Informal Creditors and Sovereign Debt Restructuring

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Granting and activation of guarantees in an updated SNA.
Advertisements

The Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account Professor Roberto Chang Rutgers University January 2007.
Credit Derivatives.
1 Chapter 14 The Debt Crisis of the 1980s © Pierre-Richard Agénor and Peter J. Montiel.
Optimal Collective Action Clause Thresholds Andrew G Haldane, Adrian Penalver, Victoria Saporta and Hyun Song Shin.
Lecture 6: Debt Policy Changing a firm’s capital structure should not affect its value to shareholders. This chapter analyzes several possible financing.
Saving, growth and the current account Daan Steenkamp ERSA / SASI Savings workshop August 2009.
EVOLUTION OF DISCLOSURE REGULATION RATIONALES: PRELUDE TO A NEW THEORY.
THE BORROWER-LENDER RELATIONSHIP. AGENDA 4 THE RISK SHARING APPROACH 4 COSTLY STATE VERIFICATION 4 INCENTIVES TO REPAY 4 INCOMPLETE CONTRACTS 4 DISCRIMINATING.
What is the ADF Partial Risk Guarantee? Partial Risk Guarantees (PRGs), also known as political risk guarantees, cover private lenders and investors against.
Sovereign risk and investment Yilin DONG. The role of investment under direct sanctions A representative agent with utility function: U 1 =u(C 1 )+βu(C.
An Overview of the Financial System chapter 2. Function of Financial Markets Lenders-Savers (+) Households Firms Government Foreigners Financial Markets.
Theory of Banking ( ) Marcello Messori Dottorato in Economia Internazionale April, 2005.
McGraw-Hill /Irwin Copyright © 2004 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved Chapter Twenty Types of Risks Incurred by Financial Institutions.
International Factor Movements
L11: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing 1 Lecture 11: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing The following topics will be covered: Pareto Efficient Risk Allocation.
An Overview of Financial Markets and Institutions
Goals of the Paper Explore the dynamic adjustment to a new WTO Round of Trade Liberalization from 2000 to 2010 Explore how this helps Asia Crisis economies.
Lecture 5 Contracting and Other Economic Determinants of Financial Reporting.
Interest Rates. An interest rate is the rate at which interest is paid by a borrower for the use of money that they borrow from a lender. For example,
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Monetary Policy Responses to Food and Fuel Price Volatility Eswar Prasad Cornell University, Brookings Institution and NBER.
ACCT3003 Issues in Accounting Theory
Estimating pension discount rates David McCarthy.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
11 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair General Equilibrium.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
The Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account Professor Roberto Chang Rutgers University March 2013.
L6: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing1 Lecture 6: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing The following topics will be covered: Pareto Efficient Risk Allocation –Defining.
HISTORY VS EXPECTATIONS -- PAUL KRUGMAN PRESENTATION BY -KOSHA MODI -PALLAVI JINDAL.
Security Markets V Miloslav S Vošvrda Theory of Capital Markets.
Introduction to Supply-side Policies Demand-side policies have one major weakness: they are not effective at promoting long-run economic growth. PL SRAS.
Money Tom Porter, Money There are two dimensions to money and two markets used to understand money. 1.Loanable Funds Markets – Savings and investment.
Chapter Thirty-Six Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets u In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded.
The free operation of the market system sometimes results in resources not being used in ways that efficiently satisfy needs and wants of consumers.
Bonds and Their Valuation
Banking and the Management of Financial Institutions
Chapter 9 Banking and the Management of Financial Institutions
Financial Markets: International Context: MN10403
Human Capital Human capital corresponds to any stock of knowledge or characteristics the worker has (either innate or acquired) that contributes to his.
On privatization methods in Eastern Europe and their implications
The Fundamentals of Managerial Economics
2.5, 2.6 Monetary and Supply-side Policies
sources of short term and long term financing
Chapter 16 Learning Objectives
An Overview of Financial Markets and Institutions
Introduction to Financial Institutions and Markets
Chapter 19 Jones, Investments: Analysis and Management
EVOLUTION OF DISCLOSURE REGULATION RATIONALES: PRELUDE TO A NEW THEORY
Chapter 7 International Factor Movements.
Economics, Markets and Organizations
Asymmetric Information
SWARNAM S/UNIT 1/RISK & RETURN - CBS
CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES FOR MOBILIZING CONSTRUCTION FINANCE By Gomolemo Zimona Botswana Housing Corporation.
BANKS, MONEY, AND THE CREDIT MARKET
ROSTOW’S MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT
Grossman and Hart (1986) Journal of Political Economy
Chapter 32 Valuing Flexibility Instructors:
Chapter 9 Banking and the Management of Financial Institutions
THE CREDIT MARKET: BORROWERS, LENDERS, AND THE RATE OF INTEREST
Aggregate Demand and Supply
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model.
Global Equity Markets.
Analyzing and Structuring Financially Sustainable Investments
Financial Sector (continued)
Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 3
The Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account
Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 3
Presentation transcript:

Informal Creditors and Sovereign Debt Restructuring Sayantan Ghosal and Dania Thomas, University of Glasgow

Efficiency Trade-Offs in Sovereign Debt Restructuring Is there a trade-off between lowering the costs of a sovereign debt restructuring (leading to interim or ex post welfare gains) and the interest rate charged on sovereign debt (linked to ex ante welfare gains)? Conventional view: (a) default is less likely the higher the anticipated probability of costly (interim inefficient) debt restructuring, (b) as a consequence, interest rates at which sovereigns can borrow are lower (ex ante welfare gains). Brookings Report (2013): need for alternative perspectives. This paper: conditional on an economy-wide negative shock, lowering the costs of sovereign debt restructuring also lowers the interest rate charged on sovereign debt.

Inter-Creditor Inequity and Informal Creditors Bolton and Skeel (2007) highlight the problem of inter-creditor inequity between ‘formal and informal creditors- those who have a contract and those whose benefits are part of the social contract’.  Guzman and Stiglitz (2016): Delayed debt restructuring and reliance on ‘bailouts’ creates ‘large inter-creditor inequities as only the creditors that get paid with the resources of the “bailouts” benefit while the expected value of the claims of the other claimants (such as the creditors whose debts mature in a longer term, or the workers and pensioners whose wages depend on the capacity of production of the economy that decreases precisely as the consequence of the austerity often associated with those plans) decreases’. A debt restructuring process should ‘ensure ‘overall economic efficiency a critical feature of which is ex post efficiency...it should provide the conditions for a rapid and sustained economic recovery’. (Guzman and Stiglitz (2016))

Non-contractible Domestic Elite Payoffs Domestic agents are split into two groups, a minority elite and a majority non-elite. The domestic elite (a) lend to the sovereign state, (b) participate in international capital markets, (c) are organized effectively and engage in collective political activity (party formation and collective Political Activity (Olson (1965)). Taken together, these three factors ensure that their payoffs are non-contractible (i.e. cannot be used for debt repayments without their explicit consent).

The Domestic Non-elite and Incentives to Restructure Debt The non-elite do not lend to the sovereign, cannot directly participate in international capital markets and cannot engage in collective political activity. Their payoffs are claims on domestic income, as part of a social contract (i.e. the non-elite are informal creditors). Under certain conditions, we show that: conditional on a negative shock, the incentives to restructure debt are different for the domestic elite and non-elite, debt restructuring leads to both interim and ex ante welfare gains.

The Decision to Restructure The factors that sustain non-contractibility of elite payoffs also ensure that their interests prevail. For the non-elite to acquire decision-making power, they must be able to organise themselves to engage in costly collective political activity (e.g. anti-austerity protests/movements). Which outcome prevails? Key factors: (a) the probability that an organised non-elite successfully usurps decision-making power, and (b) the distribution of the cost of engaging in collective political action within the non-elite.

A Role for the UNCTAD Roadmap (UNCTAD, 2015)

Model 1 𝑡=0,1,2; a single good in each period. Three agent types: domestic elites, mass 𝛼; domestic non-elites (informal creditors), mass 1−𝛼, 0<𝛼< 1 2 ; foreign creditors. All consumption in the last two periods. Common Preferences: instantaneous utility function represented by 𝑢 . , 𝑢 0 , 𝑢 ′ . >0, 𝑢 ′′ . <0, 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑥→0 𝑢 𝑥 =∞; Common discount factor, 0<𝛿<1. At 𝑡=0, elite endowment 𝑤 0 >0; non-elite endowment is zero.

Model 2 Domestic output in periods 1 and 2 requires an initial public investment of 𝐼 0 ; under the assumption that 𝐼 0 > 𝑤 0 , 𝐼 0 − 𝑤 0 has to be financed by borrowing from foreign creditors with 𝑤 0 financed by the elite at an interest rate 𝑟 (determined in equilibrium by a no-arbitrage constraint). At 𝑡=1, domestic output is 𝑌 1 ∈{ 𝑌 𝐿 1 , 𝑌 𝐻 1 } with probability 1−𝑞,𝑞 , 0≤𝑞≤1. At 𝑡=2, output in period 2 has a stochastic structure: if a public investment 𝐼 1 is made at 𝑡=1, then output in period 2 is 𝑌 2 = 𝑌 𝐻 2 ; otherwise, 𝑌 2 ∈{ 𝑌 𝐿 2 , 𝑌 𝐻 2 } with probability 𝑝,1−𝑝 , 0<𝑝<1.

Model 3 In each period, a fraction 𝛽,0<𝛽<1, appropriated by the elite for their private benefit and the remaining quantity 1−𝛽 𝑌 1 , 𝑌 1 ∈ 𝑌 𝐿 1 , 𝑌 𝐻 1 , available for further investment, interest repayments on debt and non-elite consumption. At 𝑡=1, in the event of no default, the interest payment received by the elite can be used either for consumption in that period or for purchasing a non-domestic asset that guarantees a payoff of 𝛽𝑌 𝐻 2 in period 2; with default, the option to invest in the non-domestic asset isn’t available. In any period, with default, there is a direct utility cost of 𝐵 𝑁𝐸 (resp. 𝐵 𝐸 ) to the non-elite (resp. elite) with 𝐵 𝑁𝐸 ≥ 𝐵 𝐸 >0.

Analysis For simplicity, assume the riskless interest rate 𝑟 𝑓 =1. Two assumptions: (A1) 2𝐼 0 1+𝑞 < 1−𝛽 𝑌 𝐿 1 < 𝐼 1 + 2𝐼 0 1+𝑞 <min{ 𝑌 𝐿 1 , 1−𝛽 𝑌 𝐻 1 }; (A2) 1−𝛽 𝑌 𝐿 2 < 3+𝑞 1+𝑞 𝐼 0 < 1−𝛽 𝑌 𝐻 2 . Proposition 1. Under assumptions (A1) and (A2), there exists 𝑌 >0, 𝜀>0 and 𝛼 >0 such that whenever 𝑌 𝐻 2 > 𝑌 , 0<𝑌 𝐿 1 − 𝐼 1 + 2+𝑝(1−𝑞) 2−𝑝(1−𝑞) 𝐼 0 <𝜀, 0<𝛼< 𝛼 and 𝑝> 2 3+𝑞 it follows that there are both ex ante and interim social welfare gains when, conditional on 𝑌 1 = 𝑌 𝐿 1 , debt is restructured. However, conditional on a negative shock in period 1, the domestic elite do not have an incentive to restructure debt while the domestic non-elite do.

The Decision to Restructure Debt In the absence of collective political activity by the non-elite, elite interests will prevail. Following Olson (1965), assume that successful collective political activity is organized by an organisation (such as a political party or a labour union) whose members are rewarded selectively. Conditional on 𝑌 1 = 𝑌 𝐿 1 , let ∆ denote the per capita payoff gain to a non-elite agent. Let 𝜋 denote the fraction of the non-elite who join the party and suppose the probability with which the non-elite usurp decision-making power is also given by f π =min{𝜋, 𝜋 𝑚𝑎𝑥 }. Payoff to a non-elite party member is 𝑓(𝜋) 𝜋 ∆−𝑐; payoff to a non-elite agent who is not a party member is 0.

Non-Elite Collective Action Suppose 𝑐∈[0, 𝑐 ] with cdf 𝐻(𝑐). Let 𝑐 (𝜋)= 𝑓(𝜋) 𝜋 ∆. Equilibrium participation: min{𝐻 𝑐 (𝜋) ,1}=𝜋. Proposition 2. (i) 𝜋 𝑚𝑎𝑥 ∆≥ 𝑐 , 𝜋=1 is the only equilibrium; (ii) Suppose 𝜋 𝑚𝑎𝑥 ∆< 𝑐 . Then: (a) if 𝐻 ∆ ≥ 𝜋 𝑚𝑎𝑥 , equilibrium participation is 𝜋= 𝜋 𝑚𝑎𝑥 , 𝑏 if 𝐻 ∆ < 𝜋 𝑚𝑎𝑥 , then equilibrium participation is given by 𝜋=𝐻(∆). Effectiveness of anti-austerity protests depends on (a) the distribution of participation costs (relative to payoff gains) within the non-elite (shape of 𝐻(𝑐)) and (b) the maximum probability of usurping political power.

Open Questions Empirical substantiation; Contrasting Case studies: Iceland, Greece; Incorporating secondary debt markets; A full-fledged dynamic general model; Implications for official sector involvement to restore liquidity and prevent a self-fulfilling debt crisis: use of conditionality and the UNCTAD Roadmap; Implications for capital account convertibility.