16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
Advertisements

In this chapter, you will learn…
Chapter overview This chapter surveys the most prominent work on consumption: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher and Intertemporal.
MANKIW'S MACROECONOMICS MODULES
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
Chapter 21 The Theory of Consumer Choice
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
In this chapter, you will learn:
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Review of the Previous Lecture Traditional View of Government Debt Ricardian View of Government Debt Myopia Borrowing Constraints Other Perspectives –Fiscal.
Review of the Previous Lecture
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER SIXTEEN.
MACROECONOMICS © 2010 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved S E V E N T H E D I T I O N PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw C H A P.
CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 0 Class Slides for EC 204 To Accompany Chapter 16.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 13: Consumption.
Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
Consumption and Saving
The Theory of Consumer Choice
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Principles of Microeconomics
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
This chapter presents:
The Theory of Consumer Choice
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Eva Hromadkova PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER TEN Aggregate Demand I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 10: Aggregate.
Chapter 16: Consumption.
Keynes’s Conjectures 0 < MPC < 1
© 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
The Economy in the Short-run
Chapter 15. Consumption, income and wealth ECON320 Prof Mike Kennedy.
Review of the previous lecture 1. Real Business Cycle theory  assumes perfect flexibility of wages and prices  shows how fluctuations arise in response.
Chapter Seventeen1 CHAPTER 17 Consumption ® A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 7th. Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Tutorial written by: Mannig.
Source: Romer and Bernstein, 2009 and e21, 2011.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Consumption.
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
Lecture 3 Consumption. John M. Keynes: Absolute Income Hypothesis Consumption is a linear function of disposable personal income, C = C + cY C = consumption.
Lecture by: Jacinto Fabiosa Fall 2005 Consumer Choice.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
KYIV SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS I September-October 2013 Instructor: Maksym Obrizan Lecture notes II # 2. CHAPTER 16 Consumption Household consumption.
Outlines  Introduction Introduction  Excess sensitivity and Excess sensitivity and econometric approach  The simulation design The simulation design.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
1 © ©1999 South-Western College Publishing PowerPoint Slides prepared by Ken Long Principles of Economics 2nd edition by Fred M Gottheil.
Chapter 18 The Keynesian Model
Chapter overview This chapter surveys the most prominent work on consumption: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher and Intertemporal.
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Calculate and graph a budget line that shows.
Consumption Topic 13: (chapter 16)
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 21
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Chapter 9 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption-Savings Decision and Credit Markets Macroeconomics 6th Edition Stephen D. Williamson Copyright © 2018, 2015,
Aggregate Supply & SR Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment
16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect.
The traditional view of Debt
This chapter sets up the IS-LM model, which chapter 11 then uses extensively to analyze the effects of policies and economic shocks. This chapter also.
TOPICS FOR FURTHER STUDY
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving
The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand
Abel & Bernake: Macro Ch3 Varian: Micro Ch10
Irving Fisher and Intertemporal Choice
16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect.
Presentation transcript:

16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect to continue with graduate studies in economics. After reviewing the Keynesian consumption function and its implications, the chapter presents Irving Fisher’s theory of intertemporal choice, the basis for much subsequent work on consumption. This section of the chapter uses indifference curves and budget constraints. The chapter and this PowerPoint presentation do not require or assume that students know these tools. But if they have not, then this section of the chapter is the most difficult. The chapter then presents the Life-Cycle and Permanent Income Hypotheses, and discusses Hall’s Random Walk Hypothesis. Finally, there is a brief discussion of some very recent work by Laibson and others on psychology and economics, in particular how the pull of instant gratification can cause consumers to deviate from perfect rationality. Note: if you are covering Chapter 15 on government debt, please note that you can better explain Ricardian Equivalence (a topic from Chapter 15) using the Fisher model presented in this chapter. Just show students that a debt-financed tax cut is a movement along the budget constraint, not an outward shift of the constraint, and it should be clear that the optimal bundle of current and future consumption is not affected.

In this chapter, you will learn… an introduction to the most prominent work on consumption, including: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher: intertemporal choice Franco Modigliani: the life-cycle hypothesis Milton Friedman: the permanent income hypothesis Robert Hall: the random-walk hypothesis David Laibson: the pull of instant gratification CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Keynes’s conjectures 1. 0 < MPC < 1 2. Average propensity to consume (APC ) falls as income rises. (APC = C/Y ) 3. Income is the main determinant of consumption. The MPC was defined in chapter 3 and used in various chapters since. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Keynesian consumption function c = MPC = slope of the consumption function c 1 Interpretations of C-bar: autonomous consumption: the portion of consumption that does not depend on income the value of consumption if income were zero. a shift parameter CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Keynesian consumption function As income rises, consumers save a bigger fraction of their income, so APC falls. C Y Pick a point on the consumption function; that point represents a particular combination of consumption and income. Now draw a ray from the origin to that point. The slope of that ray equals the average propensity to consume at that point. (Why? The slope equals the rise over the run. The rise from zero to that point equals the value of C at that point. The run from zero to that point equals the value of Y at that point. Hence, the rise over the run equals C/Y, or the APC.) At higher values of Y, the APC (or the slope of the ray from the origin) is smaller. This is what Keynes conjectured: at higher values of income, people spend a smaller fraction of their income. slope = APC CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Early empirical successes: Results from early studies Households with higher incomes: consume more,  MPC > 0 save more,  MPC < 1 save a larger fraction of their income,  APC  as Y  Very strong correlation between income and consumption:  income seemed to be the main determinant of consumption CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Problems for the Keynesian consumption function Based on the Keynesian consumption function, economists predicted that C would grow more slowly than Y over time. This prediction did not come true: As incomes grew, APC did not fall, and C grew at the same rate as income. Simon Kuznets showed that C/Y was very stable in long time series data. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Consumption Puzzle Consumption function from long time series data (constant APC ) C Y Consumption function from cross-sectional household data (falling APC ) CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Irving Fisher and Intertemporal Choice The basis for much subsequent work on consumption. Assumes consumer is forward-looking and chooses consumption for the present and future to maximize lifetime satisfaction. Consumer’s choices are subject to an intertemporal budget constraint, a measure of the total resources available for present and future consumption. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The basic two-period model Period 1: the present Period 2: the future Notation Y1, Y2 = income in period 1, 2 C1, C2 = consumption in period 1, 2 S = Y1 - C1 = saving in period 1 (S < 0 if the consumer borrows in period 1) Note: there is no saving in period 2. Period 2 is the final period, and there are no bequests, so saving in period 2 would only reduce lifetime consumption and therefore lifetime utility/satisfaction. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Deriving the intertemporal budget constraint Period 2 budget constraint: Rearrange terms: Explain the intuition/interpretation of the period 2 budget constraint. If students understand it, then everything else follows nicely. Divide through by (1+r ) to get… CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The intertemporal budget constraint present value of lifetime consumption present value of lifetime income If your students are not familiar with the present value concept, it is explained in a very nice FYI box on p.463. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The intertemporal budget constraint Saving Consump = income in both periods The budget constraint shows all combinations of C1 and C2 that just exhaust the consumer’s resources. Borrowing Y1 Y2 The point (Y1, Y2) is always on the budget line because C1=Y1, C2=Y2 is always possible, regardless of the real interest rate or the existence of borrowing constraints. To obtain the expression for the horizontal intercept, set C2=0 in the equation for the intertemporal budget constraint and solve for C1. Similarly, the expression for the vertical intercept is the value of C2 when C1=0. There is intuition for these expressions. Take the vertical intercept, for example. If the consumer sets C1=0, then he will be saving all of his first-period income. In the second period, he gets to consume this saving plus interest earned, (1+r)Y1, as well as his second-period income. If the consumer chooses C1<Y1, then the consumer will be saving, so his C2 will exceed his Y2. Conversely, if consumer chooses C1>Y1, then consumer is borrowing, so his second-period consumption will fall short of his second-period income (he must use some of the second-period income to repay the loan). CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The intertemporal budget constraint The slope of the budget line equals -(1+r ) 1 (1+r ) Y1 Y2 The slope of the budget line equals -(1+r): To increase C1 by one unit, the consumer must sacrifice (1+r) units of C2. C1 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Consumer preferences Higher indifference curves represent higher levels of happiness. C1 C2 An indifference curve shows all combinations of C1 and C2 that make the consumer equally happy. IC2 IC1 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Consumer preferences The slope of an indifference curve at any point equals the MRS at that point. C1 C2 Marginal rate of substitution (MRS ): the amount of C2 the consumer would be willing to substitute for one unit of C1. IC1 1 MRS CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Optimization C1 C2 The optimal (C1,C2) is where the budget line just touches the highest indifference curve. At the optimal point, MRS = 1+r O All points along the budget line are affordable, including the two points where the orange indifference curve intersects the budget line. However, the consumer prefers (and can afford) point O to these points, because O is on a higher indifference curve. At the optimal point, the slope of the indifference curve (MRS) equals the slope of the budget line (1+r). CHAPTER 16 Consumption

How C responds to changes in Y An increase in Y1 or Y2 shifts the budget line outward. Results: Provided they are both normal goods, C1 and C2 both increase, …regardless of whether the income increase occurs in period 1 or period 2. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Keynes vs. Fisher Keynes: Current consumption depends only on current income. Fisher: Current consumption depends only on the present value of lifetime income. The timing of income is irrelevant because the consumer can borrow or lend between periods. If you covered Ricardian Equivalence in Chapter 15, you might wish to revisit it briefly at or around this point in the presentation. Draw the intertemporal budget constraint. Pick a point on it to represent (Y1–T1, Y2–T2). Now suppose the government gives each consumer a one-unit tax cut. Disposable income in period 1 rises by 1. Assume the government is not changing G1 or G2, and, just to keep things simple, assume that the government’s budget was balanced prior to the tax cut. Then, cutting taxes by one unit in period 1 requires that the government borrow one unit in period 1, which it must repay with interest in period 2. In order to retire this debt in period 2, the government must raise period-2 taxes by (1+r). Thus, disposable income rises by 1 in period 1 and falls by (1+r) in period 2. Notice that the present value of the fall in period-2 income is exactly equal to the rise in period 1 income. Thus, consumer is not any better off. What’s happened here is that the government has altered the timing of taxes (shifting some of the burden from the present to the future), but has not altered the present value of lifetime taxes. Therefore, the budget constraint does not shift out. Rather, the income point simply moves along the line toward the southeast (one unit to the right, and 1+r units downward). The combination (C1, C2) that was optimal before will still be feasible and optimal. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

How C responds to changes in r An increase in r pivots the budget line around the point (Y1,Y2 ). As depicted here, C1 falls and C2 rises. However, it could turn out differently… A A B Y1 Y2 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

How C responds to changes in r income effect: If consumer is a saver, the rise in r makes him better off, which tends to increase consumption in both periods. substitution effect: The rise in r increases the opportunity cost of current consumption, which tends to reduce C1 and increase C2. Both effects  C2. Whether C1 rises or falls depends on the relative size of the income & substitution effects. Note: Keynes conjectured that the interest rate matters for consumption only in theory. In Fisher’s theory, the interest rate doesn’t affect current consumption if the income and substitution effects are of equal magnitude. After you have shown and explained this slide, it would be useful to pause for a moment and ask your students (perhaps working in pairs) to do the analysis of an increase in the interest rate on the consumption choices of a borrower. In that case, the income effect tends to reduce both current and future consumption, because the interest rate hike makes the borrower worse off. The substitution effect still tends to increase future consumption while reducing current consumption. In the end, current consumption falls unambiguously; future consumption falls if the income effect dominates the substitution effect, and rises if the reverse occurs. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Constraints on borrowing In Fisher’s theory, the timing of income is irrelevant: Consumer can borrow and lend across periods. Example: If consumer learns that her future income will increase, she can spread the extra consumption over both periods by borrowing in the current period. However, if consumer faces borrowing constraints (aka “liquidity constraints”), then she may not be able to increase current consumption …and her consumption may behave as in the Keynesian theory even though she is rational & forward-looking. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Constraints on borrowing The budget line with no borrowing constraints Y2 Y1 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Constraints on borrowing The borrowing constraint takes the form: C1  Y1 The budget line with a borrowing constraint Y2 Similar to Figure 16-8 on p. 469. Y1 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Consumer optimization when the borrowing constraint is not binding The borrowing constraint is not binding if the consumer’s optimal C1 is less than Y1. (Figure 16-9, panel (a), on p.470) In this case, the consumer optimally was not going to borrow, so his inability to borrow has no impact on his choices. Y1 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Consumer optimization when the borrowing constraint is binding The optimal choice is at point D. But since the consumer cannot borrow, the best he can do is point E. E (Figure 16-9, panel (b), on p.470) In this case, the consumer would like to borrow to achieve his optimal consumption at point D. If he faces a borrowing constraint, though, then the best he can do is at point E. If you have a few minutes of classtime available, have your students do the following experiment: (This is especially useful if you have recently covered Chapter 15 on Government Debt) Suppose Y1 is increased by $1000 while Y2 is reduced by $1000(1+r), so that the present value of lifetime income is unchanged. Determine the impact on C1 - when consumer does not face a binding borrowing constraint - when consumer does face a binding borrowing constraint Then relate the results to the discussion of Ricardian Equivalence from Chapter 15. Note that the intertemporal redistribution of income in this exercise could be achieved by a debt-financed tax cut in period 1, followed by a tax increase in period 2 that is just sufficient to retire the debt. In the text, pages 470-71 contain a case study on the high Japanese saving rate that relates to the material on borrowing constraints just covered. D Y1 CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis due to Franco Modigliani (1950s) Fisher’s model says that consumption depends on lifetime income, and people try to achieve smooth consumption. The LCH says that income varies systematically over the phases of the consumer’s “life cycle,” and saving allows the consumer to achieve smooth consumption. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis The basic model: W = initial wealth Y = annual income until retirement (assumed constant) R = number of years until retirement T = lifetime in years Assumptions: zero real interest rate (for simplicity) consumption-smoothing is optimal The initial wealth could be zero, or could be a gift from parents to help the consumer get started on her own. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis Lifetime resources = W + RY To achieve smooth consumption, consumer divides her resources equally over time: C = (W + RY )/T , or C = aW + bY where a = (1/T ) is the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth b = (R/T ) is the marginal propensity to consume out of income CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Implications of the Life-Cycle Hypothesis The LCH can solve the consumption puzzle: The life-cycle consumption function implies APC = C/Y = a(W/Y ) + b Across households, income varies more than wealth, so high-income households should have a lower APC than low-income households. Over time, aggregate wealth and income grow together, causing APC to remain stable. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Implications of the Life-Cycle Hypothesis $ Wealth The LCH implies that saving varies systematically over a person’s lifetime. Income Saving Figure 16-12, p.474. Consumption Dissaving Retirement begins End of life CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Permanent Income Hypothesis due to Milton Friedman (1957) Y = Y P + Y T where Y = current income Y P = permanent income average income, which people expect to persist into the future Y T = transitory income temporary deviations from average income The middle of page 476 gives two hypothetical examples that help students understand the concepts of permanent and transitory income. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Permanent Income Hypothesis Consumers use saving & borrowing to smooth consumption in response to transitory changes in income. The PIH consumption function: C = a Y P where a is the fraction of permanent income that people consume per year. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Permanent Income Hypothesis The PIH can solve the consumption puzzle: The PIH implies APC = C / Y = a Y P/ Y If high-income households have higher transitory income than low-income households, APC is lower in high-income households. Over the long run, income variation is due mainly (if not solely) to variation in permanent income, which implies a stable APC. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

PIH vs. LCH Both: people try to smooth their consumption in the face of changing current income. LCH: current income changes systematically as people move through their life cycle. PIH: current income is subject to random, transitory fluctuations. Both can explain the consumption puzzle. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Random-Walk Hypothesis due to Robert Hall (1978) based on Fisher’s model & PIH, in which forward-looking consumers base consumption on expected future income Hall adds the assumption of rational expectations, that people use all available information to forecast future variables like income. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Random-Walk Hypothesis If PIH is correct and consumers have rational expectations, then consumption should follow a random walk: changes in consumption should be unpredictable. A change in income or wealth that was anticipated has already been factored into expected permanent income, so it will not change consumption. Only unanticipated changes in income or wealth that alter expected permanent income will change consumption. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Implication of the R-W Hypothesis If consumers obey the PIH and have rational expectations, then policy changes will affect consumption only if they are unanticipated. This result is important because many policies affect the economy by influencing consumption and saving. For example, a tax cut to stimulate aggregate demand only works if consumers respond to the tax cut by increasing spending. The R-W Hypothesis implies that consumption will respond only if consumers had not anticipated the tax cut. This result also implies that consumption will respond immediately to news about future changes in income. Students connect with the following example: Suppose a student is job-hunting in her senior year for a job that will begin after graduation. If the student secures a job with a higher salary than she had expected, she is likely to start spending more now in anticipation of the higher-than-expected permanent income. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Psychology of Instant Gratification Theories from Fisher to Hall assume that consumers are rational and act to maximize lifetime utility. Recent studies by David Laibson and others consider the psychology of consumers. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

The Psychology of Instant Gratification Consumers consider themselves to be imperfect decision-makers. In one survey, 76% said they were not saving enough for retirement. Laibson: The “pull of instant gratification” explains why people don’t save as much as a perfectly rational lifetime utility maximizer would save. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Two questions and time inconsistency 1. Would you prefer (A) a candy today, or (B) two candies tomorrow? 2. Would you prefer (A) a candy in 100 days, or (B) two candies in 101 days? In studies, most people answered (A) to 1 and (B) to 2. A person confronted with question 2 may choose (B). But in 100 days, when confronted with question 1, the pull of instant gratification may induce her to change her answer to (A). The text discusses time inconsistency in this context. Time inconsistency was introduced and defined in chapter 14. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Summing up Keynes: consumption depends primarily on current income. Recent work: consumption also depends on expected future income wealth interest rates Economists disagree over the relative importance of these factors, borrowing constraints, and psychological factors. CHAPTER 16 Consumption

Chapter Summary 1. Keynesian consumption theory Keynes’ conjectures MPC is between 0 and 1 APC falls as income rises current income is the main determinant of current consumption Empirical studies in household data & short time series: confirmation of Keynes’ conjectures in long-time series data: APC does not fall as income rises CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 42

Chapter Summary 2. Fisher’s theory of intertemporal choice Consumer chooses current & future consumption to maximize lifetime satisfaction of subject to an intertemporal budget constraint. Current consumption depends on lifetime income, not current income, provided consumer can borrow & save. CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 43

Chapter Summary 3. Modigliani’s life-cycle hypothesis Income varies systematically over a lifetime. Consumers use saving & borrowing to smooth consumption. Consumption depends on income & wealth. CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 44

Chapter Summary 4. Friedman’s permanent-income hypothesis Consumption depends mainly on permanent income. Consumers use saving & borrowing to smooth consumption in the face of transitory fluctuations in income. CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 45

Chapter Summary 5. Hall’s random-walk hypothesis Combines PIH with rational expectations. Main result: changes in consumption are unpredictable, occur only in response to unanticipated changes in expected permanent income. CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 46

Chapter Summary 6. Laibson and the pull of instant gratification Uses psychology to understand consumer behavior. The desire for instant gratification causes people to save less than they rationally know they should. CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 47