Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Objectives At this point, we know
Advertisements

28 Money, Interest, and Inflation
25 MONEY, THE PRICE LEVEL, AND INFLATION © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
Outline Investment and the Interest Rate
Instructor: MELTEM INCE
FIN 40500: International Finance Nominal Rigidities and Exchange Rate Volatility.
The study of the behavior and decision making of the entire economy Examines major trends for the economy as a whole.
22 Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand
Exchange rates Currencies are bought and sold in the foreign exchange market. The price at which one currency exchanges for another in the foreign exchange.
Currency Analysis with Fundamentals. Fundamental Analysis involves the use of data to assess the strength/weakness of a currency Economic Data GDP Employment.
Economics 282 University of Alberta
Macroeconomic Policy and Floating Exchange Rates
Chapter 14: Monetary Policy  Objectives of U.S. monetary policy and the framework for setting and achieving them  Federal Reserve interest rate policy.
 Circular Flow of Income is a simplified model of the economy that shows the flow of money through the economy.
Chapter 15: Monetary Policy
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER FOUR Money.
Money What is money? Anything people will accept in place of the goods and services they seek to obtain. Money is a stock of assets that can be readily.
© 2011 Pearson Education Money, Interest, and Inflation 4 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain what determines.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain what determines the demand for money and.
AS - AD and the Business Cycle CHAPTER 13 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Provide.
Money, Interest, and Inflation CHAPTER 12 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain.
Exchange Rates. An exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of another. –It indicates how many units of one currency can be bought with a single.
124 Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand. 125  What is the purpose of the aggregate supply-aggregate demand model?  What determines aggregate supply.
© 2011 Pearson Education Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand 13 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Define and.
Review of the previous lecture Money the stock of assets used for transactions serves as a medium of exchange, store of value, and unit of account. Commodity.
Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain what determines aggregate supply  Explain what determines aggregate demand  Explain.
Economics Unit 4: Macroeconomics Vocabulary Review.
CHAPTER 14 (Part 2) Money, Interest Rates, and the Exchange Rate.
7 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain what determines the demand for money and.
National Income & Business Cycles 0 Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples 4: Money and Inflation.
1 FINA 353 Principles of Macroeconomics Lecture 9 Topic: Fiscal Policy FINA 353 Principles of Macroeconomics Lecture 9 Topic: Fiscal Policy Dr. Mazharul.
The Government Budget, Foreign Borrowing, and the Twin Deficits
Interest Rates, Saving and Investment Fiscal Policy
Budget Deficits and the National Debt
Chapter 9.
The Federal Reserve System
Chapter 7 Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy
Chapter 9 The Balance of Payments and Exchange Rates
How the Economy Reaches Equilibrium in the Short Run
Basic Theories of the Balance of Payments
The Real Economy WHERE WE ARE AND WHERE WE’RE HEADING
Economics Flashcards # Unit 3 Macroeconomics
Chapter 10 Interest Rates & Monetary Policy
A. Economic Growth B. Monetary Policy in the Long Run
Monetary Policy.
Chapter 20 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Chapter 19 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Basic Theories of the Balance of Payments
Sponge Quiz #1: In Year 1, the cost of a market basket of goods was $720. In Year 2, the cost of the same basket was $780. What was the consumer price.
Macro Free Responses Since 1995
Budget Balance and Government Debt
Chapter 9.
Week 11 Monetary and fiscal policy
Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples 4: Money and Inflation
Review for Exam
Inflation
14 MONETARY POLICY Part 1.
Money, Interest, and Inflation
INTEREST RATES, MONEY AND PRICES IN THE LONG RUN
Introduction Long run models are useful when all prices of inputs and outputs have time to adjust. In the short run, some prices of inputs and outputs.
27 The Monetary System For use with Mankiw and Taylor, Economics 4th edition © Cengage EMEA 2017.
Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium in the Money Market
© 2016 Pearson Education Ltd. All rights reserved.19-1© 2016 Pearson Education Ltd. All rights reserved.19-1 Chapter 1 Why Study Money, Banking, and Financial.
BUSINESS CYCLES (continued)
Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Macroeconomics Review
13_14:Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand
Presentation transcript:

Monetary and Fiscal Policy SIS 628 April 3, 2019 Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Fiscal policy

Role of Government Government’s decisions: Decide how much to spend: G Decide how to finance the spending

Deciding how much to spend Is it something that the private sector does not already provide? (e.g. defense) Does it add to the productivity of the economy? (e.g. infrastructure) Does it give happiness? (e.g. public parks) Does it meet distributional goals? (e.g. transfers; unemployment benefits during recessions)

Deciding how to finance the spending Three ways to finance G Taxation Borrowing Inflation Initially, we assume government does not choose this option.

Deciding whether to tax or borrow One option: “balanced budget rule” G = T Which is, G = τY (because tax revenue = tax rate times tax base) Why balanced budget rule may not be a good idea Suppose G goes up temporarily (e.g. due to war); under balanced budget rule, would have to raise τ Suppose economy goes into recession (Y is less than potential), and so τY drops; under balanced budget rule, options would be either to cut G or raise τ A better rule Finance temporary increases in G or temporary shortfalls in T by borrowing Finance permanent increases in G by a permanent increase in T (raise τ; unless increased G is expected to make economy more productive and thus raise Y)

Fiscal balances Suppose government of a new country decides it needs to spend more than in can collect in taxes in its first year So G1 > T1 The government borrows the rest (“issues bonds”) So government runs a fiscal deficit: G1 - T1 = B1 Second year: (G2 + rB1) - T2 = B2 – B1 If G2 + rB1 = T2 (govt. has a balanced budget in year 2), then B2 = B1 (stock of outstanding debt remains constant) If G2 + rB1 < T2 (govt. has a fiscal surplus in year 2), then B2 < B1 (government pays off some of the outstanding debt) If G2 + rB1 > T2 (govt. has a fiscal deficit in year 2), then B2 > B1 (government adds to the outstanding debt)

Evolution of the debt (G2 + rB1) - T2 = B2 – B1 We can rewrite as B2 = B1 + (G2 + rB1 - T2) Which is the same as: B2 = (1 + r) B1 + (G2 - T2) In general, for year t Bt = (1 + r) Bt-1 + (Gt - Tt) Bt-1 is government debt at the end of year, t – 1 or, equivalently, at the beginning of year t ; r is the real interest rate, which we shall assume to be constant here. Thus rBt-1 equals the real interest payments on the government debt in year t. Gt is government spending during year t. Tt is taxes minus transfers during year t.

Evolution of the debt-to-GDP ratio

Evolution of the debt-to-GDP ratio The change in the debt-to-GDP ratio over time is equal to the sum of two terms. The first term is the difference between the real interest rate and the growth rate times the initial debt ratio. The second term is the ratio of the primary balance to GDP.

Evolution of the debt-to-GDP ratio This equation implies that the increase in the ratio of debt to GDP will be larger: the higher the real interest rate, the lower the growth rate of output, the higher the initial debt ratio, the higher the ratio of the primary deficit to GDP.

U.S. Debt-to-GDP ratio Source: Finance and Development, March 2009; Paying the Piper, Carlo Cottarelli.

U.K. Debt-to-GDP Ratio Source: Finance and Development, March 2009; Paying the Piper, Carlo Cottarelli.

Japan’s Debt-to-GDP Ratio Source: Finance and Development, March 2009; Paying the Piper, Carlo Cottarelli.

Central Bank actions: monetary policy in the short-run

Many different interest rates For this course: Policy interest rate (can be “set” by central bank) In the U.S., this rate is the fed funds rate Short-term interest rate Long-term interest rate Each of these interest rates can be decomposed into a part that is “real” and a part due to “expected inflation” An assumption we make is that by changing the policy interest rate the central bank can influence other interest rates The relationship among short-term and long-term interest rates is called the ‘yield curve’ or the ‘term structure of interest rates’

How Should Central Banks Set the Policy Rate? The Taylor Rule The first ‘2’ in the equation is the neutral (long-run) real interest rate (assumed to be 2 percent) The second ‘2’ in the equation is the inflation target (assumed to be 2 percent) The two ‘0.5’ numbers are values that held for the U.S. in the 1980s and 1990s. They can be different over other periods, and can differ by country.

Taylor Rule (continued) If p = 2 and output is at potential, then monetary policy targets the real policy rate at 2% (and therefore the nominal policy rate is 4%). For each percentage point increase in p, monetary policy should be ‘tightened’ by raising the real policy rate by 0.5 percentage points. For each percentage point that GDP falls below potential, monetary policy should be ‘eased’ by reducing the real policy rate by 0.5 percentage points.

Central bank actions: from the short run to the long run

When the Fed Wants to “Loosen” Fed buys T-bills from banks Fed pays for the T-bills by writing a cheque: injecting liquidity Banks now have more cash than they want to hold Banks that want to borrow from other banks can do so at a lower fed funds rate money is cheap Fed injects liquidity until fed funds rate has fallen to the Fed’s set “target”

Transition from Short Run to Long Run (1) Interest rates and money supply Raising policy interest rates is similar to curbing growth of money supply. Lowering policy interest rates is similar to raising the growth rate of the money supply. In the short run, the central bank lowers policy interest rates (i.e. raises the growth rate of the money supply) to stimulate the economy (bring output back to trend; close the output gap) But it lowering policy interest rates stimulates the economy, shouldn’t the central bank always keep interest rates low?

Transition from Short Run to Long Run (2) ‘Good’ scenario: Central bank has lowered rates because the economy is in a slump (output gap is large). In this case, inflation may not go up much; plus, some stimulus can be justified even if inflation does go up a bit The central bank has credibility, that is, people expect it to keep its (medium- to long-run) inflation target. This means that people expect that interest rates will be raised back to neutral once the output gap has closed. Hence, inflation expectations remain anchored.

Transition from Short Run to Long Run (3) ‘Bad’ scenario(s): Wrong reasons: Central bank has lowered rates even though the economy is not in a slump (output gap is zero). Or, the central bank may have made a mistake about the size of the output gap. In these cases, inflation may go up (and the stimulus cannot be justified on the grounds that it is helping the economy recover from a slump) Right reasons, poor credibility: Central bank may have lowered reasons for the right reasons (economy is indeed in a slump) but it has poor credibility. That is, people expect it will not keep to (or have difficulty keeping to) its medium- to long-run inflation target. This means that people expect that interest rates will not be raised back to neutral once the output gap has closed. Hence, inflation expectations can get unanchored. Wrong reasons, poor credibility: Worse case scenario – inflation may kick up because central bank has intervened at the wrong time; and problem is compounded as inflation expectations get unanchored.

U.S. Inflation & its Trend

Central bank actions: the long run

The Quantity Theory of Money Key  inflation rate M/M growth rate of money supply Y/Y growth rate of output (real GDP) Normal economic growth requires a certain amount of money supply growth to facilitate growth in transactions. Money growth in excess of this amount leads to inflation. Inflation is “too much money chasing too few goods” [Note: we’re simplifying by assuming that the ‘velocity of money’ is constant.] As we have learnt, in the long-run, Y/Y (growth rate of real GDP) depends on growth in inputs and on technological progress. Hence, the Quantity Theory of Money predicts a long-run one-for-one relation between changes in the money growth rate and changes in the inflation rate. Note: During hyperinflations, the quantity theory of money can hold even in the short run

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply: Effects of a Permanent Monetary Expansion A monetary expansion leads to an increase in output in the short run but has no effect on output in the medium run. The difference between Y and Yn sets in motion the adjustment of price expectations. In the medium run, the AS curve shifts to AS’’ and the economy returns to equilibrium at Yn. The increase in prices is proportional to the increase in the nominal money stock.

U.S. data on inflation and money growth, decade averages

International Data on Inflation & Money Growth

Understanding Hyperinflations Three ways to finance G Taxation Borrowing Inflation

Hyperinflation What is it? What causes it? Does that work?   50% per month What causes it? Excessive money supply growth. Does that work? Only for a short time. Because money ceases to function as a store of value, and may not serve its other functions (unit of account, medium of exchange), people start conducting transactions with barter or a stable foreign currency. Because people are no longer willing to subject themselves to the “inflation tax,” it ceases to be a source of revenue for the government. How is it stopped? Proximate step: stop printing money. At a more fundamental level: it requires a credible announcement of government fiscal reform (i.e. cuts in government spending, increases in tax revenue, new sources of borrowing or some combination of all three) and follow-through. What is it? Informal definition:   50% per month What causes it? Excessive money supply growth. Why do governments do it? When a government cannot finance its expenditures by raising taxes or selling bonds (i.e. borrowing), it sometimes tries to meet expenditures by printing money. Does that work? Only for a short time. Because money ceases to function as a store of value, and may not serve its other functions (unit of account, medium of exchange), people start conducting transactions with barter or a stable foreign currency. Because people are no longer willing to subject themselves to the “inflation tax” it ceases to be a source of revenue for the government. How is hyperinflation stopped? In theory, the solution to hyperinflation is simple: stop printing money. In practice, it requires a credible announcement of government fiscal reform (i.e. cuts in government spending, increases in tax revenue, new sources of borrowing or some combination of all three) and follow-through on the announced plans.

‘Classic’ hyperinflations Seven Hyperinflations of the 1920s and 1940s Country Beginning End PT/P0 Average Monthly Inflation Rate (%) Average Monthly Money Growth (%) Austria Oct. 1921 Aug. 1922 70 47 31 Germany Nov. 1923 1.0 x 1010 322 314 Greece Nov. 1943 Nov. 1944 4.7 x 106 365 220 Hungary 1 Mar. 1923 Feb. 1924 44 46 33 Hungary 2 Aug. 1945 Jul. 1946 3.8 x 1027 19,800 12,200 Poland Jan. 1923 Jan. 1924 699 82 72 Russia Dec. 1921 1.2 x 105 57 49 PT/P0 is the price level in the last month of hyperinflation divided by the price level in the first month.

Episodes of Hyperinflation in the 1980s

Monetary policy in open economies: The Impossible trinity

Interest Rate Parity If domestic and foreign assets are considered perfect substitutes, then we expect interest parity to hold on average: rt –rwt = (Xet+1 – Xt)/Xt That is, the interest rate differential between the domestic (Rt ) and foreign interest rate (rwt ) should be zero, unless the market expects changes in the exchange rate. In practice, interest rate differentials fail to predict large swings in actual exchange rates and even fail to predict which direction actual exchange rates change. Why? It could be because domestic and foreign assets are imperfect substitutes. Changes in risk premiums (t ) may drive deviations from interest rate parity rt –rwt = (Xet+1 – Xt)/Xt + t

Example of Interest Rate Parity We should expect that interest rates on offshore currency deposits and those on domestic currency deposits within a country should be the same if the two types of deposits are treated as perfect substitutes, assets can flow freely across borders and international capital markets are able to quickly and easily transmit information about any differences in rates.

Example of interest rate parity: Comparing Onshore and Offshore Interest Rates for the Dollar Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, monthly data.

Lack of interest rate parity (and illustration of risk premium) Interest Differentials, 1998 - 2005 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 Basis points EMBI vs. US spread Brazil vs. US Spread

Interest Rate Parity (IRP) and Monetary Policy Choices IRP imposes limits on central bank’s monetary independence. Why? Assume capital can flow in unlimited amounts between domestic and foreign country. Suppose now the domestic central bank were to try to keep exchange rates steady. At the same time, suppose also that it tries to adjust interest rates (say upwards) in order to attain a separate inflation target. Under fully-integrated capital markets, higher domestic interest rates  large capital inflow into the domestic economy. Capital flows in  the value of the domestic currency will have to go up versus the foreign currency—i.e., appreciation of the domestic currency. So the exchange rate cannot be held steady if the interest rate objective takes primacy.

IRP and Monetary Policy Choices (continued) Suppose now the central bank wants to keep its currency from appreciating. To prevent appreciation it must either inject more domestic currency into the market directly, or buy up foreign currency with domestic currency. Either way, the domestic currency it issues or pays out is new money  expansion in domestic liquidity Expansion in domestic liquidity  interest rate falls So the interest rate target cannot be achieved if the fixed exchange rate takes primacy.

Conclusion: One of the three must go. Either A central bank must give up trying to maintain stability in exchange rates and allow the currency to be determined by the market forces that work through arbitrage, or A central bank must give up its independence in setting domestic interest rates; that is, it must align its domestic objectives with the objective of keeping exchange rates stable, or Something has to be done to limit capital flows and break the arbitrage that ties together exchange rates and interest rates.

Breaking the Arbitrage that Ties Interest Rates and Exchange Rates: The ability to conduct full arbitrage between local and global capital markets depends on the degree to which capital is allowed to flow between the two sets of markets—the degree of capital market integration or linkage between domestic and global markets. The degree of capital market integration often depends on the level of development and sophistication of local financial markets and institutions. But it can also be a policy choice

Degree of Capital Market Integration: “Full” or complete capital market integration: Few or no legal restrictions or natural market barriers on capital flows between domestic and global capital markets, particularly on currency-related transactions. No limit on volume of capital flows between markets. Convertibility of currency on capital account (not just current account). Feasible to conduct unlimited arbitrage whenever it makes sense to.

Degree of Capital Market Integration: Less than complete capital market integration: Significant capital or exchange controls limit the volume of capital that can flow between domestic and global markets. Capital markets are segmented and arbitrage between from one market to another is expensive or impossible.

“Impossible Trinity” “Impossible Trinity” or Policy Trilemma–The following three things are incompatible: Fully integrated capital markets (which would require interest rate parity) Independent or autonomous monetary policy (i.e., CB can target policy interest rates, as in the Taylor’s Rule we discussed ) Fixed (“stable”) exchange rates (x)

Monetary Policy in ‘Small’ Open Economies

Long-run unemployment: natural Rate or “NAIRU”

Unemployment Two components of unemployment rate Cyclical unemployment is related to the business cycle Natural rate of unemployment – the unemployment that would prevail even in the absence of business cycles (even at “full-employment’) In a recession, the actual unemployment rate rises above the natural rate; cyclical unemployment is high In a boom, the actual unemployment rate falls below the natural rate; cyclical unemployment is low.

Actual and natural rates of unemployment in the U.S., 1960-2007 Unemployment rate 10 8 Percent of labor force Natural rate of unemployment 6 4 Figure 6-1, p.160. The actual unemployment rate fluctuates considerably over the short run. These fluctuations will be the focus of chapters 9-13 later in the book. For this chapter, though, our goal is to understand the red line: the so-called “natural rate of unemployment,” or the long-run trend in the unemployment rate. Source: BLS Obtained from http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/ Unemployment data are based on seasonally-adjusted, monthly unemployment rates for the civilian non-institutional population of the U.S. The actual u-rate for each quarter is an average of the three monthly unemployment rates in that quarter. The natural u-rate in a given quarter is estimated by averaging all unemployment rates from 10 years earlier to 10 years later; future unemployment rates are set at 5.5%. 2 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Model of the natural rate Notation: L = # of workers in labor force E = # of employed workers U = # of unemployed U/L = unemployment rate Section 6-1

Assumptions: 1. L is fixed. 2. During any given month, s = fraction of employed workers that become separated from their jobs s is called the rate of job separations f = fraction of unemployed workers that find jobs f is called the rate of job finding s and f are exogenous

The transitions between employment and unemployment f U s E Employed Unemployed

The steady state condition Definition: the labor market is in steady state, or long-run equilibrium, if the unemployment rate is constant. The steady-state condition is: s E = f U # of unemployed people who find jobs # of employed people who lose or leave their jobs

Example: Each month, Find the natural rate of unemployment: 1% of employed workers lose their jobs (s = 0.01) 19% of unemployed workers find jobs (f = 0.19) Find the natural rate of unemployment:

Tweaking the model to “account” for cyclical unemployment During recessions, unemployment goes up above the natural rate because: s (job separation rate) tends to go up above its “natural” level f (job finding rate) tends to go down below its “natural” level During booms, unemployment falls below the natural rate because: s tends to go down below its “natural” level f tends to go up above its “natural” level