Chapter 38 Asymmetric Information

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Advertisements

Information Economics Consider the following variants on the game of poker: The Certainty Game – 5 cards dealt face up so that all players can see them.
Hal Varian Intermediate Microeconomics Chapter Thirty-Six
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection. What does it mean Adverse Selection (AS)? There is an AS problem when: before the signing of the contract,
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other. Consider a market.
Moral hazard and contracts
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
Contracts and Mechanism Design What Contracts Accomplish Moral Hazard Adverse Selection (if time: Signaling)
An Overview of the Financial System chapter 2. Function of Financial Markets Lenders-Savers (+) Households Firms Government Foreigners Financial Markets.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 20/1 Chapter 20 Asymmetric Information and Market Behaviour.
Slide 1  2002 South-Western Publishing An assumption of pure competition was complete knowledge of all market information. But knowledge can be unevenly.
Adverse Selection Asymmetric information is feature of many markets
L25 Asymmetric Information. Structure of the course 1) Consumers choice 2) Equilibrium, Producers (Pareto efficiency) 3) Market Failures - fixed cost:
Asymmetric Information ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
Asymmetric Information
Economics of Management Strategy BEE3027 Lecture 7.
Lectures Section Seven: Market Failure Introduction to Microeconomics (L11100)
Ch 14 Agency. Principal-Agent Relationship Principal owns an asset Agent works on principal’s behalf to preserve on enhance the value of the asset Problem.
Industrial Economics Fall INFORMATION Basic economic theories: Full (perfect) information In reality, information is limited. Consumers do not know.
Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,
Imperfect Information: Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons
Economics of Information Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard Chapter 17.
ECON 2001 Microeconomics II nd semester Elliott Fan Economics, NTU Lecture 1 Microeconomics, Elliott Fan Preface.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Asymmetric Information
Prof. Dr. Friedrich Schneider Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre Recht und Ökonomie (Law and Economics) LVA-Nr.:
L25 Asymmetric Information. Road map 1) Consumers choice 2) Equilibrium, Producers (Pareto efficiency) 3) Market Failures - fixed cost: monopoly and oligopoly.
The Moral Hazard Problem Stefan P. Schleicher University of Graz
Asymmetric Information
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Asymmetric Information The seller of the good knows more about its quality than the buyer.. Perhaps the market does not exist.
Contracting The incentives of the employer (principal) and employee (agent) are different. A contract is designed to implement an outcome both parties.
Lecture 5 Financial Incentives This lecture is paired with our previous one that discussed employee benefits. Here we focus on the reasons why monetary.
© 2010 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Chapter 7 Incentive Mechanism Principle-Agent Problem Production with Teams Competition.
CHAPTER 12 Risk and information ©McGraw-Hill Education, 2014.
20 UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION © 2012 Pearson Education.
Milgrom and Roberts (1992): Chapter 6 Economics, Organization & Management Chapter 6: Moral Hazard and Performance Incentives Examples of Moral Hazard:
Introductory Economics. Definition of Economics Unlimited wants and needs combined with limited resources results in scarcity. Therefore, Economics studies.
Chapter Thirty-Six Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets u In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded.
Simplifying Call Option – By Prof. Simply Simple TM
The Economics of Information
Managerial Economics Market Failure and Government Intervention
Preface.
Asymmetric Information
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 10
Asymmetric Information
George Akerlof The Market for Lemons.
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Asymmetric Information
Presenting “Options”.
Asymmetric Information
Information failure It exists when some, or all, of the participants in an economic exchange do not have perfect knowledge. Asymmetric information.
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
Introduction to Risk Management
Asymmetric Information
Markets with Asymmetric Information
Adverse selection Abhinash adhikari Astha gyawali Bijay chalise
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Chapter 19 Contract Theory
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
The Economics of Information
Lecture 9&10 Asymmetric Information.
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 38 Asymmetric Information Key Concept: adverse selection and moral hazard. Incentives, incentives, incentives!

Chapter 38 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other.

Consider a market with 100 people who want to sell their used cars and 100 people who want to buy a used car. Everyone knows that 50 cars are lemons and 50 are plums. The current owner knows the quality of his car, but the potential purchasers do not.

The owner of a lemon is happy to part with his car for 1000 and that of a plum for 2000. The buyers are willing to pay 1200 for a lemon and 2400 for a lemon. If information is symmetric, then the lemon will sell at some price between 1000 and 1200 while the plum between 2000 and 2400.

What if the information is not symmetric? Since there are 50 lemons and 50 plums, thus buyers are willing to pay up to 0.5x1200+ 0.5x2400=1800.

Yet at 1800, only the owners of lemons are willing to sell their cars. However, in equilibrium, buyers cannot have wrong expectation, so they expect to see only lemons in the market. When this happens, they are willing to pay only 1200. Thus only lemons get sold while none of the plums do. This differs from the case when information is symmetric.

This is an example of adverse selection This is an example of adverse selection. There are some other examples like insurance, health insurance, (marriage market?) so market equilibrium is typically not efficient.

There are ways evolved to alleviate this inefficiency There are ways evolved to alleviate this inefficiency. For instance, compulsory purchase plan, employee insurance as fringe benefits. (Talk a bit about reputation and standardization.)

Some practices also emerge. For instance, the owner of a plum can offer a warranty, a promise to pay the purchaser some agreed upon amount if the car turned out to break down. Or he can allow the purchaser to take his car to a technician to examine his car. Now these are called signaling.

Suppose we have two types of workers, able and unable. Able workers have MPL of a2 while unable a1 and a2>a1.

The fraction of able workers is b. If firms can distinguish two types of workers, then they will offer wage a2 to able and to a1 unable. However, if they cannot, they can only offer ba2+(1-b)a1. Now if under this wage, both types will work, then there is no problem of efficiency loss.

Suppose now workers can acquire education to signal his type. Now workers acquire education first and then firms decide how much to pay after observing the choice of education by workers. Assume the education does not affect the productivity at all to simplify.

Let e2 be the education acquired by able and e1 by unable. Let c2e2 be the cost for able and c1e1 for unable. Suppose further that c2<c1.

Let e* satisfy (a2-a1)/c1 < e*< (a2-a1)/c2. Then we have an equilibrium where able workers get education e* and unable 0. Firms pay a2 when they see e*and pay a1 when they see 0.

Let e* satisfy (a2-a1)/c1 < e*< (a2-a1)/c2. Does anyone have an incentive to deviate? Would unable mimic able? If he did, then the gain is a2-a1 while the cost is c1 e*. The first inequality guarantees that this is not profitable.

Let e* satisfy (a2-a1)/c1 < e*< (a2-a1)/c2. What about able workers? Would he deviate to acquire education of 0? If he did, the loss is a2-a1 while the gain is c2e*. The second inequality guarantees that loss is bigger than gain and so it is not profitable to do so. Hence it is indeed an equilibrium.

This is called a separating equilibrium where two types choose different signals to separate. In this setup it is a pure waste to signal.

However, when the competitive equilibrium is not efficient, though signaling has cost, it might have some benefit and may improve efficiency.

Another interesting problem arising in the insurance market is known as the moral hazard. This relates to the phenomenon that after contracting (insured), one transacting party may have the incentive to take less care. (talk about theft insurance)

The tradeoffs involved are: too little insurance means people bear too much risk too much insurance means people will take inadequate care So the whole point is on balancing these two.

Hence an insurance policy often includes a deductible, the amount that the insured party has to pay in any claim. (compared this to premium). This is designed to make sure that consumers will take some care.

Now the whole problem becomes how can I get someone do something for me? This naturally leads us to the incentives problems.

Suppose we have a worker (agent) who if exerting effort x can produce output y=f(x). Efforts are not observable but outputs are. Let the cost of x be c(x) and the worker has some outside opportunity which gives him the utility of u. Then the whole problem boils down to choosing the payment s(y)=s(f(x)) to the worker to max the profit of the Principal.

Now to make the worker participate, we have the participation constraint (individual rationality IR). That is, s(f(x))-c(x)u. So if we can observe x, the principal simply does maxx f(x)-s(f(x)) subject to s(f(x))-c(x)u. This can be solved by maxx f(x)-c(x)-u (**). So FOC is MP(x*)=MC(x*).

But if x is not observable, then we need to worry about whether agents will indeed choose x*.

This brings us to another constraint, called the incentive compatibility (IC) constraint. It means that s(f(x*))-c(x*) s(f(x))-c(x) for all x.

There is a way to do this, that is, to sell the firm to the agents. So s(f(x))=f(x)-R. If the worker max s(f(x))-c(x)=f(x)-c(x)-R, then it looks just like (**). So x* will be chosen if IR is OK. To make IR OK, we just choose R so that f(x*)-c(x*)-R=u.

In short, the sell-out contract is to make the agents the residual claimant so that he will take the proper care. However, this is good because we assume risk neutrality of agents. If agents are risk averse, then this incentive scheme may entail too much risk on agents and for this reason, we do not see that every principal uses this kind of scheme to motivate his agents.

A final note on the voting right of a corporation A final note on the voting right of a corporation. It is often the case that shareholders have the right to vote on various issues while bond holders do not.

Why is that? The answer may lie in the incentives. If a corporation produces X dollars and total claim is B dollars of bond holders. Then the amount that goes to shareholders is X-B. So this makes sure the shareholders have the right incentives to max X.

Chapter 38 Asymmetric Information Key Concept: adverse selection and moral hazard. Incentives, incentives, incentives!