In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU
Advertisements

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 16 Unemployment: Search and Efficiency Wages.
Uncertainty and Information CHAPTER 19 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain.
Supply and Demand The goal of this chapter is to explain how supply and demand really work. What determines the price of a good or service? How does the.
Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Part 1 Marketing Dynamics
“A little knowledge is a dangerous thing. So is a lot.”
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 22 Frontiers of Microeconomics.
Government Policies That Alter the Private Market Outcome
What is economics?.
Market Equilibrium: The Invisible Hand Randy Rucker Professor Department of Agricultural Economics and Economics June 19, 2013.
CHAPTER 10 CREDIT You’re in Charge
The Federal Reserve System Chapter 14 Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
1 Consumer Motivation CHAPTER 8. 2 Consumer Motivation Represents the drive to satisfy both physiological and psychological needs through product purchase.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies. Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 2 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies In a free, unregulated.
KOOTHS | BiTS: Economic Policy and Market Regulation (winter term 2013/2014), Part 2 1 Economic Policy and Market Regulation Part 2 Dr. Stefan Kooths BiTS.
An Introduction to International Economics
Chapter 18 Pricing Policies McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter 12 Capturing Surplus.
15 Monopoly.
1 1 BA 445 Lesson C.4 Signaling Product Quality ReadingsReadings Baye Signaling (see the index) Dixit Chapter 9.
Measuring the Economy’s Performance
© 2007 Thomson South-Western, all rights reserved N. G R E G O R Y M A N K I W PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich Public Goods and Common Resources 11.
© 2010 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2010 update Public Goods and Common Resources M icroeconomics P R I.
Application: International Trade
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 12 Keynesian Business Cycle Theory: Sticky Wages and Prices.
Principles of Marketing
© 2010 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2010 update Firms in Competitive Markets M icroeconomics P R I N C.
Globalization and International Trade Lecture 8 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini.
Introduction Microeconomics continues to evolve.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other. Consider a market.
1 Public choice Alexander W. Cappelen Econ
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION A difference in access to relevant knowledge is called information asymmetry.
The Voting Problem: A Lesson in Multiagent System Based on Jose Vidal’s book Fundamentals of Multiagent Systems Henry Hexmoor SIUC.
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
MACROECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS and the FINANCIAL SYSTEM © 2011 Worth Publishers, all rights reservedPowerPoint® slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 20/1 Chapter 20 Asymmetric Information and Market Behaviour.
Slide 1  2002 South-Western Publishing An assumption of pure competition was complete knowledge of all market information. But knowledge can be unevenly.
Adverse Selection Asymmetric information is feature of many markets
Chapter 11 Game Theory and Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western, all rights reserved N. G R E G O R Y M A N K I W PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich 1 P R I N C I P L E S O F F O U R T.
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Lectures Section Seven: Market Failure Introduction to Microeconomics (L11100)
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 22 Frontiers of Microeconomics.
CHAPTER 17 Uncertainty and Asymmetric Information © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Microeconomics 9e by Case, Fair.
Economics PRINCIPLES OF By N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics
Imperfect Information: Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons
Economics of Information Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard Chapter 17.
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION 1. Definition of asymmetric information 2. Sources of.
Principles of Microeconomics 15. Psychology and Economics* Akos Lada August 13th, 2014 * Slide content principally sourced from N. Gregory Mankiw and David.
Markets with Asymmetric Information
Contracting The incentives of the employer (principal) and employee (agent) are different. A contract is designed to implement an outcome both parties.
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Markets with Asymmetric Information
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Frontiers of Microeconomics
Presentation transcript:

Frontiers of Microeconomics 22 Frontiers of Microeconomics Microeconomics P R I N C I P L E S O F N. Gregory Mankiw This is the final microeconomics chapter. It introduces students to three relatively new areas of research in microeconomics: asymmetric information, political economy, and behavioral economics. If these topics have anything in common, it is this: Each shows that things are not always as ideal as the traditional economic models assume. Consumers do not always behave rationally. Government solutions do not always improve things. And market outcomes may suffer when market participants don’t all have access to the same information. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: How does asymmetric information affect market outcomes? How can market participants reduce the resulting problems? Why might democratic voting systems fail to represent the preferences of society? Why do people not always behave as rational maximizers? 1

Introduction Microeconomics continues to evolve. Microeconomics continues to evolve. This chapter introduces three active areas of research: Asymmetric information Political economy Behavioral economics FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 2

Asymmetric Information Information asymmetry: a difference in two or more parties’ access to relevant knowledge Two types: Hidden actions – one person knows more than another about an action he or she is taking. Hidden characteristics – one person knows more than another about the attributes of good he or she is selling. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 3

Hidden Actions and Moral Hazard Moral hazard: the tendency of a person who is imperfectly monitored to engage in dishonest or otherwise undesirable behavior Workers sometimes shirk their responsibilities because their employer cannot continually monitor their effort and performance. Someone whose property is insured may not try as hard to protect it from theft/damage. While the parents are out, the babysitter may spend more time watching videos than watching the children. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 4

The Principal-Agent Problem Agent: a person who is performing a task on someone else’s behalf (e.g., a worker) Principal: the person for whom this action is being performed (e.g., an employer) When the principal cannot perfectly monitor the agent’s behavior, there is a risk (“hazard”) that the agent may do something undesirable (“immoral”). E.g., worker may play video games or surf the web while on the clock. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 5

How Principals May Respond Better monitoring Parents plant hidden cameras in the home to increase the chance of detecting undesirable behavior. Higher wages Employers pay workers efficiency wages (wages above the equilibrium level) to increase the penalty for being caught shirking. Delayed payment Firms delay payment (e.g., year-end bonuses) to increase the penalty for being caught shirking. Chapter 19 introduced and discussed efficiency wages. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 6

Corporate Management The separation of ownership and control of corporations creates a principal-agent problem: Principals: the shareholders, pay managers to maximize the firm’s profits Agents: the managers, may pursue their own objectives Shareholders hire a board of directors to oversee management, create incentives for management to pursue the firm’s goals instead of their own. Corporate managers sometimes sent to jail for taking advantage of shareholders. This is a case of hidden actions and moral hazard: Managers know the firm much more intimately than shareholders, and have control of the firm’s resources. A manager may be tempted to use corporate resources for personal gain, or may use insider information to make illegal stock trades. To align managers’ interests with the firm’s goals, the Board of Directors designs compensation packages with incentives such as shares of stock or bonuses based on the firm’s performance. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 7

Hidden Characteristics and Adverse Selection Hidden Characteristics and Adverse Selection Adverse selection arises when the seller knows more than the buyer about the good being sold. Example 1: The market for used cars The seller knows more than the buyer about the quality of the car being sold. Owners of “lemons” more likely to put their vehicles up for sale. So buyers are more likely to avoid used cars. Owners of good used cars less likely to get a fair price, so may not bother trying to sell. The classic paper on this example is George Akerlof’s “The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” Akerlof was awarded a Nobel Prize in 2001 for his contributions to research on asymmetric information. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 8

Hidden Characteristics and Adverse Selection Hidden Characteristics and Adverse Selection Example 2: Insurance Buyers of health insurance know more about their health than health insurance companies. People with hidden health problems have more incentive to buy insurance policies. So, prices of policies reflect the costs of a sicker-than-average person. These prices discourage healthy people from buying insurance. In both examples, the information asymmetry prevents some mutually beneficial trades. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 9

Market Responses to Asymmetric Information Market Responses to Asymmetric Information Signaling: action taken by an informed party to reveal private information to an uninformed party Individual selling a good used car provides all receipts for work done on car. Dealership provides warranties on used cars. Firms spend huge sums on advertising to signal product quality to buyers. Highly competent workers get college degree to signal their quality to employers. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 10

Market Responses to Asymmetric Information Market Responses to Asymmetric Information Screening: action taken by an uninformed party to induce informed party to reveal private information Health insurance company requires physical exam before selling policy. Buyer of a used car requires inspection by a mechanic. Auto insurance company charges lower premiums to drivers willing to accept a larger deductible – they are most likely the safer drivers. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 11

Asymmetric Information and Public Policy Asymmetric information may prevent market from allocating resources efficiently. Yet, public policy may not be able to improve on the market outcome: Private markets can sometimes deal with the problem using signaling or screening. The govt rarely has more information than private parties. The govt itself is an imperfect institution. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 12

A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1 Asymmetric information For each situation below, identify whether the problem is moral hazard or adverse selection explain how the problem has been reduced A. Aperion Audio sells home theater sound systems over the Internet and offers to refund the purchase price and shipping both ways if the buyer is not satisfied. B. Landlords require tenants to pay security deposits. 13

A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1 Answers, part A Aperion Audio sells home theater sound systems over the Internet and offers to refund the purchase price and shipping both ways if the buyer is not satisfied. Adverse selection: Buyers may fear that systems purchased on the Internet will not sound good, since the sellers know that buyers cannot hear them first. So, firms with good systems are less likely to be successful selling them on the Internet. Aperion Audio reduces the problem by signaling high quality with its generous return policy. 14

A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1 Answers, part B Landlords require tenants to pay security deposits. Moral hazard: The landlord (principal) does not know how well the tenant (agent) treats the apartment. Tenants may not be careful if they can get away without paying for damage they cause. The security deposit increases the likelihood the tenant will take care of the property in order to receive his deposit back when he moves out. 15

Political Economy Political economy applies the methods of economics to study how govt works. First, we consider voting. Condorcet paradox: the failure of majority rule to produce transitive preferences for society. Transitivity is a property of preference rankings: If A is preferred to B, and if B is preferred to C, then A should be preferred to C. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 16

Example of the Condorcet Paradox A, B, and C are three candidates running for an open seat on the city council. There are 3 types of voters, each with its own rankings of the candidates: Voter Type Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 % of all voters 35% 45% 20% 1st choice A B C 2nd choice 3rd choice FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 17

Example of the Condorcet Paradox Suppose pair-wise voting: First, B runs against C: B wins. Then, A runs against B: A wins. The overall winner: A Alternative order: First, A runs against C: C wins. Then, C runs against B: B wins. The overall winner: B Voter Type Type 1 Type 2 Type 3 % of all voters 35% 45% 20% 1st choice A B C 2nd choice 3rd choice First, B runs against C. What is the outcome? Type 1 and Type 2 voters prefer B over C, so B wins. Second, A runs against B. Type 1 and Type 3 voters prefer A over B, so A wins. However, in a race between A and C, C would win: Type 2 and Type 3 voters prefer C to A. This result violates transitivity! FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 18

Lessons from the Condorcet Paradox Democratic preferences are not always transitive. The order on which things are voted can affect the result. Majority voting does not always reveal what society really wants. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 19

Arrow’s Four Desirable Properties of a Voting System Arrow’s Four Desirable Properties of a Voting System 1. Unanimity: If everyone prefers A to B, then A should beat B. 2. Transitivity: If A beats B, and B beats C, then A should beat C. 3. Independence of irrelevant alternatives: The ranking between any two outcomes should not depend on whether a third option is available. 4. No dictators: There is no person that always gets his way, regardless of everyone else’s preferences. Based on Social Choice and Individual Values, by Kenneth Arrow. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 20

Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem Arrow proved that no voting system can satisfy all four properties. Arrow’s impossibility theorem: a mathematical result showing that, under certain assumed conditions, there is no scheme for aggregating individual preferences into a valid set of social preferences FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 21

The Median Voter Theorem Suppose society is deciding the level of the government budget. Each voter has her own preferences about the size of the budget. If you line up all voters in order of their budget preferences, the median voter is the one right in the middle. Median voter theorem: a mathematical result showing that majority rule will always pick the outcome most preferred by the median voter The median voter theorem is due to Duncan Black in a 1948 article entitled “On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making.” A precursor is the research of Harold Hotelling. Hotelling’s law says that firms will make their products very similar (e.g., two competing ice cream stands locating next to each other in the middle of the beach). FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 22

Example of the Median Voter Theorem The median voter prefers a budget of $50 billion. Preferred govt budget (billions) Why $50 is the median choice: At least 50% of voters want a budget no larger than $50 billion, and at least 50% of voters want a budget no smaller than $50 billion. Why $40 would win a two-way race between $40 and $70: Each voter chooses the option that is closest to his or her own preferred budget. $40 would be chosen by voters that prefer anything between $20 and $50, and such voters comprise 60% of the electorate. $70 would be chosen by voters who prefer $60, $70, or $80, and such voters comprise only 40% of the electorate. The choice closest to $50 will win any two-way race. Suppose the choices are $40 and $70. $40 will win, even though more voters prefer $70! FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 23 23

Implications of the Median Voter Theorem Implications of the Median Voter Theorem In a two-party or two-candidate race, each party will move its position toward that of the median voter. Minority views are not given much weight. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 24

Politicians are People Too Politicians motivated by self-interest, just like firms and consumers. Some politicians motivated by re-election, willing to sacrifice the national interest toward that goal. Others motivated by greed. The lesson: Economic policy is not made by benevolent leaders, and sometimes fails to resemble the ideals derived in economics textbooks. Here we see the Principal-Agent problem again: Principal = citizens. Agent = elected officials. The textbook contains an In The News box with a column by humorist Dave Barry on the role of the politician’s self-interest in shaping farm policy. You and your students will enjoy this article. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 25

A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 2 Application of Median Voter Theorem Would you expect the Democratic presidential nominee to be more liberal during the primaries or the general election, or to be consistent throughout both? Would you expect the Republican nominee to be more conservative during the primaries or the general election, or to be consistent throughout both? 26

A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 2 Answers The median voter in Democratic primaries is more liberal than the median voter in the general election. So, the Democratic candidate’s best strategy is to act more liberal during the primaries and more centrist during the general election. Similarly, the Republican candidate will want to appeal more to the median Republican voter during the primaries, and then appear less conservative during the general election. 27

Behavioral Economics Behavioral economics: the subfield of economics that integrates the insights of psychology People aren’t always as rational as traditional economic models assume. Herbert Simon viewed humans as satisficers, people who make choices that are merely “good enough” rather than optimal. Other economists have suggested that people are only “near rational” or exhibit “bounded rationality.” FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 28

People Aren’t Always Rational Studies find that people make systematic mistakes: People are overconfident. People give too much weight to a small number of vivid observations. People are reluctant to change their minds. Even though people are not always rational, the assumption that they are is usually a good approximation for economic modeling. The book cites some interesting research and examples on each of these findings. Here’s an additional example of giving too much weight to vivid observations: After a rock star is killed in a plane crash, people start taking the train more and flying less. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 29

People Care About Fairness People’s choices are sometimes influenced more by their sense of fairness than self-interest. Example: The ultimatum game The rules Two players who do not know each other have a chance to share a prize of $100. Player A decides what portion of the prize to give to player B. B must accept the split or both get nothing. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 30

People Care About Fairness Predicted outcome if both players rational A would propose a 99-1 split and B would accept, because $1 is better than nothing. Actual outcomes from experiments with real people B usually rejects lopsided splits like 99-1 as wildly unfair. Expecting this, A usually proposes giving $30 or $40 to B. B views this as unfair, but not so much as to abandon his self-interest, so B accepts. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 31

People Care About Fairness The results of the ultimatum game apply in other situations. Example: A firm may pay above-equilibrium wages during profitable years to be fair, or to avoid appearing unfair and risking retaliation from workers. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 32

People Are Inconsistent Over Time People tend to prefer instant gratification, even when delaying would increase the gratification. Result: People fail to follow through on plans to do things that are dreary, take effort, or cause discomfort. E.g., people often save less than they plan To help follow through, people look for ways to commit themselves to their plans. E.g., worker has money taken out of paycheck before he ever sees it Another example of time inconsistency: A worker plans to start saving 20% of her income 3 months from now, because she must first pay off some overdue bills. After 3 months pass, the worker savings nothing and instead spends all her monthly income. Here is the classic textbook example of time inconsistency (from Mankiw’s intermediate macro text and other textbooks): The government announces a policy of not negotiating with terrorists who take hostages. The policy is intended to deter terrorists, make them believe they would gain nothing by taking hostages. But terrorists know that once they have hostages, the government will be tempted to try to negotiate for the hostages’ lives. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 33

CONCLUSION Recall two of the Ten Principles from Chapter 1: Recall two of the Ten Principles from Chapter 1: Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity. Governments can sometimes improve market outcomes. Research at the frontiers of microeconomics illustrates some caveats that go with these principles: Consumers aren’t always rational. Market outcomes may not be best when information is asymmetric. Government solutions are not always ideal. FRONTIERS OF MICROECONOMICS 34

CHAPTER SUMMARY In many transactions, information is asymmetric. When there are hidden actions, principals may be concerned that agents suffer from the problem of moral hazard. When there are hidden characteristics, buyers may be concerned about the problem of adverse selection among the sellers. Private markets sometimes deal with asymmetric information with signaling and screening. 35

CHAPTER SUMMARY Governments are imperfect institutions. The Condorcet paradox shows that majority rule does not always produce transitive preferences for society. Arrow’s impossibility theorem shows that no voting system will be perfect. In many situations, majority voting will produce the outcome desired by the median voter, regardless of the preferences of everyone else. Policymakers may be motivated by self-interest rather than the national interest. 36

CHAPTER SUMMARY In contrast to the behavior assumed in traditional economic models, insights from psychology suggest that decision making is more complex. People are not always rational. They care about the fairness of outcomes even to their detriment, and they can be inconsistent over time. 37