Optimal Structure of Competition Authorities: a Model and Empirical Evidence Svetlana Avdasheva National Research University Higher School of Economics,

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Competition and the Market
Advertisements

Baker & McKenzie – CIS, Limited is a member firm of Baker & McKenzie International, a Swiss Verein with member law firms around the world. In accordance.
The fundamentals of EC competition law
GAMBIA COMPETITION COMMISSION GAMBIA COMPETITION COMMISSION Levelling the Field for Development SIXTH ANNUAL AFRICAN CONSUMER PROTECTION DIALOQUE CONFERENCE.
Economic analysis in German competition law enforcement
1 BINARY CHOICE MODELS: LOGIT ANALYSIS The linear probability model may make the nonsense predictions that an event will occur with probability greater.
1 BINARY CHOICE MODELS: PROBIT ANALYSIS In the case of probit analysis, the sigmoid function F(Z) giving the probability is the cumulative standardized.
FEDERAL ANTIMONOPOLY SERVICE. Government regulation on banking market in Russia Competition aspects.
BINARY CHOICE MODELS: LOGIT ANALYSIS
Asst. Prof. Dr. Alexander Bürgin IUE1 European Union Law and the Courts Repetition.
1 INTERACTIVE EXPLANATORY VARIABLES The model shown above is linear in parameters and it may be fitted using straightforward OLS, provided that the regression.
NADEZHDA GOREYKO SVETLANA AVDASHEVA
The Sixth Annual African Consumer Protection Dialogue Conference
Course: Law of the European Union [5] Administrative and judicial procedures in the European Union Filip Křepelka,
European Commission – Directorate General for Competition Dr. K. Mehta, Director, Cartels A PRIMER ON ANTI-TRUST POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION UCL – Louvain-la-Neuve.
The determinants of foreign investment in Russian food industry companies Draft of the paper Student: Gladysheva Anna Group: 41MMAE Argument consultant:
1 BINARY CHOICE MODELS: PROBIT ANALYSIS In the case of probit analysis, the sigmoid function is the cumulative standardized normal distribution.
An Introduction to regulation, it ’ s significance and rationale Kevin Hinde.
STRUCTURE AND FUNCTIONS OF COMPETITION AGENCIES. GENERAL STRUCTURE OF CA CAs differ in size, structure and complexity The structure depicts power distribution.
Chapter 6 Production. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 62 Topics to be Discussed The Technology of Production Production with One Variable Input.
1 INTRODUCTION OF THE LAWS ON ABUSE OF DOMINANT POSITION AND ABUSE OF MONOPONY POSITION IN VIETNAM Speaker: Mr. Trinh Anh Tuan Official Vietnam Competition.
1 SECTION 337 INVESTIGATIONS Managing Intellectual Property IP In China April 30, 2013 New York, New York.
Company LOGO New Paradigm for International Insurance Comparison: With an Application to Comparison of Seven Insurance Markets Wei Zheng, Peking University.
Erlinda M. Medalla April 27-28, 2006 Hanoi Understanding Competition Policy.
Defining and applying mitigating and aggravating circumstances. Relevant changes to the amount of fine. Defining and applying mitigating and aggravating.
FEDERAL ANTIMONOPOLY SERVICE International Competition Network 6 th Annual Conference Moscow 2007 Application Experience of International Competition Network.
Business and Society POST, LAWRENCE, WEBER Antitrust, Mergers, and Global Competition Chapter 9.
Competition policy in healthcare (market) Trudi Makhaya 1.
Commission Vs. Microsoft: "Rights", "Wrongs" and Priorities for Economic Analysis Prof. Yannis Katsoulacos, Athens University of Economics and Business,
Unilateral Exclusionary Conduct – An Analytical Framework Jorge Fagundes 3rd Coloquio - ForoCompetencia Buenos Aires, Argentina – November 2, 2007 Fagundes.
FEDERAL ANTIMONOPOLY SERVICE Moscow 2006 New Antimonopoly Law of the Russian Federation.
UNCTAD Competition Law and Policy The Institutional Framework for the Administration and Enforcement of Competition Law by Michael Adam, Competition law.
1 The role of Economics in European Competition Enforcement and Policy Damien Neven, Chief Economist * DG COMP, European Commission 5 th International.
1 Antimonopoly Committee of Ukraine Guidelines on setting fines imposed for violations of the law on protection of economic competition GENERAL APPROACHES.
1 BINARY CHOICE MODELS: LOGIT ANALYSIS The linear probability model may make the nonsense predictions that an event will occur with probability greater.
Company Law NAGY, Csongor István
Government intervention and competition policy 3.
ICC roundtable Istanbul, 30 April 2010 Procedural Fairness: Update on Recent OECD Activities Antonio Capobianco OECD Competition Division
Court Cases and Dispute Resolution on Tax Matters
Logic of Hypothesis Testing
3rd Economic Analysis of Litigation Workshop June
Competition Law and its Application: European Union
Competition Law (EU, USA, Turkey)
Competition Law (EU, USA, Turkey)
Author: Konstantinos Drakos Journal: Economica
Rethinking the Principal-Agent Theory of Judging
Filip Křepelka, Masarykova univerzita
Principles of Administrative Law <Instructor Name>
NMO Environmental Enforcement
Competition law Class 8-9
Conduct Remedies in BRICS Countries: Impact on Domestic and International Markets CRESSE th International Conference on Competition and Regulation.
Underwriter reputation and the quality of certification Evidence from high-yield bonds Accounting English 姓名:王海婷 学号: 亮亮图文旗舰店
Chapter 8: Production and Cost Analysis I
Tax Compliance, the IRS, and Tax Authorities
The competition enforcement in regulated sectors
Role of Government and Market Failures
ECO 550Competitive Success/tutorialrank.com
ECO 550 Education for Service-- tutorialrank.com.
Chapter 9: controlling mechanisms of governmental powers
Rights of Complainants in Competition Law Proceedings
Caron Beaton-Wells and Julie Clarke
Continuous improvement is the process by which organizations frequently review their procedures, aiming to correct errors or problems. The most effective.
The Economic Perspective on Different Sanctioning Methods – Achieving Deterrence & Maximizing Consumer Welfare Prepared for ICN Cartels Working Group Webinar.
European actions.
Parental liability & investment firms
Intel and the future of Article 102 TFEU
January 2019 Designing Upper Economics Electives with a significant writing component Helen Schneider The University of Texas at Austin.
Applied Economics Department, Institute of Industrial and Market Studies Legal standards in the Russian competition enforcement: interplay between competition.
THE GOALS OF COMPETITION LAW AND THE ROLE OF LEGAL INSTITUTIONS
Presentation transcript:

Optimal Structure of Competition Authorities: a Model and Empirical Evidence Svetlana Avdasheva National Research University Higher School of Economics, Russia Svetlana Golovanova Yannis Katsoulacos Athens University of Economics and Business, Greece EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Institutional structure and performance assessment Policy portfolio diversification Performance assessment Responsibilities other than antitrust and merger analysis Share of competition staff, % Separate units for different responsibilities Separate budgeting and performance assessment for different unites Welfare effects Output-type Enforcement success Cost efficiency Public / expert opinion US Antitrust Division Department of Justice No 100 Non applic. Non applicable Yes US Federal Trade Commission 47 EU Directorate General for Competition UK Competition and Market Authority 40 n/a Dutch Authority for Consumers and Markets 34 Australian Competition and Consumer Commission 44 South African Competition Commission 70 Brazilian CADE (Conselho Administrative de Defesa Econômica) 41 Russian Federal Antitrust Service No 1

Existing literature Issue has been the subject of investigation by economists and legal scholars with many prominent competition authors contributing, significantly improving our understanding of relevant factors. An (admittedly limited) list of contributions must include: Kovacic W., & D Hyman (2013) Lowe (2009) Fox E & M J Trebilcox (2012) Fels A. & H Ergas (2014) Jenny (2015) provides very good extensive review. Also - Reports by OECD (2003) (2014). EALE, 14-16 September 2017

A model and theoretical predictions We propose a model of a reputation maximizing CA in which reputation is increasing in enforcement success measured by the number of appealed infringement decisions that are not annulled. where Rk – reputation Sk - measures “enforcement success” in activity k. We assume that enforcement success depends on the number of decisions reached on cases opened that are not subsequently reversed - diminishing marginal utility with respect to decisions Dk - number of decisions in activity k - the probability that a decision in activity k is appealed and annulled in a Court of Appeals 0 <  < 1 EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Optimal choices ck – the marginal cost of investigating cases in activity k The optimal unconstrained number of decisions Result 1: other things equal optimal unconstrained number of decisions in activity k exceed those in activity j if the probability of annulment in latter is higher. EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Specialist authorities The maximum allowed by the authority’s budget: Optimal decisions by specialist authorities: EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Generalist authorities The authority’s total budget is the same as the sum of the budgets of the specialist authorities Assume that, by law the authority is constrained to undertake each period at least a certain minimum number of decisions per activity which is less than the optimal number of specialist CAs. Then the CA will maximize its utility by going for the maximum possible decisions of activity with higher marginal net reputation benefit (activity 1), given the constraints: EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Generalist authorities Result 2: A generalist CA will always increase the number of decisions of the reputation enhancing activity and decrease the number of decisions of the other activity, relative to budget constrained specialist CAs: and EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Welfare comparisons The welfare generated by each specialist authority’s activities will be given by: where - the average (consumer) welfare gain of decisions from activity k Keeping in mind that activity 1 has higher marginal net reputation benefit Result 3: A sufficient condition for welfare under a budget constrained specialist institutional structure to exceed welfare under a generalist institutional structure is that: It meant that the welfare gain per decision that is not annulled in Courts of Appeal, relative to its cost, must be higher for decisions in activity 2 than for decisions in activity 1. If this holds then an institutional structure with specialist CAs is welfare superior to one with a generalist CA. EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Empirical evidence Corollary of Results 2 and 3 (empirically testable prediction): If enforcement, e.g. on consumer protection or unfair practices, is an activity that is characterized by low annulment rates, relative to enforcement on e.g. antitrust related practices, then a generalist CA will tend to concentrate on the former (especially if marginal costs are not larger, or are not much larger in the former), though this may well be welfare-reducing (if, on average, antitrust decisions have a more beneficial impact on welfare). We provide empirical evidence using a very large dataset of appealed infringement decisions that were made between 2008 – 2012 by the Russian Federal Antitrust Authority (FAS). We examine whether FAS’ enforcement choices in this period can be explained by reputational, “Enforcement Success” related, considerations in different enforcement activities. EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Proper and non-proper enforcement activities We distinguish between two types of decisions. One, that we associate with Antitrust Enforcement in the standard sense (Proper Antitrust Decisions) and a second one involving decisions that cannot be treated as antitrust - though FAS makes these under Russian law on competition. We term the latter Non-Proper Antitrust (NPA) Decisions – these involve many decisions that in other jurisdictions would be the responsibility of unfair practices or consumer protection units. FAS applied legislation of abuse of dominance according to the principle of strict liability of dominant company for every harm imposed on counterparties. We call the investigations where there is no evidence on competition restriction, and there is no causal relationship between dominance and harm imposed non-proper antitrust decisions (NPAs) in contrast to proper antitrust decisions (PA). EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Prob. (Pearson chi2) < 0.001 NPA vs. PA Percent in the overall sample Share of decisions with monetary penalties Monetary penalty if applied, in thousandsRUR, mean, st. err. in parentheses Enforcement success (fraction of infringement decisions not annulled), percent Time from registration of claim to final decision (in months, st. err. in parentheses) Non-proper antitrust (NPA) decisions 82.85 11,82 4.60 (0.90) 61.93 9.78 (0.10) Proper antitrust (PA) decisions 17.15 14,24 109.80 (57.90) 53.12 12.04 (0.28) Prob. difference=0 Prob. (Pearson chi2) = 0.081 Prob. (t-stat) < 0.001 Prob. (Pearson chi2) < 0.001 EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Empirical analysis H1. Decisions on proper antitrust cases have lower enforcement success (higher probability of annulment under judicial review) than decisions on non-proper antitrust cases. H2. Decisions on proper antitrust cases require larger amount of resources of CA than decision on non-proper antitrust cases. EALE, 14-16 September 2017

duration of litigation, in months 10.16 6.18 57 Content of a decision Variable name Description Obs. Mean St. dev. Min Max Dependent variables Success =1 if infringement decision stay in force after all instances, =0 otherwise 3931 0.60 1 Duration duration of litigation, in months 10.16 6.18 57 Content of a decision PA =1 if the case is a proper antitrust one, =0 otherwise 0.17 Competition authority – related determinants (X1) Law period 2012 =1 for cases initiated after the change of Russian antitrust legislation in the end of 2011, =0 otherwise 0.21 CA experience logarithm of the number of antitrust cases decided in the region in the past 3.37 1.22 0.69 5.67 Sanctions – related determinants (X2) Fine =1 if monetary fine is mentioned in the decision, =0 otherwise 0.12 Size of the fine logarithm of the fine size in thousands of rubles, =0 otherwise 3884 2.11 18.37 Conduct remedies =1 if conduct remedies are mentioned in the decision, =0 otherwise 0.31 Violator – related determinants (X3) Size of violator =1 if the alleged violator is one of 400 largest companies in Russia, =0 otherwise 0.16 Repeat offender =1 if the company is a repeat offender 0.43 Other variables Several instances (appeals in more than one court) =1 if the case was considered in more than one court instances (decision of the first instance court was appealed) , =0 otherwise 0.82 Highest court appeal =1 is the case was sued to highest instance court, =0 otherwise 0.22 EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Empirical Approach EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Baseline Probit Regressions Dependent variable: enforcement success Baseline Probit Regressions Robustness checks Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Sub- sample 1 sample 2 sample 3 sample 4 PA -0.067*** -0.062*** -0.074*** -0.034 -0.082*** -0.020 -0.050* Law period 0.031 (1 – PA) x Law period 0.033 competition authority – related determinants CA experience 0.036*** 0.038*** 0.043*** 0.029** 0.046*** 0.047*** 0.031*** sanctions – related determinants Fine -0.063** Size of fine -0.013*** -0.019** -0.011*** -0.022*** -0.010* Conduct remedies -0.053*** -0.052*** -0.072* -0.048*** -0.003 -0.040* violator – related determinants Size of violator -0.064*** -0.059*** -0.049** -0.098 -0.044*** -0.027 Repeat offender 0.024 0.025 Number of observations 3931 3884 701 3183 860 2002 Pseudo R2 0.0158 0.0175 0.0164 0.0149 0.0176 0.0010 0.0016 Prob. > chi2 0.0000 0.0148 0.0174 0.0075 correctly classified (default = 0.5) 60.34% 60.53% 61.05% 60.63% 61.23% 57.44% 64.54%

Baseline OLS Regressions Dependent variable: duration of court proceeding in months Baseline OLS Regressions Robustness check Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Sub- sample 1 sample 2 sample 3 sample 4 Constant 1.909*** 1.913*** 1.917*** 1.275*** 2.188*** 2.600*** 1.976*** PA 0.203*** 0.192*** 0.196*** 0.308*** 0.180*** 0.118*** 0.252*** Law period -0.007 (1-NPA) x law period -0.026 competition authority – related determinants CA experience 0.030*** 0.029*** 0.027*** -0.015 0.013** 0.016* 0.016 sanctions – related determinants Fine 0.067** Size of fine 0.015*** 0.052*** 0.009** 0.008* 0.011 Conduct remedies 0.090*** 0.089*** -0.082 0.0.72*** 0.040* 0.076** violator – related determinants Size of violator 0.160*** 0.161*** 0.034 0.109*** 0.033 0.168*** Repeat offender 0.070*** 0.068*** 0.062 -0.000 -0.043* 0.054* Number of observations 3931 3884 701 3183 860 2002 R2 adj. 0.0347 0.0351 0.0350 0.0542 0.0377 0.0291 0.0413 Prob. > F 0.0000

Results of the econometric analysis show that the marginal contribution of a NPA case to reputation is higher and marginal cost under litigation is lower. There is no stage of the judicial review where higher expected enforcement success coexists with higher costs. According to the model this should imply that the number of NPA decisions for a reputation-maximizing authority is higher than the number of PA decisions. However it is far from clear that this choice is conducive to generating the largest welfare impact from enforcement. EALE, 14-16 September 2017

Thank you! EALE, 14-16 September 2017