11.5% = wRF (4%) + (1-wRF )(9%) ----> wRF = -0.5 The investment strategy is to borrow 50% and invest 150% of equity in the market portfolio

6.4.4 Investing with the CML: An Example