Consumer’s and Producer’s Surpluses

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Market Intervention under Competitive Market Conditions
Advertisements

Unit 2: Supply, Demand, and Consumer Choice
What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
Chapter 3 Rational Consumer Choice
Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Policy & the Perfectly Competitive Model: Consumer & Producer Surplus
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
1 CHAPTER To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand” button. To return to the previous slide, click the red “shrink” button. To.
An Introduction to International Economics
Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
7 chapter: >> Taxes Krugman/Wells Economics
Chapter 13 – Taxation and Efficiency
Chapter 13: Taxation and Efficiency Econ 330: Public Finance Dr
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  Suppose you know you can buy as much gasoline as you choose at a given price.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
Consumer Behavior Esa Unggul University Budget Constraints Preferences do not explain all of consumer behavior. Budget constraints also limit an.
Social Welfare and Policy Analysis
12 Consumer Choice and Demand
Basic Concepts in Economics: Theory of Demand and Supply
Chapter 5: Applications of Rational Choice and Demand Theories
A Definition of Economics
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Who Wants to be an Economist? Part II Disclaimer: questions in the exam will not have this kind of multiple choice format. The type of exercises in the.
Chapter Nine Applying the Competitive Model. © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.9–2 Applying the Competitive Model In this chapter, we.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per litre once you enter the.
Who Wants to be an Economist? Notice: questions in the exam will not have this kind of multiple choice format. The type of exercises in the exam will.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Nine Properties and Applications of the Competitive Model.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
“Supply, Demand, and Market Equilibrium”
Economic surplus Gains and losses with international trade: Economic Welfare.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 9: Applications of Consumer Choice.
ECON 101: Introduction to Economics - I Lecture 3 – Demand and Supply.
Utility Maximization and Choice
Chapter 4 Demand I have enough money to last me the rest of my life, unless I buy something. Jackie Mason.
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 4 Demand I have enough money to last me the rest of my life, unless I buy something. Jackie Mason.
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
 Consumer welfare from a good is the benefit a consumer gets from consuming that good in excess of the cost of the good.  If you buy a good for exactly.
Chapter 5 Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
CDAE Class 10 Sept. 27 Last class: 3. Individual demand curves Today: 3. Individual demand curves Class exercise Next class: 3.Individual demand.
Consumer’s and Producer’s Surplus Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 3
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
1 Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter Nine Applying the Competitive Model. © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 9-2 Topics  Consumer Welfare.  Producer Welfare. 
$2.50 $2.00 Price Frozen pizzas per week $3.00 $3.50 MB 4 MB 3 MB 2 MB 1
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Chapter Five The Demand Curve and the Behavior of Consumers.
Economics 2010 Lecture 9 Markets and efficiency. Competition and Efficiency  The Key Question  Allocative Efficiency  The Invisible Hand  Obstacles.
The Analysis of Competitive Markets. Chapter 9Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies--Consumer and Producer.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternCallan and Thomas, Environmental Economics and Management,
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Gains From Exchange (Trade) and Effects of Government Policies.
Supply.  Labor and output  One basic question every business owner must answer is how many workers to hire  Marginal product of labor: the change of.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Chapter 2: A Review of Markets and Rational Behavior “…while the law [of competition] may be sometimes hard for the individual, it is best for the race,
Chapter 13 – Taxation and Efficiency
Introduction Are people unaffected by a tax increase if they pay zero in taxes afterwards? No, consumption may have changed in response to the tax increase.
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 2
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Presentation transcript:

Consumer’s and Producer’s Surpluses

Consumer Welfare How much are consumers helped or harmed by shocks that affect the equilibrium price and quantity? Shocks may come from new inventions that reduce firm costs, natural disasters, or government-imposed taxes, subsidies, or quotas. You might think utility is a natural measure of consumer welfare. Utility is problematic because: we rarely know a consumer’s utility function utility doesn’t allow for easy comparisons across consumers A better measure of consumer welfare is in terms of dollars.

Consumer’s Surplus Consumer’s surplus (CS) is the monetary difference between the maximum amount that a consumer is willing to pay for the quantity purchased and what the good actually costs. Step function

Marginal Value and Demand Marginal Value: The maximum amount a consumer would be willing to pay to acquire an additional unit of a good Marginal value curve and demand curve convey similar information Application of equi-marginal principle Buy the good as long as marginal value exceeds the price The consumer is in equilibrium where marginal value equals the price Total Value: The maximum amount a consumer would be willing to pay to acquire a given quantity of a good.

A Numerical Example Quantity Price Willing to Pay Actual Payment Consumer Surplus 1 15 2 13 28 26 3 10 38 30 8 4 7 45 17 5 50 25 6 52 12 40 53 46

Marginal and Total Value

The Consumer’s Surplus

Consumer’s Surplus Consumer’s surplus (CS) is the area under the inverse demand curve and above the market price up to the quantity purchased by the consumer. Smooth inverse demand function

Effect of a Price Change on Consumer’s Surplus If the price of a good rises (e.g. £0.50 to £1), purchasers of that good lose consumer’s surplus (falls by A + B) This is the amount of income we would have to give the consumer to offset the harm of an increase in price.

Consumer’s Surplus: A Mathematical Application Suppose that the demand function of a consumer is given by QD = 40 – 2P. If the market price P = 10, what is the consumer’s surplus? Given the market price P = 10, a consumer’s quantity demanded QD = 40 – 2P = 40 – 2*10 = 20 The consumer’s surplus is the area of the triangle between the price line and the inverse demand curve The inverse demand function is P = 20 – (1/2)QD; the height of the triangle is the intercept of the inverse demand curve minus P, that is 20 – 10 = 10. CS = ½ (20*10) = 100 If the market price falls to P = 5, how the consumer’s surplus would change? Given the market price P = 5, a consumer’s quantity demanded QD = 40 – 2P = 40 – 2*5 = 30 So the consumer’s surplus (the area of the triangle between the price line and the inverse demand curve) is CS = ½ (30*15) = 225 (because the height of the triangle is 20 – 5 = 15) The change in consumer’s surplus, ∆CS = 225 – 100 = 125

Market Consumer Surplus Market demand is the (horizontal) sum of individual demand curves; market CS is the sum of each individual consumer’s surplus. CS losses following a price increase are larger: the greater the initial revenue (p∙Q) spent on the good the less elastic the demand curve at equilibrium

Effect of a 10% Price Increase on Consumer Surplus Revenue and Consumer Surplus in Billions of 2008 Dollars

Deriving Demand Curves Graphically Allowing the price of the good on the x-axis to fall, the budget constraint rotates out and shows how the optimal quantity of the x-axis good purchased increases. This traces out points along the demand curve.

Expenditure Function and Consumer Welfare One measure of the harm to a consumer of a price increase is an increase in the consumer’s income needed to maintain the consumer’s utility. Cannot use an uncompensated demand curve because utility varies along the curve Can use compensated demand and the expenditure function because both hold utility constant Recall that the minimal expenditure necessary to achieve a specific utility level and given a set of prices is: Welfare change associated with price increase to p1*:

Expenditure Function and Consumer Welfare Which level of utility should be used in this calculation? Two options: Compensating variation is the amount of money we would have to give a consumer after a price increase to keep the consumer on their original indifference curve. Equivalent variation is the amount of money we would have to take away from a consumer to harm the consumer as much as the price increase did.

Compensating Variation and Equivalent Variation Indifference curves can be used to determine compensating variation (CV) and equivalent variation (EV).

Three Measures: CS, CV, and EV Relationship between these measures for normal goods: |CV| > |∆CS| > |EV| For small changes in price, all three measures are very similar for most goods.

Effects of Government Policies on Consumer Welfare Government programs can alter consumers’ budget constraints and thereby affect consumer welfare. Examples Quota: reduces the number of units that a consumer buys Subsidy: causes a rotation or parallel shift of the budget constraint Welfare programs: may produce kinks in budget constraint

Effects of Government Policies: Quotas Quotas limit how much of a good consumers can purchase. Quota of 12 units generates kink in budget line and removes shaded triangle region from individual’s choice set. Because of this quota, the consumer’s equilibrium will be at the kink of the budget line, that is tangent to a lower indifference curve indicating lower level of utility.

Effects of Government Policies: Welfare Programs Welfare programs provide either in-kind transfers or a comparable amount of cash to low-income individuals. Example: food stamps $100 in food stamps (in-kind) generates kinked budget line. $100 cash transfer increases opportunity set further.

Effects of Government Policies: Welfare Programs Because food stamps can only be used on food, consumers are potentially worse off if they would find it optimal to consume less food and more other goods than allowed by the program. Despite this, food stamps are used rather than comparable cash transfers in order to: reduce expenditures on drugs and alcohol encourage appropriate expenditure on food from a nutrition standpoint maintain program support from taxpayers, who feel more comfortable providing in-kind rather than cash benefits

Effects of Government Policies: Subsidies Subsidies either lower prices or provide lump-sum payments to low-income individuals. Example: child care subsidy Reducing price of child care rotates budget line out Unrestricted lump-sum payment (equal to taxpayers’ cost of the subsidy) shifts budget line out in a parallel fashion and increases opportunity set

Challenge Question: Child-Care Subsidies Background: Government child-care subsidies are common throughout the world. Rather than subsidizing the price of child care, the government could provide an unrestricted lump-sum payment that could be spent on child care or on all other goods, such as food and housing. Questions: For a given government expenditure, does a price subsidy or a lump-sum subsidy provide greater benefit to recipients? Which option increases the demand for child-care services more? Which one inflicts less cost on other consumers of child care?

Challenge Solution Child-care subsidy or lump-sum subsidy? Original budget constraint is LO If child-care subsidy, budget constraint is LPS . Family chooses e2 and utility is I2. If lump-sum subsidy so that e2 is affordable, budget constraint is LLS . Family chooses e3 and utility is I3. Taxpayer costs for the two programs are the same, but family is better off with the lump-sum subsidy.

The Producer’s Surplus The Producer’s Surplus is defined as the dollar amount by which a firm benefits by producing its profit maximizing level of output. In other words, a Producer’s Surplus is the amount by which the producer’s revenue exceeds her variable production costs

The Producer’s Surplus

Producer Surplus Producer surplus (PS) is the difference between the amount for which a good sells (market price) and the minimum amount necessary for sellers to be willing to produce it (marginal cost). Step function

Producer Surplus Producer surplus (PS) is the area above the inverse supply curve and below the market price up to the quantity purchased by the consumer. Smooth inverse supply function

Producer’s Surplus: A Mathematical Application Suppose that the supply function is given by QS = 2P. If the market price P = 10, what is the producer’s surplus? Given the market price P = 10, a producer’s quantity supplied QS = 2P = 2*10 = 20 So the producer’s surplus (the area of the triangle between the price line and the inverse supply curve) is PS = ½ (20*10) = 100 If the market price falls to P = 5, how the producer’s surplus would change? Given the market price P = 5, a producer’s quantity supplied QS = 2P = 2*5 = 10 PS = ½ (5*10) = 25 The change in producer’s surplus, ∆PS = 25 – 100 = – 75