Health Economics for Prescribers

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlikeLicense. Your use of this material constitutes acceptance of that license.
Advertisements

Elicitation methods Health care demands exceed resource supply Therefore, rationing is inevitable Many ways by which we can ration health care One is economic.
Health Economics for Prescribers
Health Economics for Prescribers
Health Economics for Prescribers
Health Economics for Prescribers
HEA PTP: M207 Health Economics1 Measurement & Valuation of Health What is health? Why do we need to measure it? How can it be measured? Why do we need.
Measuring outcomes Emma Frew October Measuring outcomes Learning objectives By the end of the session students should be able to – Explain how different.
How would you explain the smoking paradox. Smokers fair better after an infarction in hospital than non-smokers. This apparently disagrees with the view.
Exploring uncertainty in cost effectiveness analysis NICE International and HITAP copyright © 2013 Francis Ruiz NICE International (acknowledgements to:
Introduction to decision modelling Andrew Sutton.
Utility Assessment HINF Medical Methodologies Session 4.
Recommendations for Conducting Cost Effectiveness: Elements of the Reference Case Ciaran S. Phibbs, Ph.D. February 25, 2009.
A METHODOLOGY FOR MEASURING THE COST- UTILITY OF EARLY CHILDHOOD DEVELOPMENTAL INTERVENTIONS Quality of improved life opportunities (QILO)
Results 2 (cont’d) c) Long term observational data on the duration of effective response Observational data on n=50 has EVSI = £867 d) Collect data on.
COST–EFFECTIVENESS ANALYSIS AND COST-UTILITY ANALYSIS
AGEC 608 Lecture 14, p. 1 AGEC 608: Lecture 14 Objective: Provide overview of contingent valuation method (CVM) and review strengths and weaknesses of.
Health care decision making Dr. Giampiero Favato presented at the University Program in Health Economics Ragusa, June 2008.
AGEC 608 Lecture 17, p. 1 AGEC 608: Lecture 17 Objective: Review the main aspects of cost- effectiveness analysis (CEA) and cost-utility analysis (CUA).
Health Economics & Policy 3 rd Edition James W. Henderson Chapter 4 Economic Evaluation in Health Care.
Economic Evaluations, Briefly… CHSC 433 Module 6/Chapter 13 UIC School of Public Health L. Michele Issel, PhD, R N.
EVIDENCE BASED MEDICINE Health economics Ross Lawrenson.
Knowing what you get for what you pay An introduction to cost effectiveness FETP India.
How can societal concerns for fairness be integrated in economic evaluations of health programs? Erik Nord, PhD, Senior Researcher, Norwegian Institute.
Economic evaluation of health programmes Department of Epidemiology, Biostatistics and Occupational Health Class no. 4: Measuring costs - Part 1 Sept 15,
Economic evaluation Definition - the comparative analysis of alternative courses of action in terms of both their cost and consequences.
317_L26, Mar J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture Are looking at program evaluation in healthcare Three methods: CBA, CEA, CUA discussed CBA,
Economic evaluation of health programmes Department of Epidemiology, Biostatistics and Occupational Health Class no. 6: Cost-effectiveness analysis – Part.
Basic Economic Analysis David Epstein, Centre for Health Economics, York.
انواع ارزيابي های اقتصادي سيدرضا مجدزاده مرکز تحقيقات بهره برداری از دانش سلامت و دانشکده بهداشت دانشگاه علوم پزشکي و خدمات بهداشتي درماني تهران.
Make Nutrition Services Count: Cost-Effectiveness Research & Outcomes Research.
Economic evaluation of health programmes Department of Epidemiology, Biostatistics and Occupational Health Class no. 13: Cost-benefit analysis – Part 2.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Valuing the Environment: Methods.
Flagship Program on Health Sector Reform and Sustainable Financing.
Who is involved in making NICE guidance recommendations and what evidence do they look at? Jane Cowl, Senior Public Involvement Adviser Tommy Wilkinson,
CRJS 4466 PROGRAM & POLICY EVALUATION LECTURE #6 Evaluation projects Questions?
Economic evaluation of health programmes Department of Epidemiology, Biostatistics and Occupational Health Class no. 7: Cost-effectiveness analysis – Part.
Lecture 8 Social Regulation. Correction of market failures, not dealing with the natural monopoly problem Regulation of health, safety, environment, public.
Key Concepts and Skills
Analysis Manager Training Module
Cost effectiveness Analysis: Valuing Health; Valuing Research!
HEALTH ECONOMICS BASICS
Global burden of diseases
Preference Assessment 1 Measuring Utilities Directly
Lecture 15 Assoc. Prof. Sencer Ecer HEALTH ECONOMICS
“Analytical Tools and Data Collection” Workshop April 2009 EuropeAid/125317/D/SER/TR Roman Ladus Session 6 Measuring Impacts 1.
EWG Study Tour, Galway, 18/09/2006
Measuring Results and Impact Evaluation: From Promises into Evidence
Present: Disease Past: Exposure
How many study subjects are required ? (Estimation of Sample size) By Dr.Shaik Shaffi Ahamed Associate Professor Dept. of Family & Community Medicine.
Net Present Value and Other Investment Rules
Economic Evaluation of Health Interventions Basic Concepts
Randomized Trials: A Brief Overview
Strategies to incorporate pharmacoeconomics into pharmacotherapy
Chapter 7 The Hierarchy of Evidence
A Primer on Health Economics and Cost-Effectiveness
NAPLEX preparation: Biostatistics
Experiments and Observational Studies
Health care decision making
Sergio Bautista-Arredondo National Institute of Public Health Mexico
C h a p t e r 6 COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENTS
How to apply successfully to the NIHR HTA Board?
Assessing value for money: principles, methods and issues
Economic Problems 4/18/2019.
Health Economics for Prescribers
Health Economics for Prescribers
Measuring outcomes Emma Frew October 2012.
Elicitation methods Health care demands exceed resource supply
Presentation Developed for the Academy of Managed Care Pharmacy
Presentation transcript:

Health Economics for Prescribers Richard Smith (MED) richard.smith@uea.ac.uk David Wright (CAP) d.j.wright@uea.ac.uk 1

Lecture 3 recap (resources & costs) Identification (checklist 4) Indirect costs Measurement (checklist 5) Fixed, variable and total cost Average, marginal and incremental cost (checklist 8) Discounting (checklist 7) Valuation (checklist 6) Cost versus price Inflation Sources of unit cost data 93

‘Drummond’ checklist Was a well-defined question posed in answerable form? Was a comprehensive description of alternatives given? Was there evidence that effectiveness had been established? Were all the important and relevant costs and consequences for each alternative identified? Were costs and consequences measured accurately/appropriately? Were costs and consequences valued credibly? Were costs and consequences adjusted for differential timing? Was an incremental analysis performed? Was allowance made for uncertainty? Did presentation/discussion of results include all issues of concern? 93

Types of economic evaluation Type of Analysis Result Consequences Costs Cost Minimisation Cost Benefit Cost Utility Cost Effectiveness Money Single or multiple effects not necessarily common. Valued as “utility” eg. QALY Different magnitude of a common measure eg., LY’s gained, blood pressure reduction. Least cost alternative. Identical in all respects. Cost per unit of consequence eg. cost per LY gained. Cost per unit of consequence eg. cost per QALY. As for CUA but valued in money. Net £ cost: benefit ratio. 93

Lecture 4: Pharmaco-economic evaluation – benefits and outcomes Identification Mortality, Quality of life etc. Cost versus benefit Productivity changes Measurement In natural physical units (eg. number of lives saved) Intermediate versus final outcomes Valuation if appropriate Utility (for CUA) Money (for CBA) 93

1. Identification Which outcome measure is employed depends on the objective of the evaluation Comparing within treatment area/disease Compare across health service (system) Societal evaluation - health care set against other alternative uses for the resources This then determines the type of evaluation Cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) Cost-utility analysis (CUA) Cost-benefit analysis (CBA) 93

Costs versus benefits C/E ratio = net cost/net benefits Net cost = positive cost and negative cost Negative cost = cost saving (eg reduced LoS) Net benefit = positive benefit and negative benefit Negative benefit = reduced health (eg side-effect) Rule of thumb – anything related to resources on cost side, anything related to ‘health’ on benefits 93

Should changes in productivity be included? Depends upon viewpoint (govt., societal, NHS) Main issues are level of ‘true’ loss/gain and comparability Measurement of value (gross wage, friction cost) Double-counting, especially with CUA/CBA Comparability with ‘health’ focus (viewpoint again) Comparability with other studies Solution? Provide a good reason why they should be included Report separately from other results Differentiate measurement and valuation 93

2. Measurement Measure effectiveness not efficacy Efficacy = measure of effect under ideal conditions (can it work?) Effectiveness = effect under ‘real life’ conditions (does it work?) Efficacy does not imply effectiveness Measure (count) in natural physical units Number of lives/life years Change in blood pressure Change in cholesterol levels Measure final not intermediate outcomes Intermediate outcomes reflect change in clinical indicators Final outcomes reflect change in health status 93

Examples of Intermediate Vs Final Outcomes 93

Sources of effectiveness data Clinical trials, esp RCTs, considered strongest evidence as minimal bias and few confounding factors (takes account of ‘unknown unknowns’) but often establishes efficacy selective subjects, time horizon etc Epidemiological studies, cohort studies, real life setting so establish effectiveness, but potential for bias and numerous confounding factors causal links can be weak and disputed Synthesis methods, meta analysis/systematic review, allows for singular insufficient data to be combined, but ‘heterogeneity’ in observations (apples and pears?) potential biases in searching and reviewing Once we have identified what the most appropriate outcome is we need to see about measuring it. Before doing that want to highlight the general ways that this data is collected. This is similar to how we would collect cost data. As with cost data or resource use each has its merits.

Example of cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) Alternative dosage of lovastatin in secondary prevention of heart disease (Goldman et al 1991, JAMA 265: 1145-51) Ages 65-74 Daily dose Cost ($bn) Life years Cost/Life year 20 mg. 3.615 348,272 10,400 40 mg. 7.051 477,204 14,800 Work through another example. They looked at the cost effectiveness of different treatment regimes for primary and secondary prevention of CHD. Used a computer simulation model to estimate the instances of heart disease and risk of recurrent events. In example increasing the dose of lovastatin saved lives and life years, but costs also increased.

Limitations of measurement (i.e. just CEA) Ambiguity in assessing overall improvement or decrement in health (addressed by CUA/CBA) Are limitations to how helpful cost effectiveness analyses are. All because of the outcome measure. Consider this example. Compared to B, A is more cost effective, costs less and gives greater benefit. So in dominates box. Cannot address the issue of allocative efficiency (addressed only by CBA)

3. Valuation Value is determined by benefits sacrificed elsewhere (see opportunity cost again) Valuation requires a trade-off between benefits - measurement does not Valuation either in terms of Utility (eg QALY) Money (eg WTP) There are two possible outcomes which place a value on health. One is to elicit a preference for a health state which is then used to weight time in that health state. The most common way to do this is the QALY, although we will discuss others. Alternatively you can place a monetary value on health and then compare money gained to money spent. This results in a cost benefit analysis and we will discuss this in full next week.

Types of economic evaluation Type of Analysis Result Consequences Costs Cost Minimisation Cost Benefit Cost Utility Cost Effectiveness Money Single or multiple effects not necessarily common. Valued as “utility” eg. QALY Different magnitude of a common measure eg., LY’s gained, blood pressure reduction. Least cost alternative. Identical in all respects. Cost per unit of consequence eg. cost per LY gained. Cost per unit of consequence eg. cost per QALY. As for CUA but valued in money. Net £ cost: benefit ratio. 93

Example of ‘added value’ of CUA Laser assisted versus standard angioplasty (Sculpher et al, 1996) No matter what measure you use the important thing is what you do with them, use them to adjust the quantity of life in a health state to give an outcome measure which represents both quality and quantity.

Quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) Adjust quantity of life years saved to reflect a valuation of the quality of life If healthy QALY = 1 If unhealthy QALY < 1 QALY can be <0 No matter what measure you use the important thing is what you do with them, use them to adjust the quantity of life in a health state to give an outcome measure which represents both quality and quantity.

QALY procedure Identify possible health states - cover all important/relevant dimensions of QoL Derive utility ‘weights’ for each state Multiply life years (spent in each state) by ‘weight’ for that state.

Calculating QALYs example Weights: Good health = 1 moderate health = 0.8 poor health = 0.5 LYs: Year 1 + year 2 + year 3 = 3LYs (1+1+1) QALYs: Year 1(x0.5), year 2(x0.8), year 3(x1) = 2.3 QALYs (0.5+0.8+1) Intervention may increase recovery such that year 1(x0.8), year 2(x1), year 3(x1) = 2.8 QALYs (0.8+1+1) No difference in LYs but gain in QALYs

Utility ‘weight’ Utility = satisfaction/value/preference Utility weights are necessarily subjective Represent individual’s preferences for, or value of, one or more health states. Must Have interval properties Be “anchored” at death (0) and good health (1) [can be negative]

Techniques to ‘weight’ utility

Choice of technique Generally values/utilities elicited differ between the techniques, such that SG>TTO>RS In general this is also preference order, but choice often contingent on time Different generic scales use different scoring techniques (eg EQ-5D=TTO – see later) What is generally found in research that uses each method, is that standard gamble values will be larger than time trade-off values which are larger than rating scale values. This is because of different representations of risk, standard gamble is based on uncertainty, whereas time trade-off has certain outcomes. Difference between time trade-off and rating scaling is that one requires a choice, whereas the other is a ranking of all health states. So which is the best to use, what conforms closest to the theory? Standard gamble is based on expected utility theory and involves uncertainty, but obviously choice of technique can be contingent on time, easiest is surely the rating scale, whereas TTO and SG are more interview intensive.

Sources of ‘utility’ weights 1: Evaluation specific Develop evaluation specific description of relevant health state and then derive weight directly by survey using one of the previous techniques Advantages Sensitive account for wider QoL (process, duration, prognosis) Disadvantages resource intensive lack of comparability Those techniques just discussed, as well as some others, can be used to measure strength of preference, but there are two other ways that we can derive values or utilities to use in the denominator of a cost-utility analysis. As with clinical effectiveness we can use previously published data or we can use valued judgement.

Sources of ‘utility’ weights 2: ‘Generic’/‘multi-attribute’ instrument Predetermined weights (using one of techniques above) for specified combination of dimensions of health yielding a finite number of health state values Advantages Supply weights “off the shelf” Comparable across studies Disadvantages insensitive to small changes dimensions may not be sufficiently comprehensive weights may not be transferable across groups Those techniques just discussed, as well as some others, can be used to measure strength of preference, but there are two other ways that we can derive values or utilities to use in the denominator of a cost-utility analysis. As with clinical effectiveness we can use previously published data or we can use valued judgement.

Generic instrument example: EQ-5D 5 dimensions, 3 levels = 245 health states (35) Example values: Health state 11111 = 1.00 Health state 12111 = 0.82 Health state 11223 = 0.26 93

Monetary Valuation / CBA CUA still does not address: Allocative efficiency: is health gain ‘worth’ more than benefits those resources could yield elsewhere (health or non-health)? Valuation of non-health benefits eg process, information, convenience Valuation of non-use benefits ie externalities, option value

Methods of Monetary Valuation Assess individual ‘willingness-to-pay’ for (the benefits of) a good through either: Observed wealth-risk trade-off (revealed preference) Advantage – ‘real’ preferences/values Disadvantage – difficult control for confounders Direct survey (stated preference) Advantage – direct valuation of good Disadvantage – hypothetical/survey problems Vast majority of CBA use direct survey

Process of calculating monetary value of benefits using survey WTP Provide ‘scenario’ describing benefits and all aspects of ‘market’ (eg payment vehicle) Ask for respondents valuation using specific technique: open-ended question - maximum WTP payment card – chose from range of values closed-ended/binary question Calculate mean/median WTP for sample (cf ‘price’ in competitive market) Those techniques just discussed, as well as some others, can be used to measure strength of preference, but there are two other ways that we can derive values or utilities to use in the denominator of a cost-utility analysis. As with clinical effectiveness we can use previously published data or we can use valued judgement.

Simplified WTP question for VPF Suppose the risk of a car driver being killed in a car accident is 20 in 100,000. You could choose to have a safety feature fitted which would halve the risk of the driver being killed, down to 10 in 100,000. What is the most you would be willing to pay to have this safety feature fitted to your car?

Simplified WTP calculation Reduction in risk (dR) = 10 in 100,000 Mean WTP (dV) = £100 Implied value of prevented fatality (dV/dR) = £1m (£100/0.0001=£1,000,000) Issues of context – VPF differs for road accident, rail accident, health care etc

WTP and ATP (ability to pay) WTP is (partly) determined by income generally regarded as important factor equal income not a goal in western society Can and should it be ‘solved’ WTP as a % of income requires specification of alternative SWF ie what alternative distribution of income?

Summary Any evaluation must distinguish between identification, measurement and valuation of benefits/outcomes Identification Only non-resource use (cost-savings on cost side of equation) Treat productivity savings carefully Measurement Final not intermediate outcomes All that is needed for CEA Valuation For CUA expressed as QALYs For CBA expressed as WTP Move from CEA→CUA→CBA increases the complexity and difficulty of evaluation so needs justifying 93