Mathematics for Economists [Section A – Part 1 / 4]

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Advertisements

1 Chapter 9 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Finance 30210: Managerial Economics Optimization.
Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Optimization using Calculus
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTIMIZATION
Lecture 4 MGMT © 2011 Houman Younessi Supply: Production What is the optimal level of output? How should we decide among alternative production.
Maximization without Calculus Not all economic maximization problems can be solved using calculus –If a manager does not know the profit function, but.
Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Constrained Maximization
The Envelope Theorem The envelope theorem concerns how the optimal value for a particular function changes when a parameter of the function changes This.
Microeconomics for International Trade Theory
Functions of Several Variables Most goals of economic agents depend on several variables –Trade-offs must be made The dependence of one variable (y) on.
Economics 214 Lecture 39 Constrained Optimization.
THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTIMIZATION
Chapter 1 Economic Models Slides created by Linda Ghent
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Applied Economics for Business Management
Differentiation in Economics – Objectives 1 Understand that differentiation lets us identify marginal relationships in economics Measure the rate of change.
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTIMIZATION
Econ 533 Econometrics and Quantitative Methods One Variable Calculus and Applications to Economics.
Optimization Techniques Methods for maximizing or minimizing an objective function Examples –Consumers maximize utility by purchasing an optimal combination.
Managerial Economics Managerial Economics = economic theory + mathematical eco + statistical analysis.
11. Cost minimization Econ 494 Spring 2013.
4.1 The Theory of Optimization  Optimizing Theory deals with the task of finding the “best” outcome or alternative –Maximums and –Minimums  What output.
1 Chapter 9 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Chapter 5 Choice.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Math Review. 2 Functions and Graphs Functions are used to describe the relationship between two variables. Ex: Suppose y.
Slide 1  2005 South-Western Publishing Appendix 2A Differential Calculus in Management A function with one decision variable, X, can be written as Y =
Managerial Economics Prof. M. El-Sakka CBA. Kuwait University Managerial Economics in a Global Economy Chapter 2 Optimization Techniques and New Management.
1 THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTIMIZATION Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Walter Nicholson, Microeconomic.
Chapter 9 Production Functions
MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1 COURSE OVERVIEW AND INTRODUCTION WEEK 1.
Slide 1  2002 South-Western Publishing Web Chapter A Optimization Techniques Overview Unconstrained & Constrained Optimization Calculus of one variable.
Managerial Economics Managerial Economics = economic theory + mathematical eco + statistical analysis.
Faculty of Economics Optimization Lecture 3 Marco Haan February 28, 2005.
1 Production, Costs, and Supply Principles of Microeconomics Professor Dalton ECON 202 – Fall 2013.
Supply and Demand. The Law of Demand The law of demand holds that other things equal, as the price of a good or service rises, its quantity demanded falls.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 3 Applications of the Derivative.
10. Envelope Theorem Econ 494 Spring Agenda Indirect profit function Envelope theorem for general unconstrained optimization problems Theorem Proof.
C opyright  2007 by Oxford University Press, Inc. PowerPoint Slides Prepared by Robert F. Brooker, Ph.D.Slide 1 1.
Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Chapter 5: Production and Cost Copyright.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Chapter 11 PROFIT MAXIMIZATION. 2 Profit Maximization A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the sole goal of achieving.
A Closer Look at Production and Costs
Chapter 11 Profit Maximization.
Appendix 2A Differential Calculus in Management
Chapter 6 Production.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.
UNIT 6 COSTS AND PRODUCTION: LONG AND SHORT-RUN, TOTAL, FIXED AND VARIABLE COSTS, LAW OF DIMINISHING RETURNS, INCREASING, CONSTANT AND DIMINISHING RETURNS.
MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY
SUPPLY AND DEMAND THEORY (PART 1)
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE
Principles and Worldwide Applications, 7th Edition
Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: , b
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Cost Minimization and Cost Curves
A Closer Look at Production and Costs
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 7 Functions of Several Variables
Graphs and Their Meaning
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Macroeconomics, 9e
Presentation transcript:

Mathematics for Economists [Section A – Part 1 / 4] Instructor: Annika M. Mueller, Ph.D., The Wang Yanan Institute for Studies in Economics Main Reference: C. P. Simon and L. Blume (1994), Mathematics for Economists Further Reading: W. Nicholson and C. Snyder (2011), Microeconomic Theory

Optimization Economic models often based on assumption that economic agents (individuals, firms) are seeking to find the optimal value of some function, for example consumers maximize utility firms maximize profit Cover mathematics common to these problems

Maximization of a Function of One Variable Classic example: Profit maximization of a firm  Profit maximum (*) occurs at quantity q* * q*  = f(q) Quantity

Profit Maximization (cont'd) q* will likely be reached through an adjustment process an increase from q1 to q2 leads to a rise in profits  * 2 q2  = f(q) 1 Quantity q1 q*

Profit Maximization (cont'd) If output is increased beyond q*, profit will decline an increase from q* to q3 leads to a decline of profits  * 3 q3  = f(q) Quantity q*

Derivatives The derivative of  = f(q) is the limit of /q for very small changes in q The value of this ratio depends on the value of q1

Value of a Derivative at a Point The evaluation of the derivative at the point q = q1 can be denoted In our previous example,

Second Order Conditions The first order condition (d/dq) is a necessary condition for a maximum, but it is not a sufficient condition  If the profit function was u-shaped, the first order condition would result in q* being chosen and  would be minimized * q* Quantity

Second Order Conditions The first order condition is a necessary condition for a maximum, but not a sufficient condition c If the function was u-shaped (think: cost function), the first order condition results in q* being chosen, minimizing c. c* q* Quantity

Second Order Conditions In order for q* to be the optimum for a profit function, and Therefore, at q*, d/dq must be zero.

Second Derivatives The derivative of a derivative is called a second derivative The second derivative can be denoted by

Second Order Condition The second order condition to represent a (local) maximum is

Functions of Several Variables Most functions that economic agents are trying to optimize depend on more than just one variable trade-offs must be made The dependence of one variable (y) on a series of other variables (x1,x2,…,xn) is denoted by

Partial Derivatives The partial derivative of y with respect to x1 is denoted by It is understood that in calculating the partial derivative, all of the other x’s are held constant “How do changes in one variable affect some outcome when other influences are held constant (ceteris paribus)”

Partial Derivatives A more formal definition of the partial derivative is

Partial Derivatives Units of measurement matter: if q represents the quantity of gasoline demanded (measured in billions of gallons) and p represents the price in dollars per gallon, then q/p will measure the change in demand (in billions of gallons per year) for a dollar per gallon change in price

Second-Order Partial Derivatives The partial derivative of a partial derivative is called a second-order partial derivative

Young’s Theorem Under general conditions, the order in which partial differentiation is conducted to evaluate second-order partial derivatives does not matter

Use of Second-Order Partials Second-order partials play an important role in many economic theories One of the most important is a variable’s own second-order partial, fii shows how the marginal influence of xi on y (y/xi) changes as the value of xi increases a value of fii < 0 indicates diminishing marginal effectiveness

Total Differential Suppose that y = f(x1,x2,…,xn) If all x’s are varied by a small amount, the total effect on y will be

First-Order Condition for a Maximum (or Minimum) A necessary condition for a maximum (or minimum) of the function f(x1,x2,…,xn) is that dy = 0 for any combination of small changes in the x’s The only way for this to be true is if A point where this condition holds is called a critical point

Finding a Maximum Suppose that y is a function of x1 and x2 y = - (x1 - 1)2 - (x2 - 2)2 + 10 y = - x12 + 2x1 - x22 + 4x2 + 5 First-order conditions imply that OR

The Envelope Theorem The envelope theorem concerns how the optimal value for a particular function changes when a parameter of the function changes This is easiest to see by using an example

The Envelope Theorem Suppose that y is a function of x y = -x2 + ax For different values of a, this function represents a family of inverted parabolas If a is assigned a specific value, then y becomes a function of x only and the value of x that maximizes y can be calculated

The Envelope Theorem Optimal Values of x and y for alternative values of a

The Envelope Theorem As a increases, the maximal value for y (y*) increases

y* = -(x*)2 + a(x*) = -(a/2)2 + a(a/2) The Envelope Theorem To calculate the slope of the function, we must solve for the optimal value of x for any value of a dy/dx = -2x + a = 0 x* = a/2 Substituting, we get y* = -(x*)2 + a(x*) = -(a/2)2 + a(a/2) y* = -a2/4 + a2/2 = a2/4

The Envelope Theorem Therefore, dy*/da = 2a/4 = a/2 = x* But, we can save time by using the envelope theorem for small changes in a, dy*/da can be computed by holding x at x* and calculating y/ a directly from y

The Envelope Theorem Holding x = x* y/ a = x Holding x = x* y/ a = x* = a/2 This is the same result found earlier

The Envelope Theorem The envelope theorem states that the change in the optimal value of a function with respect to a parameter of that function can be found by partially differentiating the objective function while holding x (or several x’s) at its optimal value

The Envelope Theorem The envelope theorem can be extended to the case where y is a function of several variables y = f(x1,…xn,a) Finding an optimal value for y would consist of solving n first-order equations y/xi = 0 (i = 1,…,n)

The Envelope Theorem Optimal values for theses x’s would be determined that are a function of a x1* = x1*(a) x2* = x2*(a) xn*= xn*(a) .

y* = f [x1*(a), x2*(a),…,xn*(a),a] The Envelope Theorem Substituting into the original objective function yields an expression for the optimal value of y (y*) y* = f [x1*(a), x2*(a),…,xn*(a),a] Differentiating yields

The Envelope Theorem Because of first-order conditions, all terms except f/a are equal to zero if the x’s are at their optimal values Therefore,