Andreoni: Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion Economics 328 Spring 2005.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Nagel: Unraveling in Guessing Games: An Experimental Study Economics 328 Spring 2005.
Advertisements

Public Goods and Impure Altruism Presentation by Peter McHenry September 23, 2004.
Lecture 3 Public Goods and Government intervention
Social Choice Session 9 Carmen Pasca and John Hey.
Funding Public goods with Lotteries: Experimental Evidence John Morgan; Martin Sefton Heriberto Gonzalez October, 2007.
Public Goods & Reputation: Humans Recall Eusocial Insects: Altruism Inclusive Fitness Kin Selection Monogamous Queens Multiply-Mated Queens Lower r Kinship,
Ultimatum Game Two players bargain (anonymously) to divide a fixed amount between them. P1 (proposer) offers a division of the “pie” P2 (responder) decides.
Altruistic Punishment in Humans Ernst Fehr & Simon Gächter Clemente Jones & Nguyen Lam Psychology /08/2014.
Brandts and Solà: Reference Points and Negative Reciprocity in Simple Sequential Games Economics 328 Spring 2005.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Chapter 6 Game Theory © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Chapter 6 Game Theory © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Fehr and Falk Wage Rigidity in a Competitive Incomplete Contract Market Economics 328 Spring 2005.
Cognitive Biases 2 Incomplete and Unrepresentative Data.
Fundamentals of Political Science Dr. Sujian Guo Professor of Political Science San Francisco State Unversity
Chapter 6 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Game Theory.
Public goods provision and endogenous coalitions (experimental approach)
How the Emotions Enforce the Cooperative Behavior in Social Dilemma Games Speaker :林 家 仰.
Objectives © Pearson Education, 2005 Oligopoly LUBS1940: Topic 7.
Outline  In-Class Experiment on the Provision of Public Good  Test of Free-Rider Hypothesis I: Marwell and Ames (1979)  Test of Free-Rider Hypothesis.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Chapter 1 Economic Models © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
1 Information Markets & Decision Makers Yiling Chen Anthony Kwasnica Tracy Mullen Penn State University This research was supported by the Defense Advanced.
Punishing Unacceptable Behavior Janhavi Nilekani and Sarah Ong.
Chapter 2 – Tools of Positive Analysis
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 17 New Classical Macro Confronts New Keynesian Macro.
Grether and Plott: Economic Theory of Choice and the Preference Reversal Phenomenon Economics 328 Spring 2004.
CIFREM Doctoral Program in Economics and Management University of Trento, Italy Thesis Proposal Development (July 2006) Francesca Bortolami
© 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
1 University of Auckland Winter Week Lectures Third Lecture 4 July 2007 Associate Professor Ananish Chaudhuri Department of Economics University of Auckland.
Game Theory, Strategic Decision Making, and Behavioral Economics 11 Game Theory, Strategic Decision Making, and Behavioral Economics All men can see the.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 21 Monetary Policy Strategy.
Nash equilibrium Nash equilibrium is defined in terms of strategies, not payoffs Every player is best responding simultaneously (everyone optimizes) This.
1 Lecture 8 The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants of Consumption Planned Investment (I) The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
Income and Spending Chapter #10 (DFS)
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. GAME THEORY, STRATEGIC DECISION MAKING, AND BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS.
Experiments on Risk Taking and Evaluation Periods Misread as Evidence of Myopic Loss Aversion Ganna Pogrebna June 30, 2007 Experiments on Risk Taking and.
Perfect competition, with an infinite number of firms, and monopoly, with a single firm, are polar opposites. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly.
Motivation This experiment was a public good experiment to see if groups contribute differently than individuals.  intermediate social structure This.
Data Analysis Econ 176, Fall Populations When we run an experiment, we are always measuring an outcome, x. We say that an outcome belongs to some.
What games do economists play? To see more of our products visit our website at Tom Allen, Head of Economics, Eton College.
1 University of Auckland Winter Week Lectures Second Lecture 3 July 2007 Associate Professor Ananish Chaudhuri Department of Economics University of Auckland.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Last 2 weeks of teaching Today: lecture 33 on Public Goods. Tomorrow: lecture 34 on Asymmetric Information. Next Monday: last.
Lecture 5 Introduction to Game theory. What is game theory? Game theory studies situations where players have strategic interactions; the payoff that.
Exchange Rates. An exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of another. –It indicates how many units of one currency can be bought with a single.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Game Theory: Basics MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell March 2004.
Experimental Design Econ 176, Fall Some Terminology Session: A single meeting at which observations are made on a group of subjects. Experiment:
Testing theories of fairness— Intentions matter Armin Falk, Ernst Fehr, Urs Fischbacher February 26, 2015.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Lecture by: Jacinto Fabiosa Fall 2005 Consumer Choice.
Chapter 9: Introduction to the t statistic. The t Statistic The t statistic allows researchers to use sample data to test hypotheses about an unknown.
The inference and accuracy We learned how to estimate the probability that the percentage of some subjects in the sample would be in a given interval by.
Yu-Hsuan Lin Catholic University of Korea, Korea University of York, U.K. 5 th Congress of EAAERE, Taipei, 06 th – 07 th August 2015.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Social Networks and Trust: not the Experimental Evidence you may Expect Daniela Di Cagno Emanuela Sciubba Luiss Guido Carli, Rome Birkbeck College, London.
Indirect Reciprocity in the Selective Play Environment Nobuyuki Takahashi and Rie Mashima Department of Behavioral Science Hokkaido University 08/07/2003.
OVERCOMING COORDINATION FAILURE THROUGH NEIGHBORHOOD CHOICE ~AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY~ Maastricht University Arno Riedl Ingrid M.T. Rohde Martin Strobel.
Game theory Chapter 28 and 29
Behavioral economics Chapter 30
Economic Science Association World Meetings 2010
Chapter 9 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption-Savings Decision and Credit Markets Macroeconomics 6th Edition Stephen D. Williamson Copyright © 2018, 2015,
Game theory Chapter 28 and 29
Lecture 9 Static Games and the Cournot Model
Utility Maximization Ch7
Unit 4 SOCIAL INTERACTIONS.
The Role of Incentives and Communication in Strategic Alliances: An Experimental Investigation Strategic Management Journal, (2010) Rajshree Agarwal,
Behavioral economics Chapter 30
Rie Mashima & Nobuyuki Takahashi (Hokkaido University)
Presentation transcript:

Andreoni: Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion Economics 328 Spring 2005

What are Public Goods? What Can Experiments Tell Us About Them? Pure public goods Non-excludable Non-rival For public goods, the marginal social benefit always exceeds the marginal private benefit. Hence, theory predicts under-provision. What do experiments bring to the study of public goods? Tight control over the environment How do real individuals’ decision vary from theory (and how can the theory then be modified)? Market design

Voluntary Contribution Mechanism: Theory For laboratory experiments, voluntary contribution mechanisms (VCM) are the most frequently studied version of a public goods problem. N players. Initial endowment = Ei. Players simultaneously decide how much to contribute to a public pool. Let xi be the amount contributed. Payoffs are given by the following formula. Ri = Ei – xi + V The variable V is called the marginal per capita return (MPCR).

Voluntary Contribution Mechanism: Theory To simplify, assume the return on contributions is linear: Ri = Ei – xi + V∙ If we have 1/N < V < 1, we have a public goods problem. Individually, each player is best off giving nothing to the public good, but collectively the players are best off donating their entire endowments.

Voluntary Contribution Mechanisms: Results Even though the theory predicts no contributions, experimenters general observe substantial contribution levels. Consider the data shown to the right, taken from Isaac and Walker (1988). Group size either equals 4 or 10. H denotes MPCR = .75 and L denotes MPCR = .3. In all cases, there are large amounts contributed to the public good, although the amount does predictably decline with experience. What forces might be driving these high contribution rates?

Experience Effects Generally, although not always, experimenters find that contribution rates decrease with experience. There are two likely explanations . . . Learning. Inexperienced subjects may erroneously contribute to the public good, not realizing that their payoff is maximized by not contributing. As they realize their mistake, they contribute less and contribution rates fall. Strategic play Suppose it is considered likely that some individuals are “reciprocal altruists.” In English, I am willing to contribute to the public good as long as others contribute. This is not the behavior of a “rational” individual. It then becomes profitable for a rational individual to pretend to be a reciprocal altruist. By developing a reputation for being this type, the player can induce contributions by other rational players. Because it is costly to maintain a reputation and because the value of maintaining a reputation shrinks as the end of an experiment approaches, we would expect contribution rates to fall over time as individuals stop maintaining their reputations.

Experience Effects To separate these two hypotheses, Andreoni (1988) ran a “partners and strangers” experiment. In the partners treatment, subjects play with the same five person group for all ten rounds of the experiment. In the strangers treatment, there is random rematching of groups in every round. This should reduce the benefits of building a reputation. In fact, contributions decline in both treatments and average contributions are actually somewhat higher in the strangers treatment. These results suggest that learning is driving the decline in contribution rates and that high contribution rates cannot solely be attributed to strategic concerns.

MPCR Marginal per capita Return (MPCR): Suppose that subjects’ predilection for contributing to public goods could be explained by a standard model of consumer choice. It should then be true that the marginal rate of substitution between private and public goods equals the ratio of prices for these goods. Since an increase in V, the MPCR of public goods, is equivalent to decreasing the price of public goods, an increase in V should unequivocally lead to more public goods being provided. With very few exceptions, this is what experimenters observe. (Of course, a cynic might also note that increasing V reduces the cost of erroneously donating to the public good.)

Group Size Group Size: One can imagine an increase in group size cutting either way. On the one hand, every dollar contributed to the public good now generates greater group benefits (holding MPCR fixed). On the other hand, sustaining cooperation is usually more difficult in large groups –monitoring is more difficult and punishing defectors involves a difficult coordination problem. There has been relatively little systematic examination of the effect of group size on contributions, largely due to the difficulties and expense of such experiments. There are good papers on this topic by Isaac and Walker (1988) and by Isaac, Walker, and Williams (1991). Their results suggest that increased group size will lead to higher contributions, although this effect interacts with the MPCR.

Communication Communication: The theory does not predict that allowing pre-play communication should have any effect on contributions. However, early work by psychologists (Dawes, McTavish, and Shaklee, 1977) showed that cooperation in N-person games is increased by allowing pre-play communication. A large number of studies have found similar effects in public goods games (Dawes, McTavish, and Shaklee, 1977; Isaak, McCue, and Plott, 1985; Isaak and Walker, 1988 & 1991). Moreover, with communication contribution rates increase over time. Recent work by psychologists (Dawes, Orbell, and van de Kragt, 1987, 1988, and 1990) indicates that communication works either by allowing for multilateral promises (coordination from a game theorist’s point of view) or by generating group identity.

Andreoni (1995): Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion Research Question: The preceding literature had established that subjects would contribute to public goods in VCM games. Two leading hypotheses had emerged for why. One possibility is other-regarding preferences – reasons such as kindness, altruism, or warm-glow. This is similar to the ideas we have seen proposed for ultimatum games. Rather than only caring about themselves, people also care about the payoffs of others. Here, instead of being jealous when others get more than themselves, they are concerned when others get less. The other possibility is subject error (confusion). For unsophisticated subjects, it may not be immediately that contributing money to the public good is a dominated strategy. (This may not just be a failure to understand the mathematics. Many real world settings are similar to the public goods games, but give people incentives to contribute to the public good.) Declining contribution rates could reflect subjects becoming less confused. Andreoni’s experiments are designed to separate out these two hypotheses.

Experimental Design and Procedures For all treatments subjects play 10 rounds of a standard VCM game. The MPCR for all of the treatments is .5. Subjects played in fixed groups of five (partners). There were three treatments: Regular: This is a standard VCM game, with subjects paid their experimental earnings. Rank: In this treatment, subjects’ cash earnings are based on the rank of the experimental earnings. Subjects are shown the conversion table, so they know that their cash payoffs are solely determined by their rank. This treatment eliminates any incentive for cooperation and largely reduces the effects of “kindness.” RegRank: It is possible that just knowing about ranks (without it affecting one’s cash payoff) might change behavior. The RegRank treatment controls for this. It is identical to the regular treatment except that subjects are told their rank.

Initial Hypotheses If contribution to the public good is driven solely by confusion, we should expect the regular and rank treatments to yield (statistically) indistinguishable behavior. If kindness is playing an important role, we should expect lower contribution rates in the rank treatment. If there is no confusion present, we should expect no contributions in the rank treatment.

Results The percentage of subjects’ endowments contributed to the public good and the percentage of the subjects contributing something to the public good can consistently be ranked from top to bottom: Regular, RegRank, and Rank. These differences are statistically significant. The differences narrow over time, but this must happen as contribution rates are falling. While there are always at least some contributions in the rank treatment, these contributions die out to virtually nothing by the final round. This suggests that little confusion is left by the end of the experiment. Indeed, Andreoni attributes virtually all of the early cooperation to confusion (81% in round 1). This percentage drops steadily with experience. For experienced subjects, cooperation is rough 50% kindness, 50% confusion.

Conclusions Both kindness and confusion play some role in generating contribution in public goods games. Roughly half of these contributions seem to be directly due to kindness, with the proportion increasing over time. These results indicate that an examination of other-regarding preferences is necessary to understand contribution in public goods games.

Some Recent Work Conditional Cooperators: There is an increasingly large body of evidence that subjects in public goods games are “conditional cooperators” or “reciprocal altruists.” In other words these subjects are more willing to contribute if they think others will also be contributing. Fischbacher, Gächter, and Fehr (2001) provide a nice example of this. Punishments: Fehr and Gächter (2002) study a public goods game with punishments, much like the game you played in Block 3 of Tuesday’s experiment. The presence of these punishments doesn’t change the game’s equilibrium. None the less, they find that individuals frequently punish free-riders and that the overall level of contribution is dramatically increased by the presence of punishments. Social Sanctions: There has been an increasing interest among economists in social norms – behaviors supported more by social approval or disapproval than monetary incentives. Rege and Telle (2002) provides evidence that social sanctions of a very weak sort can greatly increase contributions in public goods games. This is the treatment we studied in Block 2.